企业税收筹划外文翻译文献

企业税收筹划外文翻译文献

企业税收筹划外文翻译文献

(文档含中英文对照即英文原文和中文翻译)

Corporate Tax-Planning Effectiveness: The Role of Compensation-Based

Incentives (Ⅰ)

John D. Phillips University of Connecticut

ABSTRACT

This study investigates whether compensating chief executive officers and

business-unit managers using after-tax accounting-based performance measures leads to lower effective tax rates, the empirical surrogate used for tax-planning effectiveness. Utilizing proprietary compensation data obtained in a survey of corporate executives, the relation between effective tax rates and after-tax performance measures is modeled and estimated using a two-step approach that corrects for the endogeneity bias associated with firms' decisions to compensate managers on a pre- versus after-tax basis. The results are consistent with the hypothesis that compensating business-unit managers, but not chief executive officers, on an after-tax basis leads to lower effective tax rates.

KEYWORDS tax planning; performance measures; endogenous treatment effects.

I. INTRODUCTION

Effective tax planning, defined by Scholes et al. (2002) as tax planning that maximizes the firm's expected discounted after-tax cash flows, requires managers to consider their decisions' after-tax consequences. In this paper, I investigate whether after-tax accounting-based performance measures lead to lower effective tax rates (ETR), my empirical surrogate for tax planning effectiveness.1 The ETR, an income-statement-based outcome measure calculated as the ratio of total income tax expense to pre-tax income, generally measures the effectiveness of tax reduction strategies that lead to higher after-tax income. A lower ETR, however, can only proxy for tax savings and does not always imply that after-tax income and/or cash flows have been maximized.2 Despite this limitation, the ETR has been used to measure the effectiveness of spending on the tax function (Mills et al. 1998) and corporate tax department performance (Douglas et al. 1996). Also, lowering the ETR is frequently cited as a way to increase earnings (e.g., Ziegler 1997) and increase share price (e.g., Mintz 1999; Swenson 1999).

Accounting research has addressed the relation between accounting-based compensation and managers' actions (e.g., Larcker 1983; Healy 1985; Wallace 1997). This paper is the first to address whether after-tax accounting-based performance measures motivate managers to take actions that help lower their firms' ETR and does so at both the chief executive officer (CEO) and business-unit (SBU) manager levels.

Prior after-tax performance measure research has focused only on the determinants of compensation CEOs using pre- versus after-tax earnings (e.g., Newman 1989; Carnes and Guffey 2000; Atwood et al. 1998; Dhaliwal et al. 2000) and provides no evidence concerning after-tax compensation's effectiveness in lowering a firm's tax liability. Extending this investigation to the SBU level is motivated out of the apparent conflict between arguments that taxes should be allocated to SBU for incentive compensation purposes (e.g., McLemore 1997) with empirical observations that a majority of firms do not do so (e.g., Douglas et al. 1996).4 The current investigation provides evidence concerning the incremental effectiveness of explicitly motivating CEOs and SBU managers to incorporate tax consequences into their operating and investment decisions.

A common issue in cross-sectional studies that attempt to link a particular management accounting choice to an outcome measure is that all sample firms may be optimizing with respect to the choice being investigated (Ittner and Larcker 2001). Without addressing the endogeneity of a firm's choice, it is difficult to provide evidence consistent with this choice leading to an improved outcome. To address this issue, the relation between ETR and CEO and SBU-manager after-tax performance measures is estimated using a two-step approach that helps correct for the potential endogeneity bias associated with these two choice variables. As a first step in implementing this approach, the Antle and Demski (1988) controllability principle is used to model a firm's decisions to adopt after-tax CEO and SBU-manager performance measures. To include a particular measure in a manager's compensation contract, this principle requires that the expected benefits from holding a manager responsible for a measure must be greater than the additional wage that must be paid to compensate the manager for the resulting additional risk and effort. Accordingly, an after- tax performance measure should be used as a contracting variable in a manager's incentive compensation contract only if the manager's involvement in tax-planning efforts leads to a difference between pre-tax and after-tax accounting results, which is generally reflected in the ETR. Consistent with prior research, the pre- versus after-tax CEO and SBU-manager selection models include variables that control for a firm's tax-planning opportunities because the presence of such opportunities reflect the extent to which a manager's actions can be expected to lower the ETR.

Even if a manager's efforts are expected to lead to a lower ETR, a firm will use an after-tax performance measure only if the expected benefits exceed the expected

costs of doing so. An after-tax performance measure is expected to lead to a lower ETR because it motivates the manager's increased cooperation with tax professionals to help identify, develop, and execute tax-planning strategies. McLemore (1997, 1) cites Hewlett Packard's tax director to support the need for SBU-manager involvement in tax-planning efforts:

Tax planning is only as good as being involved in the early stages of such things as business planning, strategic planning, and merger and acquisition work....Your tax department has to be represented at the table when those decisions are made. The evolving model for the future is the tight integration of tax people with business unit planning.

Costs associated with using after-tax performance measures include the additional wage that must be paid to compensate the manager for the increased risk due to potential tax law changes and the increased effort that results from including income tax expense in the compensation contract. Other potential costs associated with after-tax compensation include the administrative cost of allocating tax expense to a firm's SBU, increased tax examination costs, and increased tax authority scrutiny. Contrary to measuring after-tax compensation's benefits via observed ETR, there are no clear empirical surrogates for after-tax performance measures' costs. This study thus focuses on the realized benefits of compensating managers on an after-tax basis but does not provide evidence of the associated costs' magnitude.

Proprietary data obtained in a survey of corporate executives are used to construct certain test variables, including those indicating whether CEOs and SBU managers are compensated using after-tax accounting-based performance measures. Publicly available data are used to construct ETR and other test variables. The results are consistent with the hypothesis that compensating SBU managers, but not CEOs, on an after-tax basis leads to lower ETR, resulting in an estimated median tax savings of $13.3 million annually. Sensitivity tests performed on a subsample of firms with high simulated MTR (Graham 1996) provide further evidence that low-MTR firms' potential ETR-lowering actions that could have ambiguous effects on cash flows and after-tax profits are not driving this result. Further sensitivity tests help rule out the proportion of tax function outsourcing as an alternative explanation for the statistically and economically significant negative relation between after- tax SBU-manager compensation and ETR.

The results contribute to the accounting-based compensation literature by linking after- tax accounting-based performance measures to SBU-manager involvement that is incrementally effective in lowering firms' ETR. Consistent with Guidry et al. (1999) who document bonus-induced earnings management at the SBU level, this finding provides additional insight into the effect that SBU-manager accounting-based incentives have on managers' actions. Also, the estimated explicit tax savings resulting from after-tax performance measures provide corporate decision makers with information relevant to the design of SBU-manager incentive compensation plans.

The paper proceeds as follows. The next section sets forth the hypotheses tested in this study. Section III outlines the empirical models and estimation procedures used in testing these hypotheses. Section IV provides a discussion of the data and sample, including a brief overview of the survey used to obtain proprietary compensation data. Results are presented in Section V. The final section provides the conclusion and a discussion of the study's limitations.

II. HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT

Newman (1989), Cares and Guffey (2000), and Atwood et al. (1998) investigate firms' choices of after-tax earnings as the contracting variable in CEO bonus plans. These studies hypothesize that firms with greater tax-planning opportunities, consistent with the Antle and Demski (1988) controllability principle, are more likely to use after-tax performance measures. Using proxies for tax-planning opportunities, these studies collectively find that multinational status, number of operating segments, firm size, and capital intensity are positively associated with after-tax CEO compensation. Atwood et al. (1998) also presents evidence that leverage is negatively associated with this choice.

企业税收筹划的有效性:基于对报酬的激励作用(上)

约翰D·菲利普斯康涅狄格大学

摘要

本研究探讨首席执行官是否修正主管和业务部门经理利用税后会计为基础的绩效措施,导致较低的实际税率,以报酬激励用于税收筹划的有效性。企业的主管由于被激励获得的专有报酬的数据,运用建模和估计这两个步骤来研究有效税率和税后性能指标之间的关系来更正企业的管理人员的决定,以修正相关的内生性偏置前与后的计税基础。结果与假设一致修正了业务部门经理,但是没有修正主管,关于税后导致较低的实际税率。

关键词税收计划;性能指标;内源性的处理效果

引言

有效的税收筹划,根据斯科尔斯等人的定义(2002),税收筹划,即最大限度地提高公司的预期税后净现金流量,要求管理者要考虑他们的决定所造成的税后结果。在本文中,研究是否以税后会计为基础的绩效措施,将导致较低的实际出口退税税率。实际的经验替代了出口退税的税务规划效力,一个基础的收入结果被合适的计量,所得税费用总额作为税前收入的一定比例,通常测量减税策略将导致更高的税后收入的有效性。较低的出口退税,然而,仅能够代理节税以及通常并不意味税后收入或者是现金流已经达到最大值。尽管有这一局限性,出口退税还是被用来衡量税收功能性支出的有效性(米尔斯,1998)和企业各部门税

务绩效(道格拉斯,1996)。另外,降低出口退税是经常被作为一种增加收入(齐格勒,1997)和使股价上升的手段(e.g. Mintz 1999; Swenson 1999)。

会计研究处理了以会计绩效为基础的薪酬和经理的行为之间的关系(e.g., Larcker 1983; Healy 1985; Wallace 1997),本文是第一个从事这方面研究的文章:是否以税后会计为基础的绩效管理措施鼓励经理人员采取行动来降低他们公司的出口退税,并且首席执行官和事业部经理也要求做。在此之前的税后业绩计量研究只集中于首席执行官们的报酬的决定因素为预先的税后收益 (e.g., Newman 1989; Carnes and Guffey 2000; Atwood et al. 1998; Dhaliwal et al. 2000),没有提供任何证据说明降低一个公司的税务负担与税后报酬的关系。这项调查扩展到了事业部层次,这些部门的报酬激励动机与减少税收的目的目的之间存在明显的冲突(e.g., McLemore1997)以及观察的经验是,大多数企业没有这样做(e.g., Douglas et al. 1996)。目前的研究提供的证据关于明确激励首席执行官和事业部管理人员纳入其经营和投资决策的税务结果的增量效益。

以某个侧面来研究出口退税与管理层薪酬的共同课题,衡量的结果是所有样本公司可优化关于被调查的选择(Ittner and Larcker2001)。如果不解决公司选择的内生性,很难提供一致的证据关于这选择导致改善的结果。为了解决这个问题,首席执行官和事业部经理关于税后绩效与出口退税的联系依旧采用两步方式估计,可以帮助对潜在的内生性与相关偏见这两个变量做出正确的选择。作为实施这一方法的第一步,the Antle and Demski (1988) 可控性原则是用来模拟一个公司的决定,通过对首席执行官和事业部经理税后绩效指标的衡量。要包括一个特别措施在经理人的薪酬合同中,这一原则要求持有一个衡量预期收益和负责任的经理更加努力工作来规避所支付的附加工资之间的额外风险。因此,税后绩效指标应作为一个激励经理人的获取额外报酬的方法,只有当经理的税务规划工作的参与导致了税前和税后核算结果之间的差异,这通常反映在出口退税上面。与以前的研究相一致,包括与首席执行官和事业部经理选择税后模型的变量,对于一个企业的税务筹划的机会控制,因为这种机会的存在会在某种程度上反映了经理人的行动,可以预期,将会降低出口退税。

即使通过经理人的努力,预计将导致较低的出口退税,公司将使用税后绩效指标只有当预期收益超过预期成本才这样做,税后业绩措施预计会导致较低的出口退税,因为它促使管理人员和税务专业人员加强合作以达成一致的,发展的,执行税收筹划策略,McLemore (1997, 1)引用惠普公司的税务主任支持税务规划工作需要事业部经理参与的必要性:

税收筹划这种事情也只有在被作为业务规划的早期阶段,战略上的规划,兼

并和收购工作……你的税务部门要在会议上,代表这些部门做出决定。对未来的发展模式是税务策划人与业务部门紧密合作完成的。

与使用税后业绩的措施有关的费用包括附加工资必须支付给经理以弥补由于潜在的税法变化增加的风险,使经理加倍的努力,包括,从合同中补偿个人所得税方面费用的增加的结果。与税后报酬有关的其他潜在费用包括向一个公司的事业部分配行政费用开支,税务检查成本增加,并增加税务机关审查频率。相反,通过观察出口退税的好处来衡量税后报酬,有没有税后业绩计量的成本效益明显的有经验代理人。因此,本研究着重于在管理者的基础上实现的税后补偿效益,但不提供相关的成本,规模的证据。

在企业主管的调查中所获得的专有数据用于构造并测试某些变量,说明是否包括那些首席执行官和事业部的经理们使用税后会计基础的绩效指标。公开数据用于构造出口退税和其他变量来测试,结果与假设一致,即事业部经理的报酬,但不包括公司首席执行官的,与税后导致较低的出口退税有关,估计使每年平均节省1330万美元的税款。模拟公司进行敏感性测试的子样本中,边际税率(Graham 1996)提供进一步的证据表明,低边际税率的公司将会有降低潜在出口退税的行动,可能对现金流量和税后利润不吻合这一结果产生模棱两可的影响。敏感性测试有助于进一步排除了税收职能外包的比例,作为另一种解释,统计上和经济上显示事业部经理的税后报酬和出口退税呈负相关。

研究结果有助于薪酬以会计为基础的著作,通过实施事业部经理参与的以税后会计为基础的绩效措施,是逐步降低企业出口退税的有效措施。符合Guidry et al. (1999)表明了奖金导致事业部盈余管理水平的不同,这一发现提供了更多的有洞察力的影响,事业部经理以会计绩效为基础对管理人员的行为进行激励。另外,明确的表明企业的决策者设计降低所得税费用的公司税后业绩会使管理层人员获得更多薪酬的措施来激励事业部经理。

该文章的过程如下:下一节阐述了在这项研究中测试的假设。第三节概述了经验模型和估计程序在测试中使用的一些假说。第四节提供了数据和样本的讨论,包括用于获得所有的用于调查的报酬数据的简要概述。结果列于第五章最后一节提供了一个结论,即关于该研究的局限性的讨论。

II. 假说发展

Newman (1989), Cares and Guffey (2000), and Atwood et al. (1998)调查作为税后盈利企业对首席执行官奖金计划包含变量的选择。这些研究假设,企业有更大的税收筹划的机会,与Antle and Demski (1988)的可控性原则一致,更有可能

使用税后业绩的措施。利用税收筹划的机会代理,这些研究都发现了跨国公司的地位,经营分部的数量,企业规模,首席执行官的报酬和资本密集度呈正相关,Atwood et al. (1998)还提出证据,充分利用这一负相关的选择。

Corporate Tax-Planning Effectiveness: The Role of Compensation-Based

Incentives (Ⅱ)

John D. Phillips University of Connecticut

Dhaliwal et al. (2000) also focuses on the relation between a firm's tax-planning opportunities and the decision whether to use after-tax earnings in CEO bonus plans, but measures planning opportunities using only realized tax credits and absolute values of firms' permanent book-tax differences. They exclude temporary book-tax differences such as those resulting from accelerated tax depreciation because these differences do not impact a firm's after-tax accounting earnings, the performance measure used in after-tax accounting-based bonus plans. Similarly, the ETR used in the current study is computed using total tax expense in the numerator, thereby excluding the effects of

temporary book-tax differences.

Consistent with prior literature, Dhaliwal et al. (2000) find that firms with greater tax credits and absolute values of permanent book-tax differences are more likely to compensate their CEOs on an after-tax basis. Because permanent differences can either increase or decrease taxable income relative to book income, they provide no direct evidence of an association between after-tax CEO compensation and lower ETR. The current study investigates this relation between after-tax CEO compensation and ETR. The first hypothesis, stated in alternative form is:

H1: Using after-tax performance measures in CEO accounting-based bonus plans leads to lower ETR.

This paper also extends the pre- versus after-tax compensation analysis to SBU-manager incentive compensation plans. The need for SBU-manager involvement in tax-planning efforts is consistent with the coordination task that arises when specialists require input and cooperation from non specialists (Milgrom and Roberts 1992). The firm's tax professionals not only need help from the firm's SBU managers in the identification of tax-planning opportunities, but also their cooperation in developing and executing strategies to capitalize on such opportunities.

In the context of lowering the ETR and increasing after-tax accounting income, how do SBU managers participate in efforts that increase tax credits and lead to permanent differences that lower taxable income? Colgate-Palmolive's CFO states that "Colgate man- agers routinely watch for ways to time remittances from overseas [which leads to higher foreign tax credits], maximize research and development tax credits...." (Mintz 1999, 2.) SBU managers can also help tax professionals formulate transfer prices (Ernst & Young 1999), which helps lower the ETR by decreasing (increasing) income reported in countries with tax rates in excess of (lower than) the U.S. tax rate.5 Other examples of SBU-manager involvement that helps lower the ETR include (1) determining whether a potential employee qualifies for a payroll-based tax credit before the hiring decision is made, (2) consulting with the firm's tax professionals prior to domestic location decisions to incorporate varying state and local tax rates as a factor in such decisions, and (3) helping tax professionals gather data necessary to document tax return reporting positions.

The above discussion suggests that SBU-manager involvement is helpful in lowering the ETR. It is possible that the pre- versus after-tax nature of the CEO's

旅游服务贸易外文翻译文献

旅游服务贸易外文翻译文献(文档含英文原文和中文翻译)

旅游服务贸易的国际竞争力:罗马尼亚的案例 引言 旅游业是唯一的可以为任何发展水平的国家提供贸易机会的服务活动。然而,它也是一个很大程度因为国家的能力和在全球经济中的表现而又有明确的利益分配不均行业,而这又需要提高自己的竞争力。 自20世纪90年代初,罗马尼亚旅游业经历了出口量,生长速率和结构的重大变化。这些不同的波动都影响了罗马尼亚在国际旅游市场上相对的竞争地位并引起了其旅游贸易平衡的变化。同时,新的和更多的错杂的欧式建筑,引起了罗马尼亚的区域旅游竞争力的显著变化。 在此背景下,本文试图提出一个框架,以竞争力和旅游贸易表现之间的关系为重点,来评估罗马尼亚的旅游服务贸易的国际竞争力。 一、国际竞争力视角:国际竞争力之与国际旅游业的相关性 国际竞争力的概念,尽管有争议,难以捉摸,但现在已经得到认可,并继续吸引世界各地的学者和决策者的关注。 到目前为止,为提高国际竞争力已采取措施,都被认为是在经济层面进行的(加瑞利,2003)通常是指一个国家生产的商品和服务,以满足国际市场的考验,并同时保持和增加公民的收入的能力(欧洲委员会,2007)。 由于竞争力最终取决于一国企业在国内和国际的市场成功,所以对竞争力的注意力都集中在企业层面的竞争力上(波特,1990),对于此的普遍理解是指“……该公司保持,并更好的是,扩大其全球市场份额,增加和扩大利润的能力” (克拉克和盖,1998, 经济合作与发展组织,1993)。 因此,虽然广泛流传但是国际竞争力作为与国家经济和其国际贸易相关

的理论基础已经不太在学术文献进行分析。因此,一个国家国际竞争力的性质,效益和局限性仍然含糊不清(科尔德威尔,2000,克鲁格曼,1994, 1996)。 国际竞争力,是指一个国家在货物和服务贸易方面巩固和保持贸易优势相对于世界其他地区的贸易优势。 每当一个国家的经济福利通过贸易流量的增加,或通过从初始平衡状态的贸易条件的改变而增加,他的国际竞争力都会得到提高(科尔德威尔,2000)。 贸易理论表示,经济福利依赖于一个国家有比较优势的货物和服务的生产。这实际上意味着当生产符合一国的比较优势的情况时国际竞争力能得到保障。如果一国能在国际上表现良好并在出口市场竞争成功,这可能就是他们健全的国际竞争力的标志。 因此,在国际上,竞争力定义为一个经济体能够吸引其出口需求和投资供给需求的能力和在所有社会规范内提升公民生活水平的能力。这反过来又取决于宏观和微观经济政策,影响生产的经济生产率要素和经营成本的法规和制度。 一个可用的文献回顾和实证证据支持国际竞争力可以解释为在一定程度上,一个国家的出口能力这一观点(道乐和沃尔夫,1993, 格博格等. 2004)。还有就是,事实上,是出口表现和国际竞争力之间的循环关系。出口是国际竞争力的第一衡量指标。出口情况的改善会导致了一个国家的竞争力提升。这种效果是一个企业的技能,知识,创新和运用新技术并能够在一个成功的商业方式中利用技术机会等的结果。 另一方面,为了在竞争激烈的全球市场努力成功实现出口,一个国家被迫提高竞争力。更具竞争力的国家,它的经济更强大。因此,它更有能力在全球市场竞争,以吸引具有较高的知识,技能,水平人们去购买新技术等,

企业员工福利外文翻译文献

企业员工福利外文翻译文献 (文档含中英文对照即英文原文和中文翻译) 译文: 西方企业员工福利满意度研究述评 摘要:近年来,西方企业管理学界越来越重视员X-福利满意度理论研究,因为员工的福利满意度会直接影响他们的工作态度、工作行为与企业经营管理工作的效果。本文概述了西方企业员工福利满意度理论研究的现状,并根据组织公平理论和双因素理论,探讨福利管理决策公平与不同类型的福利对员工满意度的影响,最后为我国企业加强福利管理工作提出了若干建议。 关键词:福利;满意度;组织公平;双因素理论 一、企业福利政策的发展趋势 福利是员工薪酬的一个重要组成部分。近年来,越来越多的企业为员工提供良好的福利待遇,以便吸引、激励并留住优秀员工。企业的福利政策出现了以下发展趋势:(1)福利在员工薪酬组合中的比重增大,企业支付的福利费用大幅增加。 (2)员工也必须承担部分福利费用。企业以往为员工免费提供所有福利。目前,许

多员工必须承担部分医疗保险、养老保险费用。(3)企业的福利制度越来越复杂,福利形式越来越多样化,管理人员需要花费更多的时间与精力来从事员工福利制度设计与管理工作。许多企业在制定与实施福利制度时较少考虑员工的反应。例如,有些企业为了降低福利费用,采用灵活的福利制度,或将部分福利管理工作外包给其他公司,而不考虑员工是否满意。许多欧美学者认为,企业管理人员在制定与实施福利制度时必须考虑员工的反应。他们的实证研究表明,员工对福利的满意度会直接影响企业福利制度的效果。 二、员工福利满意度理论研究概述 20世纪60年代以来,西方企业管理学界对员工薪酬理论进行了大量的研究。然而,企业管理学者却较少研究员工福利理论。在现有文献中,欧美学者主要从福利的激励作用、员工对福利计划的理解和偏好、福利与员工薪酬满意度的关系、员工的福利满意度等方面研究员工福利理论。美国学者威盛顿(Barton I。.Weathington)和坦切克(I。ois E.Tetrick)指出,企业管理学界在员工福利这个领域的研究成果存在以下不足:(1)许多学者实际上是研究员工的薪酬满意度或工作满意度,而不是研究员工的福利;(2)大多数学者只研究福利对员工的影响,却忽视各类福利对员工工作态度和工作行为的影响;(3)企业管理理论研究人员主要从企业的角度来研究福利制度,却很少考虑员工对福利的态度。近年来,西方企业管理学界逐渐加强了对员工福利满意度的研究。 I.员工福利满意度的计量 1985年,美国学者赫尼曼(Herbert G.Heneman)和希沃布(Donald P.Schwab)编制了一个由18个计量项目组成的“员工薪酬满意度”量表(pay satisfaction questionnaire,简称PSQ)。他们采用以下四个项目来计量员工的“福利满意度”: (1)员工对整套福利的满意度; (2)员工对企业支付的福利费用数额的满意度; (3)员工对福利价值的满意度; (4)员工对福利类别的满意度。 许多欧美企业管理学者在实证研究中把员工的福利满意度作为薪酬满意度的一个组成成分,采用PSQ量表计量员工的福利满意度。 现在,许多欧美学者对员工的福利满意度进行更深入的研究。不少学者认为员工福利满意度是一个多维概念。美国学者戴恩霍(Carol Danehower)与勒斯特(John A.I.ust)指出,员工的福利满意度应包括员工对企业支付的福利费用与企业为他们提供的整套福利的质量的满意度。他们设计了一个由11个项目组成的员工福利满意度量表(benefit satisfaction ques—tionnaire,简称BSQ),从上述两个方面来计量员工的福利满意度。他们的一系列实证研究支持员工的福利满意度是一个二维概念的结论。然而,他们也发现BSQ量表中的某些项目不能很好地计量员工对福利质量的满意度。因此,他们对BSQ量表进行了适当的修改,又增加了两个项目,并于1995年对美国某大学的2 815位员工进行了问卷调查。他们的数据分析结果表明,新的BSQ量表中的13个项目分别属于员工对福利质量的满意度、对福利费用的满意度、对福利信息的满意度三个维度。他们根据数据分析结果,指出员工的福利满意度是一个复杂的多维概念。但是,加拿大学者特兰布雷(Michel Tremblay)等人的实证研究结果并不支持戴恩霍和勒斯特的观点。他们发现,员工的福利满意度是一个单维概念。美国学者米塞利(Marcia P.Miceli)和雷恩(Matthew C.Lane)把员工福利满意度分为两类:一类是员工对福利水平的满意度,它受员工感觉中“应该得到”与“实际得到”的福利之差的影响;另一

零售企业营销策略中英文对照外文翻译文献

零售企业营销策略中英文对照外文翻译文献(文档含英文原文和中文翻译)

译文: 零售企业的营销策略 Philip Kotlor 今天的零售商为了招徕和挽留顾客,急欲寻找新的营销策略。过去,他们挽留顾客的方法是销售特别的或独特的花色品种,提供比竞争对手更多更好的服务提供商店信用卡是顾客能赊购商品。可是,现在这一切都已变得面目全非了。现在,诸如卡尔文·克连,依佐和李维等全国性品牌,不仅在大多数百货公司及其专营店可以看到,并且也可以在大型综合商场和折扣商店可以买到。全国性品牌的生产商为全力扩大销售量,它们将贴有品牌的商品到处销售。结果是零售商店的面貌越来越相似。 在服务项目上的分工差异在逐渐缩小。许多百货公司削减了服务项目,而许多折扣商店却增加了服务项目。顾客变成了精明的采购员,对价格更加敏感。他们看不出有什么道理要为相同的品牌付出更多的钱,特别是当服务的差别不大或微不足道时。由于银行信用卡越来越被所有的商家接受,他们觉得不必从每个商店赊购商品。 百货商店面对着日益增加的价格的折扣店和专业商店的竞争,准备东山再起。历史上居于市中心的许多商店在郊区购物中心开设分店,那里有宽敞的停车场,购买者来自人口增长较快并且有较高收入的地区。其他一些则对其商店形式进行改变,有些则试用邮购盒电话订货的方法。超级市场面对的是超级商店的竞争,它们开始扩大店面,经营大量的品种繁多的商品和提高设备等级,超级市场还增加了它们的促销预算,大量转向私人品牌,从而增加盈利。 现在,我们讨论零售商在目标市场、产品品种和采办、服务以及商店气氛、定价、促销和销售地点等方面的营销策略。 一、目标市场 零售商最重要的决策时确定目标市场。当确定目标市场并且勾勒出轮廓时,零售商才能对产品分配、商店装饰、广告词和广告媒体、价格水平等作出一致的决定。如沃尔玛的目标市场相当明确:

公司治理相关文献综述

《公司治理机制理论研究文献综述》-郑志刚 公司治理机制是解决现代公司由于控制权和所有权分离所导致的代理问题的各种机制的总称,它既包括公司治理的法律和政治途径、产品和要素市场竞争、公司控制权市场、职业关注等外部控制系统,同时包括激励合约设计、董事会、大股东治理、债务融资等内部控制系统。 研究意义 公司治理所要研究和解决的问题是如何使资金的提供者按时收回投资并获得合理的回报。它构成建立在高度专业化分工基础上的现代公司制度运行的核心。对公司治理问题的研究显然对于提高中国现代公司的治理效率,从而最终推进企业改革不仅具有重要的理论意义,同时还具有重要的现实意义。 一、外部控制系统 外部控制系统指的是尽管机制的实际实施超出了公司资源计划的范围,仍然可以用来实现公司治理目标的各种公司治理机制总称,它包括公司治理的法律和政治途径、产品和要素市场竞争、公司控制权市场、声誉市场等。 1.公司治理的法律和政治途径 ①公司治理的法律途径在公司治理机制中处于基础性地位。 ②此外,政治因素的考虑对一国法律的制定产生深刻的影响。由于对于大多数国家的法律而言,对雇员的保护与对投资者的保护负相关,因而,法律规定是谋求高投资者保护程度的企业家与谋求高雇员保护程度的雇员的政治妥协。 ③公司治理体系的不同更多的是意识形态的因素,而不是单纯由经济因素造成的。 2.产品和要素市场竞争

①产品(要素)市场竞争不仅是市场经济条件下,改善整体经济效率十分强大的力量,同时,它在公司治理方面也发挥重要作用 ②产品和要素市场的监督力量对于新的和存在因量经济租或准租的活动而言十分微弱。 3.公司控制权市场 所谓的公司控制权市场是指建立在现代放熟的资本市场的有效运作基础之上,通过包括公司舞管、杠杆收购以及公司重组等在内的公司战略而实现的公司资产控制权力转移的各种市场行为的总称。这里的接管包括兼并、敌意和友好要约收购以及代理权竞争等。 接管实际发生的另一个必要条件是,接管者能够战胜目标公司经理人的“反接管”措施。 对接管的主要批评是,接管的收益来自享受的税收优惠、与原公司经理人、雇员终止合同,以及非效率的资本市场在价值评估中的错误 对以接管为代表的公司控制权市场的争论表明,公司控制权市场单独同样不是一个约束经理人的有效机制。 4.声誉市场与职业关注 市场交换的经济范式的一个隐含假设是,存在一个政府来定义产权,并执行合约。即使不存在第三方,声誉或品牌作为私人机制,同样可以向当事人提供履行合约的激励。职业关注所提供的隐性激励不仅适用于经理人,同时适用于董事。风险的规避与折旧成为市场约束激励的能力的限制。因此,对未来职业的关注可能既是有利的,同时,也可能是有害的,这要取决于企业与个人利益的协调程度。二、内部控制系统

服务贸易自由化机制外文文献翻译2014年译文4000字

文献出处:Barattieri A. The mechanism of service trade liberalization[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2014, 92(1): 1-13. (声明:本译文归百度文库所有,完整译文请到百度文库。) 原文 The mechanism of service trade liberalization Barattieri A Abstract In this paper, Service trade liberalization is the key areas of the United States to promote the TPP negotiations, the United States in the negotiations are pushing mechanism of a high standard of service trade liberalization. In this paper the progress of the TPP negotiations and services trade issues important position, on the basis of the acceptance, architecture design, focus on services, regulatory consistency four aspects in the TPP uncovers the "high standards" service trade liberalization mechanism establishment. American "high standards" service trade liberalization mechanism is tailored to the interests of the United States, actually services in the service of the United States. These mechanisms are through to strengthen and promote the TPP platform, forming reversed transmission to other countries. Key words: the TPP; The United States; Service trade liberalization; High standards; Mechanism design America is the first largest exporter global trade in services, and for many years, continues to service trade surplus. Competitive advantage based on service industry and service industry The importance of promoting American exports, jobs and economic growth, the United States in the multilateral, bilateral and regional multiple layers jointly promoting service trade liberalization. In the Uruguay round negotiations, the United States has overcome many obstacles, for the first time to include the Service Trade in multilateral negotiations, contributed to the general Agreement on Trade in services (the Genre - al Agreement on Trade and Service,

老龄化和退休养老金外文翻译文献

文献信息 文献标题:Active Ageing, Pensions and Retirement in the UK(英国的积极老龄化、养老金和退休) 文献作者:Liam Foster 文献出处:《Journal of Population Ageing》,2018,11(2):117-132 字数统计:英文3829单词,20396字符;中文6752汉字 外文文献 Active Ageing, Pensions and Retirement in the UK Abstract The ageing population has led to increasing concerns about pensions and their future sustainability. Much of the dominant policy discourse around ageing and pension provision over the last decade has focussed on postponing retirement and prolonging employment. These measures are central to productive notions of ‘active ageing’. Initially the paper briefly sets out the pension developments in the UK. Then it introduces active ageing and active ageing policy, exploring its implications for UK pension provision. It demonstrates that a more comprehensive active ageing framework, which incorporates a life-course perspective, has the potential to assist the UK to respond to the challenges of an ageing population. In doing so it needs to highlight older people as an economic and social resource, and reduce barriers to older people’s participation in society. Keywords: Active ageing, Extending working lives, UK, Longevity, Pensions Introduction The world’s population is ageing. The number of people aged 65 or older worldwide is projected to grow from 524 million in 2010 to nearly 1.5 billion in 2050 (World Health Organisation 2012). The age-based dependency ratio is also changing: in Europe there are four people of working age for every person over 65 and by 2060 there will be only two (European Commission 2010). In the UK it is estimated that the

市场营销_外文翻译_外文文献_英文文献_顾客满意策略与顾客满意

顾客满意策略与顾客满意营销 原文来源:《Marketing Customer Satisfaction 》自20世纪八十年代末以来, 顾客满意战略已日益成为各国企业占有更多的顾客份额, 获得竞争优势的整体经营手段。 一、顾客满意策略是现代企业获得顾客“货币选票”的法宝随着时代的变迁, 社会物质财富的极大充裕, 顾客中的主体———消费者的需求也先后跨越了物质缺乏的时代、追求数量的时代、追求品质的时代, 到了20世纪八十年代末进入了情感消费时代。在我国, 随着经济的高速发展,我们也已迅速跨越了物质缺乏时代、追求数量的时代乃至追求品质的时代, 到今天也逐步迈进情感消费时代。在情感消费时代, 各企业的同类产品早已达到同时、同质、同能、同价, 消费者追求的已不再是质量、功能和价格, 而是舒适、便利、安全、安心、速度、跃动、环保、清洁、愉快、有趣等,消费者日益关注的是产品能否为自己的生活带来活力、充实、舒适、美感和精神文化品位, 以及超越消费者期望值的售前、售中、售后服务和咨询。也就是说, 今天人们所追求的是具有“心的满足感和充实感”的商品, 是高附加值的商品和服务,追求价值观和意识多元化、个性化和无形的满足感的时代已经来临。 与消费者价值追求变化相适应的企业间的竞争, 也由产品竞争、价格竞争、技术竞争、广告竞争、品牌竞争发展到现今的形象竞争、信誉竞争、文化竞争和服务竞争, 即顾客满意竞争。这种竞争是企业在广角度、宽领域的时空范围内展开的高层次、体现综合实力的竞争。它包括组织创新力、技术创新力、管理创新力、产业预见力、产品研发力、员工向心力、服务顾客力、顾客亲和力、同行认同力、社会贡献力、公关传播沟通力、企业文化推动力、环境适应力等等。这些综合形象力和如何合成综合持久的竞争力, 这就是CSft略所要解决的问题。CS寸代,企业不再以“自己为中心”,而是以“顾客为中心”;“顾客为尊”、“顾客满意”不再是流于形式的口号, 而是以实实在在的行动为基础的企业经营的一门新哲学。企业不再以质量达标, 自己满意为经营理念, 而是以顾客满意, 赢得顾客高忠诚度为经营理念。企业经营策略的焦点不再以争取或保持市场占有率为主, 而是以争取顾客满意为经营理念。因此, 营销策略的重心不再放在竞争对手身上而是放在顾客身上, 放在顾客现实的、潜在的需求上。当企业提供的产品和服务达到了顾客事先的期望值, 顾客就基本满意;如果远远超越顾客的期望值, 且远远高于其他同行, 顾客才真正满意;如果企业能不断地或长久地令顾客满意, 顾客就会忠诚。忠诚的顾客不仅会经常性地重复购买, 还会购买企业其它相关的产品或服务;忠诚的顾客不仅会积极向别人推荐他所买的产品, 而且对企业竞争者的促销活动具有免疫能力一个不满意的顾客会将不满意告诉16-20个人, 而每一个被告知者会再传播给12-15个人。这样, 一个不满意者会影响到二、三百人。在互联网普及的今天, 其影响则更大。据美国汽车业的调查, 一个满意者会引发8笔潜在的生意, 其中至少有一笔会成交。而另一项调查表明, 企业每增加5%的忠诚顾客, 利润就会增长25%-95%。一个企业的80%的利润来自20%的忠诚顾客;而获取一个新顾客的成本是维持一个老顾客成本的6倍。所以,美国著名学者唐?佩 珀斯指出: 决定一个企业成功与否的关键不是市场份额, 而是在于顾客份额。 于是, 企业纷纷通过广泛细致的市场调研、与消费者直接接触、顾客信息反馈等方式来了解顾客在各方面的现实需求和潜在需求。依靠对企业满意忠诚的销售、服务人员, 定期、定量地对顾客满意度进行综合测定, 以便准确地把握企业经营中与“顾客满意” 目标的差距及其重点领域, 从而进一步改善企业的经营活动。依靠高亲和力的企业文化、高效率的人文管理和全员共同努力, 不断地向顾客提供高附加值的产品, 高水准的亲情般的服

会计内部控制中英文对照外文翻译文献

会计内部控制中英文对照外文翻译文献(文档含英文原文和中文翻译) 内部控制系统披露—一种可替代的管理机制 根据代理理论,各种治理机制减少了投资者和管理者之间的代理问题(Jensen and Meckling,1976; Gillan,2006)。传统上,治理机制已经被认定为内部或外部的。内部机制包括董事会及其作用、结构和组成(Fama,1980;Fama and Jensen,1983),管理股权(Jensen and Meckling,1976)和激励措施,起监督作用的大股东(Demsetz and Lehn,1985),内部控制系统(Bushman and Smith,2001),规章制度和章程条款(反收购措施)和使用的债务融资(杰森,1993)。外部控制是由公司控制权市场(Grossman and Hart,1980)、劳动力管理市场(Fama,1980)和产品市场(哈特,1983)施加的控制。 各种各样的金融丑闻,动摇了世界各地的投资者,公司治理最佳实践方式特别强调了内部控制系统在公司治理中起到的重要作用。内部控制有助于通过提供保证可靠性的财务报告,和临时议会对可能会损害公司经营目标的事项进行评估和风险管理来保护投

资者的利益。这些功能已被的广泛普及内部控制系统架构设计的广泛认可,并指出了内部控制是用以促进效率,减少资产损失风险,帮助保证财务报告的可靠性和对法律法规的遵从(COSO,1992)。 尽管有其相关性,但投资者不能直接观察,因此也无法得到内部控制系统设计和发挥功能的信息,因为它们都是组织内的内在机制、活动和过程(Deumes and Knechel,2008)。 由于投资者考虑到成本维持监控管理其声称的(Jensen and Meckling,1976),内部控制系统在管理激励信息沟通上的特性,以告知投资者内部控制系统的有效性,是当其他监控机制(该公司的股权结构和董事会)比较薄弱,从而为其提供便捷的监控(Leftwich et等, 1981)。存在的替代机制一直是人们在不同公司治理文献中争论的话题(Rediker and Seth, 1995;Fernandez and Arrondo,2005),基于威廉姆森(1983年)的替代假说认为,特定控制机制的边际作用取决于其在公司治理制度的相对重要性。 在本文中,我们认为披露内部控制系统的特点是在管理者选择的监控机制时存在一个可替代治理机制。Leftwich(1981)认为“管理者选择一个监控包,监测包的组成取决于各种监控机制的成本与效益”(P.59)。 特别是,我们重点关注内部控制系统和监控包的另外两个机制 (公司的所有权结构和董事会) 间的关系,根据有关文献(Jensen and Meckling,1976;Fernandez and Arrondo,2005;Gillan,2006)它们在管理行为监控方面发挥相关作用。我们假设认为,内部控制系统的特性取决于激励由企业的股权结构和董事会发挥监督作用。 因此,我们研究了三年间在四个不同的证券交易所上市(伦敦、巴黎、法兰克福和米兰)160家欧洲公司内部控制系统披露程度,通过利用这个国际范例,我们能够描绘出不同的体制环境的某些功能。 我们发现证据表明内部控制系统披露代替了监测方面所发挥的作用与所有制结构、制度所有权、在董事会上独立董事比例和会计审计委员会的专家成员的比率相关。 我们再加上通过内部会计控制的披露所发挥的管理作用,采用以往文献的完整披露架构,使我们能够详细地从内容和信息管理的程度上内制披露上进行交流。而公司治理的最佳做法要求披露内部控制系统的特性,他们没有提供管理应该披露和披露程度的指令。这样的管理缺乏指示使内部控制系统存在随意性。 本文提供了实证支持威廉姆森(1983年成立)在不同的治理机制下的替代假说,它有相应的政策含义。虽然大多数公司治理研究考虑一个互补的披露机制管理采用强化公

中英金融服务贸易国际竞争力比较研究【文献综述】

毕业论文文献综述 国际经济与贸易 中英金融服务贸易国际竞争力比较研究 金融服务贸易国际竞争力相关理论综述 服务贸易是以服务作为交易标的的一种贸易行为。《服务贸易总协定》(GATS)所界定的国际服务贸易是指以过境交付、境外消费、商业存在和自然人流动这四种形式进行的各国间的服务交易。该定义已成为有一定权威性和指导性的定义为各国接受。 根据《服务贸易总协定》中的服务部门清单,可以将服务贸易分为12类:商业性服务,销售服务,金融服务,娱乐服务,通讯服务,教育服务,卫生服务,运输服务,建筑服务,环境服务,旅游服务和其他服务。而对于金融服务贸易,国内外并没有确切的定义。本文将对金融服务贸易国外及国内有代表性的研究进行综述。 一、GATS与OECD对金融服务贸易的定义 根据GATS的定义,金融服务贸易是指由一成员国的金融服务提供者所提供的任何金融性质的服务。它包括两个部分:所有保险和保险相关的服务、银行和其他金融服务(保险除外),其中其他金融服务指证券和金融信息服务。 经济合作和发展组织(OECD)对金融服务贸易的定义为由金融机构提供服务的收入,或者接受付出的支持,包括得到的和付出的直接投资收益(未分配收益和利息);从其他金融投资得到的和付出的收益(得到的和付出的利息和红利);得到的、付出的手续费和佣金。 可见,经济合作和发展组织对金融服务贸易的界定强调了金融服务贸易交易的提供方,而忽略了金融服务贸易的消费方。金融服务贸易的发展主要是以此换取其他贸易领域的发展,而且金融服务贸易可以促进本国金融业与国际金融业的接轨,从而在国际竞争中促进本国金融业的发展。 二、国外对金融服务贸易相关研究 对于金融服务贸易研究,国外学者从不同角度出发,有不同的看法。 列为恩(1996)认为,各种金融服务可以实现五种基本功能:方便商品和劳务的交易;易于风险管理;加速资源流动;获取信息,评估企业和配置资本;提供公司法人治理。同时,更多的相关文献表示,金融中介可以降低由于信息不对称产生的管理成本(戴蒙德1984;威廉森1987)也可以对规模经济产生积极的效应。 莫施里安(Moshirian 1994)认为,金融服务贸易和制造业类似,一些基本要素赋予了

养老保险外文翻译文献

养老保险外文翻译文献 (文档含中英文对照即英文原文和中文翻译) 原文: Reintroducing Intergenerational Equilibrium: Key Concepts behind the New Polish Pension System Abstract Poland adopted a new pension system in 1999. This new pension system allows Poland to reduce pension expenditure (as a percent of GDP), instead of increasing it as is projected for the majority of other OECD countries. This paper presents the conceptual background of the new system design. The new system’s long-term bjective is to ensure intergenerational equilibrium irrespective of the demographic situation. This requires stabilisation of the share of GDP allocated to the entire retired

generation. Traditional pension systems aim, instead, at stabilisation of the share of GDP per retiree. The change in demographic structure observed over the past for a couple of decades and this historic attempt to stabilise the share of GDP per retiree led to severe fiscal problems and negative externalities for growth, as observed in numerous countries. Many countries have tried to reform their pension systems in different ways to try to resolve the issue of these ever-increasing costs. Although the Polish reform uses a number of techniques applied elsewhere, its design differs from the typical approaches –and the lessons and results are promising for all OECD countries. This paper presents the theoretical and practical application of this alternative approach and as such, the key features of the new Polish pension system design. Introduction Demographic transition together with myopic policies has caused severe problems in the area of pensions in many countries around the world. Elements of traditional pension systems’ design include a weak link of benefits to contributions and the lack of control over costs of the system. Inclusion of these elements in the pension system design led to the explosion of costs, caused negative externalities for growth and contributed to persistently high unemployment. As such, the quest for pension reform is now on the top of policy agendas around the world, and especially in Europe. However, very few countries have been able to introduce fundamental reforms in the area of pensions to this time. In this case, the definition of reform is crucial. For the purposes of this paper, “reform” means changing t he system in order to remove tructural inefficiencies – and not just playing at the margins with contribution rates a nd retirement ages to adjust the system’s parameters for short-term fiscal and political reasons.Traditional pension systems have proven to be inefficient in providing societies with social security. At

差异化营销策略外文文献翻译

文献出处: Dalman, M. Deniz, and Junhong Min. "Marketing Strategy for Unusual Brand Differentiation: Trivial Attribute Effect." International Journal of Marketing Studies 6.5 (2014): 63-72. 原文 Marketing Strategy for Unusual Brand Differentiation: Trivial Attribute Effect Dalman, M. Deniz & Junhong Min Abstract This research investigates that brand differentiation creating superior values can be achieved not only by adding meaningful attributes but also meaningless attributes, which is called "trivial attribute effect." Two studies provided empirical evidences as following; first, trivial attribute effect creates a strong brand differentiation even after subjects realize that trivial attribute has no value. Second, trivial attribute effect is more pronounced in hedonic service category compared to the utilitarian category. Last, the amount of willingness to pay is higher when trivial attribute is presented and evaluated in joint evaluation mode than separate evaluation mode. Finally, we conclude with discussion and provide suggestions for further research. Keywords: brand differentiation, evaluation mode, service industry, trivial attribute Introduction Problem Definition Perhaps the most important factor for new product success is to create the meaningful brand differentiation that provides customers with superior values beyond what the competitors can offer in the same industry (Porter, 1985). Not surprisingly, more than 50 percent of annual sales in consumer product industries including automobiles, biotechnology, computer software, and pharmaceuticals are attributed to such meaningful brand differentiation by including new or noble attributes (Schilling &Hill, 1998). However, the brand differentiation that increases consumer preference is not only by introducing meaningful attributes but also meaningless attributes. For

外文翻译--公司治理对资本结构和企业价值关系的影响

外文文献翻译译文 一、外文原文 原文: The influence of corporate governance on the relation between capital structure and value Capital structure: relation with corporate value and main research streams When looking at the most important theoretical contributions on the relation between capital structure and value, as illustrated in Figure 1, it becomes immediately evident that there is a substantial difference between the early theories and the more recent ones. Modigliani and Miller (1958), who had originally asserted that there was no relationship between capital structure and value ; in 1963, instead, reached the paradoxical and provocative conclusion that a maximum level of debt would mean a maximum level of firm value, due to the fact that interest is tax deductible . Many later contributions pointed out that this effect is compensated when considering personal taxes (Miller, 1977),an eventual lack of tax capacity, due to the presence of economic loss, the effect of other types of tax shields (De Angelo and Masulis, 1980), as well as the introduction of the costs(direct and indirect) of financial distress; all these situations end up creating a trade-off between debt costs and benefits. Point L? in Figure 1c indicates an optimal level of debt,beyond which any rise in leverage would cause an increase in the benefits of debt that would be less than proportional with respect to the costs of financial distress. Furthermore, this non monotonic relation would be modified even more when considering agency costs as well as the costs of financial distress . Finally, one last stream of research (Myers, 1984,Myers 1984) points out managerial preferences when choosing financing resources . In this case no optimal level of debt becomes ……objectively?? evident,but this is due to the various situations the manager had to deal with over time. The function of managerial

相关文档
最新文档