Th eNew Price Discrimination And Priceing In Airline Markets

The New Price Discrimination and Pricing in Airline Markets: Implications for Competition and Antitrust* by

David Gillen

Sauder School of Business

2053 Main Mall

University of British Columbia

Vancouver, BC Canada V6T 1Z2

(604) 822 8352

david.gillen@sauder.ubc.ca

and

Tim Hazledine

Department of Economics

University of Auckland Business School Commerce A Building

3A, Symonds Street

Auckland, New Zealand

64 9 - 373 7599 Ext: 87435

t.hazledine@https://www.360docs.net/doc/4f7095731.html,

Paper for

XIV Pan-American Conference of Traffic & Transportation Engineering

September 20th -23rd, 2006

Las Palmas de Gran Canaria, Canary Islands (Spain)

* We are indebted to Heibin Huang, Meg Paichayoutvijit, Jixin Charlene Sun and Jiani Wu for excellent research assistance, and to the Auckland University Research Committee and the Canadian Studies program of the Government of Canada for financial support.

Abstract

The passenger air travel industry has recently been impacted by two major innovations: the rise of Low-Cost Carriers (LCCs) offering cheap, no-frills, one-way fares, and the widespread adoption of Internet-based direct Business-to-Consumer ticket sale systems. This paper explores the implications of these innovations using price data for over 1700 flights on forty Canadian and trans-border routes observed in May 2006.

We find (a) that there is extensive price discrimination based on date of purchase of ticket and other factors; (b) that average prices paid are nevertheless still significantly determined by the number and size distribution of airlines supplying a route; (c) that established

‘legacy’ carriers can still charge a substantial price premium over LCCs; and (d) that the internet fare systems may have made it easier for legacy carriers to coordinate the typically substantial increases in their fares over the last two weeks before flight date. We note the implications for antitrust policy in these markets 1. Introduction

The passenger air travel market has recently been impacted by two major innovations: first, in the 1990s, the rise of ‘Low-cost Carrier’ (LCC) airlines offering cheap one-way point to point tickets, and then, in the new millennium, the emergence and enthusiastic adoption by consumers of on-line internet booking systems. It has been suggested that the impact on the established or ‘legacy’ carriers has been dramatic – even that their business model has been

‘broken’ (Tretheway, 2004) as a consequence of the spread of these innovations.

Specifically, the transparency of Internet booking systems would result in only the lowest fare offerings being sustainable in the market, and the simplicity and efficiency of LCCs would mean that it would be their fares that would be the lowest. This would seem to have two important implications in practice for the legacy carriers. First, they would not be able to sustain the elaborate price discrimination practices whereby they had been able to extract different prices from different customers and prevent fareclass arbitrage by means of ‘fences’ placed around their cheapest fares – notably, the advance purchase return ticket with a Saturday night stayover requirement, which was cleverly designed to deter high-value business travellers but not the leisure travel segment of the market. And, second, because the new, flat, fare structure would be determined by the presence of LCCs in a market, the traditional relationship between market structure and price would be broken: it wouldn’t matter much whether a route was serviced by three or two or even just one legacy carrier, and indeed the monopoly might even be more attractive because it would be able to reap efficiencies of scale and scope economies.

In this paper we analyse more than 20,000 observations of airfares offered in May 2006 on forty North American routes: twenty two within Canada, and eighteen trans-border routes between Canada and the United States. The impact of the internet and the LCCs is immediately apparent: the old restricted return fare product has completely disappeared from the market – all thirteen of the airlines in our database offer one-way internet fares, which can be purchased either directly off the airline’s website, or from a travel agency which collects all the available fares and displays them so as to make it immediately obvious to the consumer where the best deal is coming from.

And yet the outcomes of the new competition do not at all support the ‘broken model’ predictions. We find that the legacy carriers use the new system to generate substantial inter-temporal price discrimination, with prices offered for a specific flight often being two or three times higher in the week before the flight than the fares available eight weeks before (where our observations begin). We observe this pattern of fare increases even in markets served also by LCCs, whose prices throughout -- and especially in the last week -- are significantly lower than those of the legacy carriers. We find that structural competition still matters: the legacy carriers’ fares are lower, on average, if there are more of them operating on a route. And we find evidence that the very transparency of Internet-based fare systems may actually have made it easier for legacy carriers to coordinate their pricing, in particular to take advantage of the generally higher willingness to pay of business travellers making their purchase decision close to the day of the flight. The paper is set out as follows in section 2 we provide the motivation for and background to our research and section 3 is a summary of previous studies in airline pricing. Section 4 describes our data and defines the variables subsequently used in the econometric modelling Section 5 presents a graphical illustration of prices in a sample of the markets. Section 6 discusses the regression results and their interpretation while section 7 offers a summary and some conclusions.

2. Motivation

and

Background

The focus of this paper is the link between market structure and the new price discrimination. Standard economic pricing theory is in terms of single-pricing and nearly all econometric tests use average price data, as though only a single price is charged for any particular product or service. Such analyses predict that sellers use their market power to raise price by restricting output, and that the extent a group of sellers can do this depends, among other factors, on their numbers: more sellers means lower price.

Such predictions are the basis of the policy treatment of proposed mergers, which are often turned down by the antitrust authorities if it is deemed, according to the orthodox theory, that the merged firm’s market share would be such as to make significant restrictions of output (and consequential allocative inefficiencies) likely. Such in essence was the basis of the decisions of the NZ Commerce Commission and the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission ruling against the 2002 application by Air New Zealand and Qantas to form a ‘strategic alliance’ (in essence, a cartel) covering all of the markets on which they currently compete.

A similar type of model was used in assessing the [then] proposed Air France-KLM merger and this was approved, on the basis that the likely price effects would not be significant.

There are some who argue that in such cases that keen competition at the low-price end of the market (induced by the actual or potential presence of the LCCs), coupled with the price discrimination practices of the legacy carriers have basically rendered obsolete the traditional basis of antitrust economics – that is, of price increases from restricting output. Even a dominant firm that could price discriminate effectively would not wish to restrict output, because it would pay them to supply marginal or low-valuation customers so long as this segment of the market could be ‘fenced off’ from higher value demand. Thus, the formation of a cartel would not necessarily lead to allocative inefficiencies, and possibly not even to increases in the average fares paid in these markets.

Empirical work on domestic NZ and trans-Tasman routes (Hazledine, 2006a) finds evidence that the extent of actual competition on routes (number and size of competing carriers) does still significantly affect the average fare paid, and, perhaps especially, the lowest price at which seats are offered. However, the output restrictions required to affect price increases may indeed be less than is predicted in standard single-price oligopoly models. For the present paper we develop these results and extend the tests to the domestic Canadian market, where an FSA (Air Canada) faces competition from an LCC (WestJet), and to the Canada/US transborder market where differing routes have differing levels of competition in terms of both numbers and types of carriers. We then consider the implications for antitrust as applied to horizontal mergers or alliances between competing airlines. We find this important for two reasons. First, North America has a number of carriers in Chapter 11 protection and it seems only a matter of time before further mergers will be proposed. Second, and pertinent to the Air New Zealand-Qantas proposal, Canada is often described as being similar to the Australian-New Zealand market.

3. Previous studies of airline pricing

There is an interesting econometric literature on the relationship between airline (average) fares and differences or changes in market structures, mostly using U.S. data. There have been three main focuses of attention: on the link between number of competitors and prices; on the existence of “hub premiums” earned by airlines dominating an airport used as a hub for connecting flights; and on the competitive impact of low-cost carriers or LCCs. Many of these studies are surveyed by Tretheway and Kincaid (2005).

Kim and Singal (1993) examined the impact of the fourteen U.S. airline mergers (national and/or regional carriers) that took place over the 1985-88 period, comparing routes affected by mergers with a control group of unaffected routes. They found that over the period from the initiation of merger talks through merger completion, the merging firms increased fares on average by 9.44% relative to unaffected routes, and any competitors on the affected routes raised their prices by even more -- 12.17%, on average. Hurdle et al (1989) compared 850 non-stop city-pair routes in the U.S. and report an average price differential between routes supplied by one carrier and routes supplied by two carriers of about 20%. Borenstein (1990) focused on the 1986 Northwest Airlines/Republic merger and

found average fare increases of 6.7% and 22.5% on routes served pre-merger by both airlines, depending on whether there was or was not at least one other competitor also serving the route. The same author (1991) found average fare differences between monopoly and duopoly, and between duopoly and triopoly, of 8% in each case. Oum, Zhang and Zhang (1993) predict a 17% price increase moving from duopoly to monopoly routes.

Morrison and Winston (1990) report that the number of effective airlines in a particular market over the 1982-88 period affected the fare charged with an elasticity of 0.12 -- that is, a route served by two carriers has fares twelve percent lower than a route served by just one airline.

Tretheway, in his 2004 submission to the Australian Competition Tribunal, reports an econometric model of air ticket prices estimated on a panel dataset covering ten years (1990-2000) of data on 1000 U.S. routes.1 Tretheway’s main interest is in the impact of LCC competition on prices, but his results do cover situations in which only ‘FSA’s (full-service airlines, also known as ‘legacy carriers’) serve routes, and these imply that a route with just one FSA has fares as much as 33% higher than a duopoly FSA route, which in turn sets prices on average 8% higher than on a route competed for by three FSAs.2

1 This paper is reported here as Tretheway and Kincaid (2005)

2 Tretheway’s regressions were carried out for him by Steven Morrison and Clifford Winston, who have themselves published a number of studies of U.S. airline pricing. Morrison and Winston also carried out on behalf of Air New Zealand and Qantas an analysis of airfares in Australia over the period 1999-2002, However, in later work, not surveyed by Tretheway and Kincaid, Goolsbee and Syverson (2005) find that an increase in the probability of Southwest entering a route

3 has a large (20%+) and significant impact on prices when the existing level of concentration on the route is above average, but not when the route is of below-average concentration. So, there may be some disagreement about the extent to which the ‘Southwest effect’ is qualified by the extent of existing competition, but there seems little doubt that, overall, Southwest and perhaps some other LCCs have had a substantial impact on US airfares well beyond the tickets they sell on their own flights.

Morrison and Winston (2000) estimated the hub premium using

DB1A data from 1996. They compared the average fare at eleven concentrated airports with the average fare across all airports in the US. They found a hub premium estimate of 22%. They next controlled for Southwest by simply by removing airports served by Southwest and found fares at the concentrated airports were found to be 6% lower than the remaining airports; fares at airports served by during which Ansett Australia exited and Virgin Blue entered the domestic market. This analysis was subjected to some criticisms from another consultant, Professor Jerry Hausman, which led to the NZ Commerce Commission carrying out its own econometric analysis of the data (2003, Appendix IV). The results of this imply that the presence of Ansett as a competitor to Qantas on a route reduced the latter’s fares by about 6.8% on average.

3 The perceived and actual probability of Southwest eventually entering a route increases sharply when it begins operating from both end-point airports on that route.

Southwest were approximately 39% lower than fares at airports not served by Southwest, averaging across al airports.

In another study, Morrison and Winston (1995) found that average fares for travel to and from the 12 concentrated airports were actually 6% lower on average than those for trips to and from other domestic airports if those served by Southwest were excluded from the latter group. They noted that if airports served by Southwest were excluded from both the concentrated and the remaining unconcentrated hub airports, average fares between the two groups differed by only about 1% after adjusting for differences in passengers’ trip lengths and use of frequent-flyer award tickets. More recently Hofer et al. (2004) examine whether LCCs affect network carriers’ ability to benefit from market concentration and power and whether LCCs earn hub premiums. Their conclusion is that airport market power and market concentration are positively correlated with average fares and that the presence of an LCC in a market leads to lower fares.

Overall, the body of econometric air fare analyses, nearly all of it based on the U.S. domestic market and using data generated under the old system of price discrimination based on imposing restrictions on discounted fares, gives strong support to the prediction of oligopoly theory that actual competition should matter to prices in a market. 4. The

Database

Sample

The basic unit of observation is the ‘flight’, which is a particular journey (flight number or pair of numbers) between two cities marketed by a particular airline on a particular date. In most cases the passengers on a flight are travelling in an aircraft operated by the airline or carrier which sold them the ticket, but some flights are code-shares, such that the aircraft carries passengers with boarding cards with differing flight numbers in the name of two or more airlines.

There are 1748 such flights in total, flown on one of four Wednesdays in May 2006, from May 10 through May 31. Thus there are 437 different flight numbers. These flight numbers cover 40 city-pair routes – 18 trans-border (ie between Canada and the United States) and 22 within Canada. Ten of the trans-border routes are only observed ex-Canada, and four are observed flying both ways. In total, thirteen airlines are observed.4

The sample does not include all domestic Canadian and trans-border flights. Apart from the exclusion of most ‘return’ itineraries, the sample was limited by the following choices:

4 The airlines that fly these routes are: Air Canada, Alaska, America West, American Airlines, CanJet, Continental, Delta, Harmony, Northwest, Skyservice, United, US Air, and WestJet. Note that in September 2006 CanJet announced its exit from scheduled passenger services.

?The extremely busy (many flights) Ottawa-Toronto-Montreal ‘triangle’ routes were not included, in the interests of

keeping the job manageable

?No itinerary with more than one stop was included, nor any 1-stop itinerary taking more than twice the journey time of a

non-stop flight5

The sample includes flights to and/or from the ten largest cities in Canada, and two other cities. The trans-border sample is a selection of short- and medium haul flights between four Canadian and ten American cities.

Prices

For each of the 1748 flights we observed6 the lowest available ticket price, beginning on the Wednesday eight weeks before flight date, and thereafter weekly until the final week before take-off, during which price was observed daily (Thursday, Friday, Saturday, Monday, Tuesday). We thus have up to thirteen observations7 on the lowest available prices at which tickets for the flight could have been purchased -- a total of 20,494 non-blank data entries. In our econometric work we make use of the eight weekly (Wednesday) observations on prices plus the last price offered, which is usually

5 Airline websites are often padded out with large numbers of rather lengthy and inconvenient itineraries, often at higher prices than are on offer for non-stop flights leaving at a similar time (and arriving of course much sooner). 119 of the journeys included had one-stop itineraries.

6 The Expedia.ca website was the source of the price quotes.

7 Fewer than thirteen if the flight was sold out before flight date. The prices included all taxes and ‘charges’ that the airlines usually do not include in their initial advertised prices. that shown on the day before the flight date. We have no information on the quantity of seats sold at each observed price and nor on any other prices that might have been offered before or within our eight week observation period. That is, our pricing data are sampled from the actual distribution of prices purchased.

To get comparability across routes, prices are divided by the non-stop flight distance, in kilometres. The price variables used here are: Pavk: average price (cents/km) of the eight weekly price

observations and the price the day before flight date (ie, this

is the unweighted average of nine price numbers).

P8k: price eight weeks from flight date

P0k: price the day before flight date

Pmink: lowest of the nine prices

Pmaxk: highest of the nine prices

Capacity and Concentration

We have no information on numbers of seats sold on each flight. We can ascertain, from the websites, the aircraft type and the number of seats available on the aircraft used on the flight. As a true supply-side variable, untainted by the effects of price charged – unlike the actual number of seats sold – seats available is arguably a

better measure for use in construction of market structure variables than sales.8

However, even on non-stop flights, the total number of seats on the aircraft cannot usually be used as the economic capacity or supply. This is because flights connect with other flights, so that some passengers have an origin and/or destination differing from the take-off or landing point of the particular flight. Also, some flights are operated as codeshares, with seats marketed independently by more than one airline. For these flights we allocated the seats available using what seemed to us to be reasonable rules of thumb. For example for the Air Canada one-stop route from Montreal to Calgary via Toronto, of which the first leg is flown by a 37-seat Dash 8 and the second by an Airbus A320 with 140 seats in total, we assigned just 10 seats to the Montreal-Calgary ‘flight’, and the remainder to the Calgary-Toronto nonstop. We reasoned that most of the passengers on the first leg would leave the flight at Toronto, either because that was their final destination, or to pick up other onward connections (to Vancouver, or Winnipeg, for example).

Our market structure variables are measured at the route level. For each of the 40 routes we calculated the following:

HHI: Hirschman-Herfindahl Index of seller concentration, defined as the sum of the squared market shares of all the carriers selling seats on the routes, with each airline’s market share measured as the sum of all its available seats divided by the total of all airlines’

8 With the qualification that a seat in business class is not really the same as a seat in economy. Here we just add the total number of economy and business class seats, with no weighting of the latter. available seats. So, for example, an airline with two daily flights on a route, flown by 140-seat Airbus A320s, would have a market share equal to 280 divided by the total number of available seats offered on all flights by all airlines supplying this route. DOMINATED: This is a dummy variable set equal to 1 for a route on which the largest airline offers more than 50% of the available seats, with no other carrier offering more than 25% of the seats. On twenty of the forty routes, one carrier was deemed to be dominant by this criterion.

Costs

In most airline pricing studies route distance is used as a proxy for costs. This is clearly an important determinant of flying costs, and is always a highly successful variable in econometric models, but it does suppress any variation in costs due to other factors, such as aircraft type, wage costs and overall operating efficiency. Therefore, in this study we built up our cost variable directly. This is not a simple matter. Apart from the data requirements, important conceptual and economic issues are raised. In particular, the appropriate measure of costs depends on the time horizon -- what contribution to ‘fixed’ costs is expected when airlines set fares – and also the extent that airlines expect each flight to pay its way, or, instead, price on a broader basis, such as the average costs for the route, or even for their entire networks. We do not bring firm priors to these issues, and our approach will be to let the data reveal the dimensions of costs that enter airlines’ pricing and yield management decisions.

We have three different ways of building up a costs variable. Two of these apply formulations developed in a recent article by Swan and

Adler (2006). The third is a ‘block hour’ measure based on Form 41 costs collected by the USDoT/FAA and reported in Aviation Daily. Swan and Adler report two methods for constructing costs. First is what they term a ‘planar-form cost function’ based on engineering data ,which specifies that aircraft trip costs are determined by seat numbers (S) and route distance (D). For single-aisle operations from 1000-5000 km, the relationship is:

C = (D+722)*(S+104)*$0.019

And for longer haul twin-aisle operations:

C

=

(D+2200)*(S+211)*$0.0115

The latter function has more application to long haul trans-ocean flying, whereas our data covers markets which are essentially domestic flying; our longest route is 5335 km and the average non-stop flight length is 1683 km. These formulae are designed to incorporate only aircraft trip costs, which Swan and Adler state are around 50-60% of total costs, with general administrative costs around 30% and commissions and sales expenses the remainder. Note that the constants added in these expressions to both D and S ensure that there will be increasing returns to both these factors: doubling distance for a given number of seats, or doubling aircraft seat capacity for a given distance, will in both cases less than double the total costs of making the trip, so the costs per seat kilometre will fall.

The other cost formula provided by Swan and Adler is a Cobb-Douglas cost function estimated as a log-linear regression on the same information as they used in constructing the planer cost functions. The two specifications estimated for narrow body and wide body operations, respectively, with cost per seat kilometre as the dependent variable, are:

c

=

2.44S-0.40 D-0.25

and

c

=

0.64S-0.345D-0.088

Note that in these equations the impact of distance on costs is captured through a distance elasticity, and varies between -.09 to -.25. This ‘cost taper’ results from lower fuel burn at higher altitudes and spreading the costs of getting to altitude over more km.

Our third method builds up flight costs from available measures of ‘block hour’ operating costs. The cost associated with operating aircraft on a route; referred to as flying operations cost (FOC) can be measured by the cost per block hour multiplied by the number of block hours required for the route:

FOC s = B s ? H s ? f(Y s)

where B s is cost per block hour for the aircraft used, H s are the block hours required for segment S, and f(Y s ) is flight frequency which depends on number of passengers on segment, Y s . a route can have one or more segments and we examine a flight so frequency is 1. Obviously, the cost per block hour for a given aircraft and given segment will depend upon the labour prices of the carrier as well as other input prices. 9 However, the other input

9. The aircraft cost can be measured by adding the cost per block hour multiplied by the number of block hours required for the flight segment and a portion of the indirect airline costs which are attributable to flight frequency. Note that the

prices such as fuel, maintenance and capital costs will not vary significantly across carriers for that segment.

We constructed this cost measure using information submitted by carriers to the USDOT and assembled as ‘Form 41’ data. These data are available by aircraft type by carrier by activity -- for example, costs per block hour are available for United, Southwest, American and USAir flying a Boeing 737-400 series. The data are also available on a cost per available seat mile (CASM) basis broken out for crew cost, fuel/oil, aircraft cost, insurance, taxes and maintenance burden. The cost of operating an aircraft type by carriers using that aircraft were reported by carrier, and an average across carriers for an aircraft type is also reported. We had available all costs for all aircraft types used in our data set.

The cost variable was measured as the block hour operating costs for the aircraft used times the block hours for a flight (available when collecting price data). These were divided by the seat km of the flight and expressed as ‘cost per seat km’. These represented flight costs.

These costs can differ for the same airline flying the same route if it uses different aircraft type. Accordingly, we also calculated a route-based operating cost measure for each airline and route, which was a block-hour costs need to be adjusted upward by the amount of interest cost on the capital tied up in aircraft. It appears that the cost per block hour available in Form 41 data includes only the aircraft rentals paid for leased aircraft, and does not appear to include the interest cost on the owned aircraft. This however may not be a significant problem given that most airlines lease aircraft. capacity-weighted average of the individual flight costs. We will let the econometrics tell us which measure is the more appropriate. There are additional non-operating costs attached to a flight. These include marketing and transaction costs, passenger and baggage ground-handling costs, and airport fees. We have little direct information on these costs, but we do know that they are incurred on a per passenger basis, so that excluding them from our costs measure would bias upwards the relative costs of longer flights. Therefore, we proceeded on a “top down” basis, as follows. We calculated the total of operating costs for each airline, based on the block hour-based per flight costs we had already computed aggregated over all the flights observed, applied the Swan and Adler rule of thumb that these costs are around 20% of flight operating costs, divided by the total number of seats offered on all flights by the airline, to get marketing etc costs per seat, and then for each flight divided this number by flight distance and added to our flight operating cost measure to arrive at our total costs per seat kilometre measure.

We thus have twelve possible measures of the cost per seat kilometre for a specific flight by a specific airline. There are the three different methods for constructing the operating cost variable, each of which can be measured at the flight or route level, and to which can be added or not the top-down estimate of marketing and ground costs.

We found that neither of the Swan/Adler measures performed well econometrically. This may be because our routes are clustered near

or below the bottom end of the flight distance range specified by Swan and Adler -- 1000-5000 kilometres.10 The nonlinearity built in to the Swan/Adler formulas could overestimate flight costs for these shorter flights. Also we observe both single and double aisle aircraft flying transcontinental routes, but the shorter distance Swan/Adler formula is designed just for single-aisle aircraft.

We therefore used the measure that we developed ourselves from the block hour data as the basis of our cost variable. Perhaps surprisingly, we found that adding our, admittedly quite crude estimate of marketing etc costs to the operating cost data improved the explanatory power of the variable, and we also found that prices were better explained by operating costs measured at the route, not the flight level.

Other variables

SOLDOUT: This is a dummy variable set equal to 1 if the flight appeared to have sold-out at any time in the last week before the flight date, as evidenced by its disappearance from the website offerings

LEISURE: This is an informed ‘quesstimate’ of the percentage of passengers on a route who are ‘leisure’ as opposed to ‘business’ travellers. Leisure travel includes tourism and the ‘VFR’ (visiting friends and relatives) category. This was constructed using as a basis the industry rule of thumb that, overall, about 70% of passengers are leisure travellers, and then modifying this up or down depending on the known characteristics of the route. For example, the value of

10 Fifteen of our 40 flights are actually less than 1000kms in distance. LEISURE for the Toronto-Tampa route is set at 90, and for the Toronto-New York route at 40.

PEAKDUM: This is a dummy variable assigned the value 1 for some early morning short-haul flights between large cities. It did not show any significance in the econometric analysis.

LCC: The airlines America West, CanJet, Harmony and Skyservice are all ‘Low Cost Carriers’ and the dummy LCC is set at 1 for them. We will also show results with WestJet categorised as an LCC STOPS: set equal to 1 for one-stop flights.

Table 1 provides the summary statistics for each variable used in the regression analysis.

Table 1

5. Pricing

Behaviour

Asymmetric information is an intrinsic and inescapable fact in nearly all pricing situations: customers know more about their maximum willingness to pay [WTP] for a given good or service than does the seller. This is still true of course in air travel markets, but

what distinguishes the passenger airline industry from just about all others is the extent to which the sellers -- the airlines -- have been able to devise methods of separating potential travellers by their WTP, and charging them accordingly.

In this section we use our price data to illustrate what is now the most important tool used for sorting passengers by their willingness to pay, which is simply the practice, using what the airlines call

‘yield management’, of increasing the lowest fare offered for a particular flight as the day of that flight approaches. This exploits the different WTP of leisure and business travellers. Generally leisure passengers will be more price sensitive (lower WTP) and are willing to plan and book well ahead of the departure date. Business passengers on the other hand tend to face continuously changing schedules requiring flexibility and so are unwilling to commit to an itinerary well in advance, but are willing to pay a high price when they do choose to travel

Figure 1 shows the YVR-YEG (Vancouver-Edmonton) route, which has a somewhat higher than average proportion of business travellers. The route is served by two airlines, the legacy carrier Air Canada (AC) and a LCC, WestJet (WJ). We can see both carriers start to increase prices five weeks out, at P5, and that the average price increases steadily, but with AC at a higher level throughout than WJ. So, both carriers are using intertemporal price discrimination, but the legacy carrier more so than the LCC.

Figure 1

In contrast, on Figure 2 showing the Vancouver-Halifax (YVR-YHZ) route, we had three carriers -- two LCCs (WJ and Canjet) and Air Canada. This is a relatively long haul route, at approximately 4600 km. The carriers behave in strikingly different ways. WJ gradually increases prices by a small amount, Canjet keeps prices relatively constant and AC increases prices very little in the first 6 weeks but two weeks before the flight increases prices significantly. So we have one LCC which does not price discriminate at all, one which does to a small degree and a legacy carrier which discriminates to some degree over 6 weeks and significantly in the last two weeks.

Figure 2

Compare this behaviour with Figure 3 which illustrates prices in a transborder market – a market in which the route joins a city in Canada with a city in the US. The route shown is Toronto-New York (YYZ-LGA), as served by 4 legacy carriers -- AC, AA (American airlines), Delta and UA (United Airlines) -- and one LCC, Canjet. This can be regarded as a predominately business market. Prices are relatively constant until 2 weeks prior to the flight with the LCC is charging the lowest price. At 2 weeks before the flight every carrier except Canjet raises prices significantly, as then does Canjet one week out. The prices rise significantly and in an apparently coordinated way.

Figure 3

In Figure 4 we show the high volume domestic route Toronto-Vancouver, which is fairly typical route with respect to the relative proportions of business and leisure passengers. There are four carriers: a legacy carrier, AC, a low cost carrier, WJ and two scheduled charter operators which would also be low cost.11 The legacy carrier sets prices 60 percent or more higher than other carriers. All carriers increase their prices by a small amount over weeks eight through two before flight date, but only the legacy carrier increases prices significantly within two weeks of take-off.

Figure 4

11 A schedule-charter operator flies some scheduled routes at low frequency and also flies charters to leisure destinations.

Our final illustration is Figure 5, showing another transborder route (Los Angeles-Vancouver), which is served by five legacy carriers plus the US based LCC, America West. Here the pricing behaviour is quite different. Each carrier appears to set its own, different, price level -- eight weeks out from the flight date prices range from $180 to $300. The price distributions are relatively flat in some cases and volatile in others: on average there is very little price discrimination before the last two weeks before the flight. The LCC is not even the low price supplier. Some prices go up two weeks out but others fall and the increases are not nearly as marked in other markets.

Figure 5

Figure 1 through 5 illustrate pricing activity in markets with

differing numbers of carriers, as well as differences in route length, market type, domestic versus transborder and mix of carriers. These data show quite marked differences in prices charged for flights on the same route and the same day – differences both across carriers and over time on each carrier. The data also reveal some striking apparent coordination of price increases as the flight date approaches. The next section explores these pricing patterns systematically.

6. Econometric

Results

The graphics shown in the previous section reveal substantial and differing patterns of intertemporal price discrimination across the Canadian and trans-border routes. In this section we seek to explain these patterns in terms of supply, demand and market structure factors. We are particularly interested in whether the prediction of standard (one-price) oligopoly theory that price is affected by the extent of structural competition in a market, as evidenced by the number and relative size of sellers, holds true when ‘price’ is demonstrably an average of prices paid which can differ, for the same flight, by a factor of two or three depending on when the ticket was purchased. We are also interested in the competitive impact of Low-Cost Carriers, and on whether we can explain the pattern of price discrimination; in particular, whether this is affected by market structure, as predicted by theory.

We have a panel of data, with 437 itineraries or flights each observed four times on consecutive Wednesdays in May 2006, giving a total of 1748 observations. To estimate our models we use EViews 5.1 Panel EGLS with cross sectional random effects, with the flight as the cross sectional identifier.

Results are shown on Table 2. Here we have two sets of six regression outputs. The two sets differ only in their treatment of the Canadian airline WestJet. The upper group of six has WestJet classified as a Low Cost Carrier, as indeed it claims to be. The lower six regressions all have WestJet not classified as an LCC.12

Average price regressions

The first two regression models in each group have the log of the average lowest price per kilometre as the dependent variable. We are testing the proposition that average price (in essence, the first order summary statistic of the price distribution) is a meaningful number even in the context of the very substantial intertemporal price discrimination revealed by our data. Hazledine (2006) finds in the context of the linear homogeneous Cournot-Nash model that average price charged is actually unaffected in theory by the extent of price discrimination (number of different prices offered) -- here we can test this prediction.

These regressions introduce the set of explanatory variables that we use throughout. Looking first at the first column of results, we note the following:

?Our cost measure is a highly significant determinant of the average level of prices

?The HHI market concentration index is a moderately significant determinant of average prices, as predicted by

oligopoly theory

12 The new term for business model followed now by Westjet is ‘Value Focused Carrier’ (VFC), meaning a carrier which follows the LCC strategy with respect to costing but has added services for additional price.

?Flights which are sold out before the flight date have higher average prices, suggesting that selling-out is a demand-shift

phenomenon, not a movement down demand curves induced

by lower prices

?Flights with a higher proportion of leisure (non-business) passengers may have lower prices, although this finding is

not robust to the classification of WestJet

?There was a monotonic ramping up of prices as the month of May proceeded towards the summer holiday travel season,

with flights on the last day of the month tending to be more

than 9% more expensive than flights just twenty one days

earlier

?One-stop flights yielded fares at least 15% lower than non-stops. This is a striking result, because the costs of flying

one-stops must in general be higher than a non-stop routing,

so that supply-side factors would push for a higher, not lower

price.13 It seems likely that what we have found is a

manifestation of a price discrimination practice, with highly

time-insensitive travellers taking up these cheap itineraries

whose inconvenience14 deters the high-value time-sensitive

business customer.

?It is clear, as it was in the graphs of section 5, that LCCs charge lower prices than legacy carriers: but it seems that

WestJet is a more expensive LCC than CanJet, America

13 The RCOSTB unit cost variable does not account for additional costs of operating a one-stop itinerary. It has the same value for all the flights on a particular route of a particular airline.

14 As well as taking longer, many one-stop itineraries operate in non-peak hours.

West and the others. Without WestJet, the coefficient on the LCC dummy variable is about -0.3; with WestJet also

classified as an LCC, the coefficient rises to just -0.08 ?The classification of WestJet also affects the significance of the HHI, which is greater when WestJet is assigned to be an LCC. The reason for this is probably that most of the

relatively highly concentrated duopoly routes are those

inside Canada on which Air Canada and WestJet compete,

and on which WestJet does systematically charge lower

prices than Air Canada, especially in the last week before

travel. Treating WestJet as an LCC allows some of this price differential to be absorbed into the LCC dummy coefficient, leaving more effect to be accounted for by the HHI structural measure.

In the second column we allow the coefficient of HHI to differ according to whether the route is deemed to have a ‘dominant’ carrier, as defined (without any experimentation but not unreasonably) as an airline offering more than half of the seats on a route on which no other airline offers more than one quarter. Statistically, this is a highly successful specification, but its economic implication was a surprise. Bearing in mind the literature on ‘hub premia’ and ‘city presence’ effects, we had expected prices to be higher for a dominant carrier, ceteris paribus, and indeed first specified the dummy variable

‘DOMINANT’, taking the value 1 for the airline, not for the route. When the coefficient came out as negative we investigated further, and found that the characteristic being picked up is more likely a route, not an airline characteristic – a model with the dummy variable DOMINATED fit the data better.

The implications of the result can be seen as follows. Suppose we have two routes. One is supplied by two equal-sized airlines, and so has a HHI value of 0.5. The other has a ‘dominant’ carrier offering 2/3 thirds of the total seats, competing with two smaller carriers, each supplying 1/6 of the market. The HHI for the

second route is also 0.5, but according to our regression model, prices would be about thirteen percent higher on the symmetrical duopoly route.15 That is, on these routes, there is more effective price competition between three firms than between two, even if in the triopoly case two of the three suppliers are much smaller than the leading firm. A possible explanation is that two similar-sized duopolists find it easier to tacitly collude to avoid over-

enthusiastic price competition. This may help explain why

WestJet -- which operates mostly in duopoly situations with Air Canada – has prices systematically higher than the other LCCs.

Low price regressions

The third and fourth of the six columns of results on Table 2

explore the determinants of the lowest prices charged by the

airlines.16 We use two measures of low price: Pmink, which is the lowest of the nine prices observed over the eight weeks

before flight date, and P8k, which is the first price observed,

eight weeks before flight date. In 57% of cases (998 out of

1748) these numbers are the same, but in the other instances the

15 Exp(0.5*0.25) = 1.133

16 These are the ‘lowest of the low’ -- all our price observations are the lowest price offered for a flight on the day the flight is observed.lowest fare was observed less than eight weeks before flight date.

Which is the most appropriate low-price measure? Sudden (and usually temporary) breaks in the pattern of monotonically increasing prices over time seem likely to be mostly due to unforeseen shifts in the demand curve (eg because of a cancellation of a tour group booking), not to price discrimination, which is about movements along the demand curve. If then, our focus is on the characteristics of (inter-temporal) price discrimination, then we might wish to focus on the P8k variable, being the price at the low-price end of the intertemporal distribution. On the other hand, Pmink is indeed an actual price offered in the market, and as the lowest such price is of some interest in itself, whether or not price discrimination is involved.

In the event, the two different price measures do not produce radically different regression models. It appears that market structure is an important determinant of fares even at the low-end of the demand curve, and that the legacy carrier price premium over LCCs is also observed at this end of the distribution.

We will compare these results with those in the fifth and sixth columns, which model the highest observed price (Pmaxk) and the last observed price, the day before flight (P0k). In 92% of cases these two numbers are the same, and so it is not surprising that we get quite similar regression models. These show interesting differences from the low-price models, and we focus

on the comparisons between these, and with the average price (Pavk) results. We can note that:

?The market structure variables HHI and

HHI*DOMINATED play a significant role throughout

the yield management process, with possibly little

difference in the proportional impact of structure on high

and low prices.

?The generally higher yields from SOLDOUT flights appear to be garnered in the middle of the price

distribution, since although average prices are around 3%

higher on sold-out flights, there is no discernible positive

effect on either lowest or highest prices

?If LEISURE does have an effect on yields (it only consistently appears to do so in the regression model

with WestJet classified as an LCC) this is apparent

throughout the price distribution, not – as one might

expect -- just at the high price end, which is when we

expect most business travellers to purchase their tickets.

Eight weeks out from flight date we believe that nearly

all purchasers of tickets will be ‘leisure’ travellers,

whatever the eventual composition of the passenger load

when the plane takes off. Our results suggest that the

airlines price their ‘leisure’ tickets higher if they know

the flight will eventually have a higher business traveller

composition, probably to ensure that seats for the latter

will still be available in the last one or two weeks.

?The seasonal effect on prices, which went up on average through the month of May, seems to be largely worked

through prices nearer the beginning of the distribution,

presumably because it is the demand from leisure

travellers (not business) that is increasing as the summer

approaches

?However WestJet is categorised, the LCC price effect is much larger the day before the flight than eight weeks

before. After inspecting the graphs shown in section 5 we

can see that it could hardly be otherwise, since it is in the

last week or perhaps two before flight date that the

legacy carriers’ prices increase sharply, with this being

not generally matched by the LCCs, from whom a

relatively inexpensive ticket can often be purchased as

late as the day before the flight

?The price discount charged on one-stop flights also

widens markedly in the last week, consistent with our

interpretation that these flights do not generally appeal to

high-value business travellers from whom a price

premium can be extracted on last-minute ticket sales. Analysis of the link between concentration and price

discrimination

We have found that the overall position of the intertemporal distribution of prices, as measured by the mean value of prices observed, is related to the size distribution of sellers. Is the shape -- in particular, the slope -- of the distribution also a market structure-related variable? Hazledine (2006b) predicts that it will be, at least under Cournot-Nash assumptions: in his model the high/low dispersion of prices is larger the smaller the number of competitors. That is, a monopolist is able to extract the most surplus out of a

market by means of price discrimination, and, at the other structural extreme, a near-competitive industry with many firms will have very little discriminatory power, simply because its firms lack the power to raise any of their prices much above marginal costs.

There have been two previous studies of airfare price dispersion, both using U.S. data of samples of fares actually paid during the pre-internet era, when legacy carriers partitioned their markets using the Saturday Night Stayover advance purchase restriction on their cheaper fares. Borenstein and Rose (1994), and Stavins (2001) both find that the dispersion of fares paid on particular flights was increasing in the number of airlines flying the route. Borenstein and Rose explain this by distinguishing conceptually between “competitive-type” and “monopoly-type” price discrimination. The latter is based on differences between customers in their elasticities of demand at the total market level, and the extent of such discrimination would be expected to be greater under monopoly conditions. However, if within-market cross elasticities of demand are larger at the lower willingness-to-pay end of the demand curve -- that is, such customers are also keener comparison shoppers – then introducing more competition onto a route could result in larger falls of price at the lower than at the upper end of the fare distribution.

框架合同

Scheduling Agreement and delivery schedule(计划协议及交货计划): 1.创建计划协议(Tcode:ME31L) Path:Logistics->Material Management->Purchasing->Outline Agreement->Scheduling Agreement ->Create->Vendor Known 前台->后勤->物料管理->采购->框架协议->计划协议->创建->ME31L-已知供应商 创建Scheduling Agreement也有很多的方式:Manual、Copy Document、Reference to PReq、Reference to RFQ、R eference to Contract。 Agreement Type:LP->手工创建Delivery Schedule LPA->MRP自动创建Delivery Schedule

输入“有效期限末”=2009-12-30,“付款条款”=0001,回车: 输入:物料:B-16MNR-10,目标数量:5000,工厂:1101,物料组:CR10,保存,系统提示:“计划协议在号550000 0002下被创建”,。 使用ME35L批准计划协议(否则不能做库存收货),

点击批准计划协议。。 2.维护交货计划Delivery Schedule(Tcode:ME38) Path:Logistics->Material Management->Purchasing->Outline Agreement->Scheduling Agreement ->Delivery Schedul e->Maintain 前台->后勤->物料管理->采购->框架协议->计划协议->交货计划->ME38-维护

销售战略合作协议示范文本

销售战略合作协议示范文 本 In Order To Protect Their Legitimate Rights And Interests, The Cooperative Parties Reach A Consensus Through Consultation And Sign Into Documents, So As To Solve And Prevent Disputes And Achieve The Effect Of Common Interests 某某管理中心 XX年XX月

销售战略合作协议示范文本 使用指引:此协议资料应用在协作多方为保障各自的合法权益,经过共同商量最终得出一致意见,特意签订成为文书材料,从而达到解决和预防纠纷实现共同利益的效果,文档经过下载可进行自定义修改,请根据实际需求进行调整与使用。 协议各方当事人 甲方:住址:邮编:联系电话: 乙方:住址:邮编:联系电话: 鉴于: 1、xx公司(以下简称某公司)是国内领先的xx产品(或 服务)供应商。 2、×××集团公司(以下简称××公司)销售磁条卡、智 能卡、智能卡终端接口产品、校园系统集成、发卡系统及 设备、安全认证产品等,向顾客提供该产品最为全面的基 本卡及智能卡解决方案,业务涉及金融、公交、社保、校 园、电子政务、高速公路等领域。 3、双方都拥有良好的品牌形象、销售通路和客户资

源,双方产品具有较强的互补性和兼容性。故此,双方根据《中华人民共和国协议法》及其他相关法律,本着平等互利的原则,就建立战略合作伙伴关系的规则等相关事宜,双方经协商一致,达成战略合作协议,协议如下:第一条合作宗旨 双方希望通过建立密切、长久及融洽的战略合作伙伴关系,充分发挥各自网络和业务特点,在业务捆绑、市场营销、产业推动等多个领域开展强强合作,实现资源共享、优势互补,共同促进双方产品与服务的延伸和发展。 第二条合作领域双方一致同意致力于在以下产品或服务领域建立全面、深入的战略合作伙伴关系: 1、 2、 第三条合作内容 双方一致同意以各自的资源和专业技术及经验为基

销售框架协议(律师推荐版)

销售框架协议 甲、乙双方本着自愿、平等、公开、长期及密切的合作,以共同发展为原则,依据中华人民共和国的法律、法规,经双方友好协商,达成如下条款,以资共同遵守。本协议更改及修正须采用书面形式作出。除另有书面协议外,双方以任何方式不时进行的任何一笔买卖交易均适用本合同。 定义 货物:指甲方经产品厂家或供应商合法授权销售给乙方的产品,受国家法律保护。 信用额度:是指甲方根据乙方的资信情况,交易信用记录,授予乙方可在一定的金额范围内以赊销方式从甲方采购产品。甲、乙双方就信用额度另行签署《授信协议》。 订单:在本合同生效后,甲方和乙方之间所发生的传真订货、网上订货、口头订货、合同订货、价格确认单、采购单等一切要求甲方供货的行为。订单均视为乙方向甲方发出的不可撤销之要约行为,非经甲方同意撤销、变更,乙方必须按约履行,否则按本合同违约处理。 网上订货指甲方根据情况向乙方开通电子商务系统,乙方可以通过计算机网络向甲方下单。经过甲方确认后,订单生效。 乙方的关联企业:乙方有义务向甲方书面通报所有乙方的关联企业信息,乙方应对其关联企业与甲方合作期间所产生的债务承担连带责任。 凡有下列情形之一的,均属于乙方的关联企业: 都是由同一自然人作为法定代表人或控制人; 法定代表人或实际掌权人之间存在亲属关系的; 是总公司与分公司关系或母公司与子公司关系的; 重要管理人员是其他公司的法定代表人或实际经营人; 其它关联认定依国家税务总局相关正式发文为依据。 如被甲方确认为乙方关联企业后,该关联企业可使用甲方授予乙方的信用额度及账期。 乙方资质:甲乙双方进行交易之前,乙方有义务如实登记包括但不限于乙方的名称、住所等相关信息进行填写甲方提供之《客户档案资料表》,此表所有信

营销推广活动服务合同

编号:_______________本资料为word版本,可以直接编辑和打印,感谢您的下载 营销推广活动服务合同 甲方:___________________ 乙方:___________________ 日期:___________________

以下是关于《营销推广活动服务合同》,供大家学习参 考! 营销推广活动服务合同 合同编号: 委托方 承办方 依据《中华人民共和国合同法》、《中华人民共和国广告法》及相关法律、法规、规章的规定,甲、乙双方在平等、自愿的基础上,协商一致就甲方委托乙方承办活动推广事宜达成如下合同条款,以资共 ___________________________________________________ , 活动方案:执行方案及相关计划详见本合同“附件一 ”,由乙方根据甲方要求策划、设计并经甲方确

认后执行; 前期准备:乙方进场准备时限自至 完成准备;乙方完成准备后,甲方应当及时验收,若对相关质虽及数虽有异议,应当即提出;双方经核对活动方案及相关设计图纸后,如确有问题,乙方应该立即整改;如对活动效果产生不良影响,由乙方承担相关责任及损失,甲方有权按方案清单扣除相应费用。 其他约定 第二条:合同价款及付款方式 合同价款总额为:人民币元,即大写人民币 圆整。除了经过甲方书面确认的可增加的费用 外,本合同价款总额不因任何事由上浮,包括但不限于不可抗力、价格上涨等因素。 合同价款明细详见合同“附件二”。该 价款含人工费、道具费、场地费、交通费、政府报批收费、税金等一切乙方为了履行本合同项下委托事项所产生的费用。 本合同选择以下第种方式付款: A.推广活动全部完成并经甲方书面确认后,甲方一次性支付。乙方应于甲方付款前一周提供全额发票; B.合同签订后内,甲方支付合同价款的%计RMB ¥元;活动结束并经甲方确认后,支付合同价 款的%】计RM改元。

合同PR

采购合同模板 1.合同介绍 1.1甲方(采购方) 甲方名称: 通信地址: 联系人: 电话、传真: E-Mail: 1.2乙方(供应商) 乙方名称: 通信地址: 联系人: 电话、传真: E-Mail: 1.3合同目的 提示:说明甲方向乙方采购何种物品,经双方协商后确定本采购合同。 2.术语、关键词解释 物品: 系指供应商按合同要求,需向采购方提供的一切软件、硬件及相关的技术资料。 服务: 系指根据合同,供应商承担与供货有关的辅助服务,比如运输、保险以及其它的伴随服务,比如安装、调试、提供技术援助、培训等。 3.采购物品说明 3.1采购物品及说明 3.2技术指标和质量要求 4.合同价格和支付方式 4.1本合同总价格为(人民币大写): 4.2预付款。甲方于本合同签署之日起,在15日内,将合同总成交价的20%,即人民币(元),作为预付款支付给乙方。乙方在收到上述款项后,以传真向甲方确认。如甲方不按上述规定准时支付预付款,则交货期作相应的顺延。 4.3发货款。乙方按合同规定在发货时,将有关运输提单或自提单、商业发票、装箱单和质量证书,以可靠方式寄递给甲方。甲方收到以上单据的次日起15日内,将合同总成交价的40%,即人民币(元),作为发货款支付给乙方。乙方在收到上述款项后,以传真向甲方确认。 4.4验收款。在采购物品通过甲方的验收之后,甲方在15日内,将合同总成交价的40%,即人民币(元),作为验收款支付给乙方。乙方在收到上述款项后,以传真向甲方确认。 4.5甲方和乙方应以书面方式相互通知各方的开户银行、帐户名称、帐号。开户银行、帐户名称、帐号如有变更,变更一方应在合同规定的相关付款期限前二十天内以书面方式通知对方,如未按时通知或通知有误而影响结算者应负逾期付款的责任。 5.交货与交货方式 5.1乙方于本合同签署之日起,在30日内,将甲方采购的物品全部送达指定地点。 交货地点: 5.2乙方应在交货前7日内,以电话或传真向甲方提供交货计划(内容包括合同号、设备名称、型号规格、

融合业务合作框架协议-广电战略合作框架协议

融合业务合作框架协议 甲方:中国移动通信集团广东有限公司潮州分公司乙方:中国铁通集团有限公司潮州分公司 丙方:广东省广播电视网络股份有限公司潮州分公司签署地点:广东省潮州市

目录 一、合作内容 二、合作期限 三、三方权利和义务 四、保密 五、信息安全 六、违约责任 七、不可抗力 八、通知和送达 九、争议及解决 十、协议的生效、修改、变更与终止

鉴于: 1、中国移动通信集团广东有限公司潮州分公司(以下简称甲方)是中国移动通信集团广东有限公司在潮州市设立的、以经营GSM、TD-SCDMA(3G)基础电信业务为主的国有基础通信运营商,具有丰富的互联网出口带宽资源、众多优质客户资源,并具有强大的营销推广能力。 2、中国铁通集团有限公司潮州分公司(以下简称乙方)是中国移动通信集团下属子公司中国铁通集团有限公司在潮州市设立、以经营基础电信业务和增值电信业务的国有基础电信运营企业,提供本地电话业务、国内、国际长途电话业务、互联网业务、智能业务、出租电路业务、分组交换业务、网络资源出租、代维业务及综合信息服务业务等服务,具有较为丰富的网络资源和互联网宽带业务建设、推广能力。 3、广东省广播电视网络股份有限公司潮州分公司(以下简称丙方)是广东省广播电视网络股份有限公司在潮州市设立的,负责全市有线电视网络统一规划建设和经营管理的,是以广播电视节目传输为主业的大型现代化有线广电网络运营商,具有覆盖潮州的城域网和市区有线电视接入网络,具备高普及率的电视用户和抵达千家万户的线路资源,具有成熟的网络业务服务和运营体系。 三方依照优势互补、资源合作、平等互利、风险共担、共同发展的原则,在遵守国家相关法律法规的前提下开展业务合作,致力于共同开发潮州市媒体化和信息化市场。 经三方友好协商,达成本合作协议,以资共同遵守。 一、合作内容 1.1在我国“三网融合”政策的背景下,三方通过国家政策引导与优势互补相结合的模式,平等互利、共谋发展,进行战略合作,推动潮州市三网融合的发展,服务地方经济发展和精神文明建设。

销售框架合同

销售框架合同 买方:卖方: 指定联系人:指定联系人: 电话:电话: 住所:住所: 邮编:邮编: 开户银行:开户银行: 户名:户名: 帐号:帐号: 根据《中华人民共和国合同法》及其他有关法律、法规之规定,买卖双方经过平等协商,确认根据下列条款订立本合同,以资共同遵照执行。 一、货物清单及价格: 清单详见具体订货单 二、质量与技术标准和产品包装: 1、质量与技术标准:以符合货物说明书为准。 2、产品包装: (1)有原厂商包装的,按原厂商标准; (2)没有原厂商包装的,按卖方包装标准进行包装; 三、运输和运费承担: 根据工程进度表的约定,所有合同设备及技术文件将按买方要求分批发货。卖方负责从设备出厂到设备到达中国石油“分支机构”的全部步骤及所有费用。(分支机构定义:买方指定的地址) 卖方必须在到货前7天通知买方。 四、交货: 1、卖方于买方订货单下达后9周内交货 2、交货地点:详见附件二 (注:本合同未明确约定地址的,买方应提前十个工作日以盖章传真方式通知卖方;分批交货的或事先注明每次交货时间和地点,由买方每次以盖章传真方式提示;所有上述盖章传真件,买方均需将盖章原件于传真后邮寄至卖方)。 3、买方指定收货人:详细见具体订货单 联系方式:详细见具体订货单

护照号码:详细见具体订货单 买方指定收货人收货时必须携带护照,经货代核实身份后方可将货物交由指定收货人签收,并将指定收货人签署后的货物签收单原件交付卖方。货物签收单样本(附件三)将作为本合同附件附后。 在卖方交货过程中,买方提出变更收货人的,应提前十日书面通知卖方变更后的收货人姓名、联系方式(通讯地址、护照号码、联系电话和邮政编码等),卖方在收到前述买方书面通知之前有权向本合同所约定的收货人交货。 五、付款: 本合同项下货物的付款为指示性付款。即本合同的实际付款方为新加坡******股份有限公司香港分公司,买方在收到合同项下货物后向新加坡******股份有限公司香港分公司发出付款指示,由新加坡******股份有限公司香港分公司一次性付清。即新加坡******股份有限公司香港分公司仅为接收指示委托的付款方,本合同的全部实体权利义务仍买方和卖方实际享有。 付款: 1、指示性付款的条件:买方在签收货物之后十日内进行货物的开箱验收工作(买方需将货物验收单原件一份交付卖方),如无开箱即损(开箱即损要求按照***公司的规定执行)的情况发生,买方开箱验货后五日内向新加坡******股份有限公司香港分公司发出付款指示,即买方发出指示的最晚日期不得超过货物签收后的第十五日。 此外,关于***公司开箱即损的定义:开箱即损是指箱子外包装完好,但是开箱后发现设备本身有物理性损坏的,在出厂90天内可以向思科申请做开箱即损。物理性损坏一般指货物本身外观的损坏,而不是通电后的功能性损坏。 2、指示性付款的方式:买方向新加坡******股份有限公司香港分公司出具货物验收单和货物接受证明,同时将货物验收单和货物接受证明抄送卖方。货物验收单(附件五)和货物接受证明(附件六)样本将作为本合同附件附后。上述两文书的出具及送达视为买方要求新加坡******股份有限公司香港分公司向卖方付款的 指示。关于付款的详细约定见买方、卖方及新加坡******股份有限公司香港分公司签订的三方协议。 3、若无开箱即损的情况下,如在买方的指定收货人签收货物十五日后,买方无故不向新加坡******股份有限公司香港分公司发出付款指示,则本合同的付款方式由指示性付款自动变更为直接付款,即由买方直接向卖方付款。且卖方可按照本合同第八条的约定追究买方的违约责任。 4、若发现开箱即损的情况,按照本销售合同中的第六条第4款执行完成后,买方在收到货物的情况下,按照本销售合同和三方协议的要求履行付款责任。 此外,对于买、卖双方交接发票、结算票据事宜,双方一致认同:买方取得发票并不代表买方货款已付清。货款已付清以买方付款凭证时间为准,但该笔款项应在银行规定合理时间内到账。 六、设备验收和索赔: 1、卖方依据本协议交付的设备必须满足思科公司产品标准。 2、卖方应将思科公司出具的包括出厂前检验证明等原厂技术资料提供给买方。

营销推广活动服务合同

营销推广活动服务合同 以下是关于《营销推广活动服务合同》,供大家学习参考! 营销推广活动服务合同 合同编号: 委托方: ____________________________________________ 承办方: ____________________________________________ 依据《中华人民共和国合同法》、《中华人民共和国广告法》及相关法律、法规、规章的规定,甲、乙双方在平等、自愿的基础上,协商一致就甲方委托乙方承办_______________活动推广事宜达成如下合同条款,以资共同遵守。 条:推广活动概况 活动项目: _____________________________________________; 具体内容: _____________________________________________; 活动时间:; _____________________________________________ 活动地点:

_____________________________________________; 活动方案:执行方案及相关计划详见本合同“附件一 __________”,由乙方根据甲方要求策划、设计并经甲方确 认后执行; 前期准备:乙方进场准备时限自_____________至 _______________完成准备;乙方完成准备后,甲方应当及 时验收,若对相关质量及数量有异议,应当即提出;双方经核对活动方案及相关设计图纸后,如确有问题,乙方应该立即整改;如对活动效果产生不良影响,由乙方承担相关责任及损失,甲方有权按方案清单扣除相应费用。 其他约定 ________________________________________________。 第二条:合同价款及付款方式 合同价款总额为:人民币_________元,即大写人民币 __________圆整。除了经过甲方书面确认的可增加的费用外,本合同价款总额不因任何事由上浮,包括但不限于不可抗力、价格上涨等因素。 合同价款明细详见合同“附件二_____________”。该价款含人工费、道具费、场地费、交通费、政府报批收费、税金等一切乙方为了履行本合同项下委托事项所产生的费用。.本合同选择以下第_____种方式付款: A.推广活动全部完成并经甲方书面确认后,甲方一次性支

Sales Frame Contract框架合同

Sale Frame Contract / 销售框架合同 Contract No.合同编码: 卖方 Seller: 统一社会信用代码(Business License No.): 法人代表(Legal Representative): 地址: 买方 Buyer: 统一社会信用代码(Business License No.): 法人代表(Legal Representative): 地址: Article 1 Commodity, Type, Specifications and Quantity/ 商品,类型,规格和数量 The Buyer agrees to buy and the Seller agrees to sell the products, accessories and spare parts (as specified in the Appendix 1“Sales Order”hereinafter jointly refer red to as “Goods” or “Product”) subject to the terms and conditions of this Contract and its Appendices herein. 买方同意按照本合同及其附件规定的条款购买,并且卖方同意按照本合同及其附件规定的条款向买方销售产品, 配件和备件(简称“货物”或“产品”)。 Article 2 Price/ 价格 Unless as expressively agreed by both parties in the individual sales agreement by Seller and Buyer, the contract price hereunder (“Contract Price”) shall be the price Ex Warehouse of the Seller for the Goods as listed in the Sales Order, includingVAT and standard packaging costs. 除非买卖双方在作为本合同附件的单个协议中另有明确约定,货物价格(“合同价格”)为销售订单所定义的货物的卖方库房交货价格,包括增值税和标准包装成本。 Article 3Payment/ 付款 Unless as expressively agreed by both parties in the individual sales agreement by Seller and Buyer, the Buyer shall pay the total Contract Prices for the Goods to the Seller as per the following schedule:

审计战略合作框架协议

甲方 & 乙方 审计服务战略合作框架协议

审计服务战略合作框架协议有限公司(以下简称甲方) 法定代表人: 单位住址: 委托代理人: 联系电话: 会计师事务所(以下简称乙方)

法定代表人: 单位住址: 委托代理人: 联系电话: 一、总则 依据中华人民共和国合同法、审计法等相关法律法规规定, 甲乙双方为了长期合作、互惠互利、明确双方权利义务,经过双方友好、平等、公平、公证协商,达成以下审计服务战略合作框架协议,以昭信守,遵照执行。 二、战略合作方式 合作事项为乙方为甲方及其所属公司或关联单位提供审计服务事宜,合作战略期限为五年,该协议每年签订一次。 三、甲方权利与义务 1、甲方应向乙方说明审计工作要求,即具体审计事项及内容。 2、乙方按照甲方要求完成审计工作后,甲方应按照双方约定的审计服务费用和时间向乙方支付审计费用。

3、甲方有权根据自己工作需要变更审计内容。 4、审计服务费用结算时间: 四、乙方权利与义务 1、乙方应严格按照甲方的要求提供相关审计服务。 2、如果甲方变更审计服务内容,乙方应及时按照变更后的审计内容进行审计。 3、如果甲方因工作要求,需要乙方随时介入进行审计, 方应及时按照甲方要求及时进行审计,可以事后签订补充协议。 4、审计服务费用按照国家法律法规相关规定约定的标准折扣X%进行结算。 五、违约责任 甲乙双方按照《中华人民共和国合同法》的规定承担违约责任。 六、争议解决方式 本约定书的所有方面均应使用中华人民共和国法律进行解释并受其约束。本约定书履行地为乙方出具审计报告所在地,因本约定书所引起的或本约定书有关的任何纠纷或争议(包括关于本约定书条款的存在、效力或终止,或无效之后果),双方选择以下第(2)种解决方式: (1)向甲方有管辖权的人民法院提起诉讼; (2)提交西宁市仲裁委员会仲裁。 七、其他

项目合作框架标准协议书范本

编号:HZ-20219680 甲 方:______________________________ 乙 方:______________________________ 日 期:_________年________月_______日 项目合作框架标准协议书范本 The parties to a contract shall fully fulfill their obligations pursuant to the terms of the contract.

[标签: titlecontent] 甲方:XX 公司 住所地:XXXXXXXXXXXX____ 法定代表人:XXXXXXXXXXXX 联系电话:XXXXXXXXXXXX__ 乙方:XXX_电子信息技术有限公司项目合作框架协议住所地:XXXXXXXXXXXX____ 法定代表人:XXXXXXXXXXXX 联系电话:XXXXXXXXXXXX__ 鉴于乙方拥有XXXXXX_产品完整的所有权和知识产权、且至本协议签订之日未与任何他方就本产品、知识产权有任何形式的合作,乙方也未以任何方式生产和销售本产品;甲、乙双方经协商一致,在平等、自愿的基础上,就合作生产、销售由乙方自主研制的XXXXXX_产品项目达成本协议,以资共信守。 1.合作内容 本项目合作的内容为:生产、销售由乙方自主研制的XXXXXX_产品。首批生产XXX___套(其中XXX___系统XXX 套), 以后批产品生

产量根据市场销售情况待定。 2.合作期限 XXX___年____月____日到XXX___年____月____日,共XXX___年。 3.合作体制 在甲方框架内成立由乙方组建,甲方派员监督的XXX___产品项目部,其权限为负责本项目产品的生产、销售及售后服务。项目部设立独立帐户,实行独立核算。 4.知识产权的使用 4.1本项产品的生产、销售可使用乙方提供的中文:XXXXXX;英文:XXXXXX的注册商标。也可以使用甲方所提供的商标及冠名。 5.权益平衡 自本协议签订之日起,乙方不得独立或以任何方式与第三方合作生产、销售XXXXXX_产品。 甲方从合作之日起,按月向乙方提供资金XXXXXX万元,持续时间不超过XXX个月,且该资金纳入本项目产品的生产总成本。 6.甲方职责 6.1提供本合同项目生产、销售及售后服务的所需资金,前期投入不低于人民币XXXXXX万元(以后根据市情况待定)的基本运作资金,在本协议签订生效后的十个工作日内存入开列的XXX___项目部的独立帐户内,实行专款专用,保证该资金的投放与生产、销售及售后服务的进程同步,并即时派出财务人员管理并建立独立的帐目,及时制作月报及年报等财务文件交双方备案。

Premiere切换特效汇总

视频切换特效 1.( )使画面像纸一样被重复折叠从而显示另一画面。 2.( )使画面以屏幕的一边为中心从后方转出覆盖另一画面。 3.( )使画面以屏幕的一边为中心从前方转出覆盖另一画面。 4.( )使画面从屏幕的中心逐渐展开覆盖另一画面。 5.( )使画面从屏幕的中心旋转出现而覆盖另一画面。 6.( )使画面像窗帘一样被拉起出现另一画面。 7.( )使画面以立方体的两个面进行过渡转换。 8.( )使两个画面作为页面,通过翻转实现转换。 9.( )使画面从屏幕的中心旋转缩小消失,出现另一画面。 10.( )使画面以关门的方式覆盖另一画面。 11.( )使画面从中心以矩形不断放大覆盖另一画面。 12.( )使画面以十字形向外移动显示另一画面。 13.( )使画面以圆形逐渐放大覆盖另一画面。 14.( )使画面以一个或多个形状打开覆盖另一画面。 15.( )使画面以星形不断放大覆盖另一画面。 16.( )使画面以交叉点擦除显示另一画面。 17.( )使画面以菱形逐渐放大覆盖另一画面。 18.( )画面从屏幕中心逐渐向四角撕开并卷起显示另一画面。 19.( )画面以翻页的形式从一角卷起显示另一画面(背面为灰色)。 20.( )画面以卷纸的形式从一边卷起显示另一画面(卷轴)。 21.( )画面以透明翻页的形式从一角卷起显示另一画面。 22.( )画面在中心分成四块分别卷起显示另一画面。 23.( )淡入淡出效果。 24.( )画面以点的方式叠加后逐渐显示另一画面。 25.( )画面逐渐变白后,由白色逐渐显示另一画面。 26.( )两画面以加亮模式交叉叠加后逐渐显示另一画面。 27.( )画面以随机反色显示的形式消失,逐渐显示另一画面。 28.( )两画面以亮度叠加消融的方式切换。 29.( )画面逐渐变为黑色后,由黑色逐渐显示另一画面。 30.( )画面从不同方向挤压显示另一画面。 31.( )一个画面淡出,另一个画面放大流入。 32.( )一个画面在另一个画面中心横向伸展开来。 33.( )一个画面从一边以伸缩状展开覆盖另一个画面。 34.( )画面沿着“Z”字形交错扫过另一画面。 35.( )画面从中央以开关门的方式转到另一画面。 36.( )画面以棋盘状消失过渡到另一个画面。 37.( )画面从水平、垂直或者对角线的方向以条状覆盖另一画面。 - 1 -

印刷供应商年度合作框架协议范文

合同编号:【】 印刷供应商合作框架协议 甲方:【】 法定地址:【】 法定代表人:【】 联系人:【】 办公地址:【】 电话:【】 传真:【】 邮政编码:【】 乙方:【】 法定地址:【】 法定代表人:【】 联系人:【】 办公地址:【】 电话:【】 传真:【】 邮政编码:【】

甲方:(以下简称“甲方”) 乙方:(以下简称“乙方”) 甲乙双方经过友好协商,在相互信任、相互尊重和互惠互利的原则基础上,在符合双方共同利益的前提下,就印刷业务合作问题,自愿结成战略合作伙伴关系;实现双方与客户方的多赢局面。合作条款如下: 第一条、合作期限: 甲方同意乙方作为甲方的年度合作供应商,从本协议签订之日起至XX 年XX月XX 日。在合同期内若乙方执行情况优良,乙方可在合同到期后同等企业竞争条件下享有优先续签合同权利。 第二条、甲方的权利和义务: 1、在此合作框架协议基础上,甲方可以随时根据需要以下生产工程单形式委派 乙方按时完成印刷任务;在同等条件下,甲方也应优先考虑下单给合作供应商; 2、对于乙方所提供的产品,如因乙方原因造成,甲方有向乙方退货、换货的权 利; 3、因特殊原因甲方可要求乙方加急印刷或加班印刷,乙方不得向甲方加收费 用; 4、因业务需要,甲方可以要求乙方提供样品或进行打样,乙方须优先免费协 助打样工作; 5、甲方须按结算付款时间按时支付乙方相应货款。

第三条、乙方的权利和义务: 1、作为合作伙伴关系,乙方在必要的时候(主要以甲方客户考察工厂等情况为 主)需以甲方自有工厂的身份协助甲方进行业务关系开展。 2、乙方须保证甲方客户信息不外泄,不得干扰和抢占甲方客户市场,否则视为 违约。 3、乙方须积极配合甲方供货,优先安排生产甲方产品,乙方保证在规定交货期 内完成其印刷工作(甲方要求的交货期是经乙方同意并确认的)。因乙方原因导致印刷品不能及时完成而又未经甲方同意的,乙方应承担相应损失;4、乙方须保证所提供的产品的质量和售后服务,保证按照甲方的要求(以单个 项目合同或生产工程单要求为准)完成其委派的印刷品,并保证印刷品以加工样板为准(包括纸张、颜色、工艺等),质量符合甲方要求和同类产品行业国家标准。如印刷品未达到甲方要求,甲方有权拒收货物并要求重新印刷; 5、乙方提供市内送货服务,在规定时间内,将印刷品送到指定地点。 6、合作期间乙方未经甲方许可,不得擅自将该产品供应给其他公司用于甲方竞 争之项目,其中包括采购信息的保密; 7、合作期间,乙方有义务向甲方提供跟甲方经营项目相关的商业信息,包括同 行业竞争的询价信息; 8、同等条件下乙方须保证提供产品的价格为同类市场价格最低,保证在印刷价 格方面给予甲方最大的优惠(参见本协议附件二:《印刷加工报价框架协议》)。当因市场行情变动,乙方要进行价格调整前应首先第一时间提前以书面形式通知甲方。若因乙方原因导致甲方的价格损失应由乙方承担; 9、乙方在双方合作过程中,保证所适用的技术、资料、图片等不侵犯他人的知

网络营销战略合作协议书

网络营销战略合作协议书 甲方: 乙方: 签约时间: 签约地点:

甲方: 乙方: 甲、乙双方本着平等合作、互惠互利的原则,经友好协商,根据《中华人民共和国合同法》、《中华人民共和国广告法》等有关法律法规的规定,就甲方委托乙方作为甲方“XXX”的广告服务代理(包括平面创意、撰文、设计、策划)事宜,达成如下一致协议: 一、合作范围 甲方委托乙方作“XXX”项目的广告服务代理,全权负责本项目的广告创意、撰文、设计、策划等代理事宜。 二、合作期限 委托期为年月日至年月日。本协议所拟合作期限届满前一个月,经双方协商同意,双方可续签协议。 三、乙方工作内容 广告的创意、文案、软文撰写、设计、策划、影视创意、网络宣传炒作等事宜,包括楼盘VI、报纸广告、夹报、宣传单张、海报、楼书、房展、展厅、喷画、广告折页、杂志广告、DM、邀请函、贺卡、现场POP、户外广告等平面设计、影视创意、影视脚本、活动策划方案、形象策划方案。 四、双方合作方式:

甲、乙双方以第一个月作为合作试点,在完成第一个月合作后,甲、乙双方都有权对对方的工作情况、合作程度、是否违约等情况进行评判,以作为是否继续合作的基础。如甲、乙双方对对方的合作情况不满意,均有权解除余下时间的合作关系。 五、双方责任与权利 甲方的责任和权利: 1、双方合作期间,甲方应积极配合乙方,及时提供乙方所需的各类图片和文字资料,并应对上述资料的合法性、真实性、准确性和完整性负责,如因甲方提供的资料而引起的法律纠纷,其相关的一切责任由甲方负责。 2、甲方有权及时地对乙方所提交的广告方案、设计稿和其他书面工作文件以书面形式提出修改意见和建议,乙方据此进行修改、调整、直至甲方签字认可方可定稿。但甲方应尊重乙方的专业经验和知识,并应考虑乙方工作周期等因素,在乙方提交有关文件后,应及时、完整地以书面形式提出明确的意见,以便乙方有足够时间保质保量完成各项业务。 3、为避免多头决策而导致的工作质量、效率下降,甲方特指定 为其全权代表与乙方沟通,具体负责设计方案的审定,各种方案的确定,同时指定为其协助乙方款项的结算。 4、甲方应按照本协议的规定及时付款,以保证项目的正常进行。 5、甲方在提出各种正式建议与意见时,应采用包括传真在内的书面方式,

战略合作框架协议(最终版)

战略合作框架协议 ******- 甲方: 乙方: 鉴于甲方是以研发、制造、销售传统照明产品为主体的大型上市企业公司,在照明产品拥有完善的销售体系、网络和销售团队;乙方在LED产品或LED部件的研发、制造生产、品质控制及产品实现上拥有较强能力,能够为甲方提供较为雄厚的产品和技术支持。现甲乙双方经友好协商,秉着优势互补、共同发展、诚信合作的宗旨达成如下协议: 一、合作宗旨 1、双方在合作中建立的互信、惯例与默契是商业合作战略伙伴关系的基础,提高效率与共同发展是双方合作的目标和根本利益。 2、本协议的基本原则是自愿、双赢、互惠互利、相互促进、共同发展、保守秘密、保护协作市场。 3、充分发挥双方优势,优势互补,提高竞争力,合作互补开发、制造符合市场需求的产品。 4、本协议为框架协议,应是双方今后长期合作的指导性文件,也是双方签订相关合同的基础。 二、战略合作关系合作方式 1、战略合作方式 甲、乙双方各自建立专业的团队对合作内容进行不定期交流。乙

方通过甲方指定人员了解其所需LED产品或部件的市场信息、需求和有关资料信息,以及甲方以书面、口头或电子的形式提供给乙方的任何信息或数据,包括但不限于商业秘密、商业计划、客户信息、研究成果、技术诀窍、技术图纸、文件以及其它技术和商业信息,乙方对以上信息负严格保密责任。乙方向甲方提供乙方的产品信息(包括技术资料、技术图纸、技术更新和新产品信息)以及公司的产品动态和变化等相关情况。 2、双方合作内容 甲乙双方战略合作的具体内容(包括但不限于以下内容): (1)甲方根据其实际需求委托乙方开发和加工LED产品或部件。根据甲方的需求,乙方负责开发、制造或加工,同时确保品质质量、产量、交期及成本优势,所提供给甲方的产品是符合甲方要求并通过甲方标准验收的产品。双方将签订具体采购合同,对提供的时间、标准和要求进行确定。 (2)甲方根据不同客户实际情况,参加招投标和报价等。为顺利夺标和获得订单,根据竞争对手和投标以及订单实际情况,乙方根据自己的实际情况报出合理的价格和交货期,同时提供相关的技术资料和技术支持等,支持甲方投标和获得订单。乙方在报价有效期内确定的价格不得随意更改。甲方中标后,甲乙双方将根据实际标的另行签订产品买卖或定作合同,以确定双方的权利义务,合同付款方式以及其他条款应根据甲方与最终客户签订的合同条款确定,乙方保证付款方式以及其他条款应优于甲方最终与客户签订的合同,给予甲方足

框架合作协议书

合同编号: 经销商加盟合同书 甲方:XXXXX 法定代表人(或负责人): 注册地址: 联系人: 联系电话: 乙方(经销商): 法定代表人(或负责人): 注册地址: 联系人: 联系电话: 本着真诚合作、互惠互利的原则,甲乙双方经友好协商,就乙方加盟经销甲方代理之产品及其增值服务(以下简称产品)的事宜,达成以下协议(以下简称“本协议”)。 一、协议范围 (一)产品名称 (二)合作期限 合作期间按甲方与上游厂家合同内约定的期间执行。期满后若双方有续约意向的,在甲方与上游厂家续约后,双方则应在一个月内提出并重新签署合同。 (三)销售区域 甲方授权乙方为甲方代理产品的区域为:全国范围。 区域划分如下: 浙江/湖南/西安: 华东 华南 华北/东北 华中

1、未经甲方书面同意,乙方不得将此授权再授权、分授权给任何第三方。 2、乙方承诺,未经甲方书面授权,不以任何方式将产品销售或以其它方式转移到甲方授权销售区域外的其它流通领域;如乙方需通过互联网、电视购物或其它新出现的零售渠道销售产品,则需经甲方事先授权并由双方另行签订协议。 乙方有区域内分销权,并且协助甲方开拓负责区域内分销代理商,有区域内分销代理商的管理权与任免权,甲方不得在未通知乙方的情况下开拓乙方区域内分销代理商; 甲方承诺乙方为XXXXX区域酒店渠道唯一指定区域授权代理商,在合同期内甲方不得委托渠道内乙方以外的其他个人、公司或其他主体作为其代理商销售产品。 (四)销售任务 在合同有效期内,乙方承诺最低的经销产品数量为(大写:万)台。 浙江/湖南/西安:台 华东台 华南台 华北/东北台 华中台 (五)销售提成 提成按销售业绩净利润(按符合国家规定相关财务制度计算得出)的6%计提,具体用途及分配如下: 1)3%为营运费用(含税费、销售费用、佣金等),在次月二十日前结算并支付完毕; 2)2%每月结算一次,在次月二十日前结算并支付完毕; 3)1%在自然年半年度各0.5%,在一个月内支付完毕(半年度各0.5%)。 二、产品及包装 甲方承诺向乙方提供的产品为符合国家和生产企业标准的合格产品,若产品质量不合格,负责退货、换货费用由甲方承担。 乙方承诺自身及其自有零售店不购买或直接、间接地参与任何假冒、仿制或侵权产品的设计、制造、广告、销售和分销。 未经甲方事先书面授权,乙方不得对产品及其销售包装的任何部分进行任何变动,包括但不限于添加、减少或改变任何配件、软件或硬件等。

PR特效的应用

1.Brightness & Contrast(亮度与对比度) 本视频滤镜效果将改变画面的亮度和对比度。类似于电视中的亮度和对比度的调节,但在这里调整则是对滑块的移动, 2.Channel Mixer(通道合成器) 使用本视频滤镜效果,能用几个颜色通道的合成值来修改一个颜色通道。使用该效果可创建使用其他颜色调整工具很难产生的颜色调整效果,通过从每个颜色通道中选择其中一部分就能合成为高质量的灰度级图像,创建高质量的棕褐色或其他色调的图像,已经交换或复制通道, 3.Color Balance(色彩平衡) 本视频滤镜效果利用滑块来调整RGB颜色的分配比例,使得某个颜色偏重以调整其明暗程度。本过滤属于随时间变化的特技, 4.Convolution Kernel(回旋核心) 本视频滤镜效果使用一道内定的数学表达式,通过矩阵文本给内定表达式输入数据,来计算每个像素的周围像素的涡旋值,进而得到丰富的视频效果。可以从提供的模式菜单中选择数据模式进行修改,也可以重新输入新的值(只要效果认为在Convolution Matrix(回旋矩阵)文本框中,中心的数字为该像素的亮度计算值(所输入的数字会乘以像素的亮度值),周围的数字是该像素周围的像素所需要的计算值,在此框内所输入的数值会乘以周围像素的亮度值。 在Misc(杂项)框架中的Scale文本框中输入的数将作为除数,像素点包括周围像素点的像素点与输入给“环境中心像素点的数据矩阵”对应点的乘积之和为被除数。Offset文本框是一个计算结果的偏移量(与所得的商相加)。 所有数值允许的输入范围很大,可从-99999~999999,但实际使用的没有这么大,要根据演示效果而定。 假如发现定义的一套数据很实用,并且以后还要使用,可单击Save按钮将其存储起来,并记住文件夹和文件名(或存储到软盘上)。下次通过单击Load按钮将其装载到当前的数据定义格式中,即可使用。 假如想使用内定的图像转换数据格式,应该单击图7-20中间上方的按钮,从弹出的菜单中选择相应的选项。内定的图像转换数据格式是十分有用的工具,它可让图像变得模糊或清楚。为能充分说明问题,图7-21列出了几种典型的效果供参考。这是从图7-20中选择的典型代表。这些视频效果在制作静态图片的特别节目时非常有用。它类似于Adobe Photoshop 中的过滤效果,只是在这里用于电影制作方面。假如不了解Premiere这个绝活,可能还会想到使用Photoshop进行处理。而假如将一幅照片通过Photoshop加工后再用于电影制作,势必会造成磁盘空间上的浪费和时间浪费。在此可看出Premiere的高效能力。5.Extract(提取) 当想利用一张彩色图片作为蒙板时,应该将它转换成灰度级图片。而利用此视频滤镜效果,可以对灰度级别进行选择,达到更加实用的效果。图7-22是提取视频片断的蒙板成分的对话框。 有2个滑块,带有图线的2个黑3角的滑块用来选定原始画面中的被转换成白色的灰度,Softness滑块用来调节画面的柔和程度。通过Invert复选框可以将已定的灰度图片进行反相。左下角的黑色梯形图(反相时为白色)随着Softness的滑动而变化,当变为三角形时,表明已达到原始画面的效果;当为梯形时,表明对原始画面的明暗分界进行了改动。6.Levels(色彩级别) 本视频滤镜效果将画面的亮度、对比度及色彩平衡(包括颜色反相)等参数的调整功能组合在一起,更方便地用来改善输出画面地画质和效果。图7-23是其调整对话框。

销售战略合作协议(正式版)范本

YOUR LOGO 如有logo可在此插入合同书—CONTRACT TEMPLATE— 精诚合作携手共赢 Sincere Cooperation And Win-Win Cooperation

销售战略合作协议(正式版)范本 The Purpose Of This Document Is T o Clarify The Civil Relationship Between The Parties Or Both Parties. After Reaching An Agreement Through Mutual Consultation, This Document Is Hereby Prepared 注意事项:此协议书文件主要为明确当事人或当事双方之间的民事关系,同时保障各自的合法权益,经共同协商达成一致意见后特此编制,文件下载即可修改,可根据实际情况套用。 协议各方当事人 甲方:xx公司法定代表人:住址:邮编:联系电话: 乙方:×××集团公司法定代表人:住址:邮编:联系电话: 本战略合作协议由上列各方于 鉴于:1、xx公司(以下简称某公司)是国内领先的xx产品(或服务)供应商。2、×××集团公司(以下简称××公司)销售磁条卡、智能卡、智能卡终端接口产品、校园系统集成、发卡系统及设备、安全认证产品等,向顾客提供该产品最为全面的基本卡及智能卡解决方案,业务涉及金融、公交、社保、校园、电子政务、高速公路等领域。3、双方都拥有良好的品牌形

象、销售通路和客户资源,双方产品具有较强的互补性和兼容性。故此,双方根据《中华人民共和国协议法》及其他相关法律,本着平等互利的原则,就建立战略合作伙伴关系的规则等相关事宜,双方经协商一致,达成战略合作协议,协议如下: 第一条合作宗旨双方希望通过建立密切、长久及融洽的战略合作伙伴关系,充分发挥各自网络和业务特点,在业务捆绑、市场营销、产业推动等多个领域开展强强合作,实现资源共享、优势互补,共同促进双方产品与服务的延伸和发展。 第二条合作领域双方一致同意致力于在以下产品或服务领域建立全面、深入的战略合作伙伴关系:1、2、 第三条合作内容双方一致同意以各自的资源和专业技术及经验为基础,在前述产品或服务领域的宣传推广、产品开发与支持、客户服务、网络支持、信息转接等方面进行广泛合作,共同开拓市场。1、双方认

相关文档
最新文档