A Carbon Tax in China

A Carbon Tax in China
A Carbon Tax in China

August 2004

A Carbon Tax in China?

Richard N. Cooper

Introduction and Summary

Emissions of greenhouse gases (GHGs) are thought to be a serious threat to the well-being of mankind (and other species). The principal culprit is carbon dioxide (CO2), generated largely by the extensive use of fossil fuels (coal, oil, and natural gas, in that order). CO2 concentrations in the atmosphere have risen from 285 ppm at the beginning of the industrial revolution to around 370 ppm today, and are still rising. Methane and various industrial gases also contribute to climate change. The concern is that the average surface temperature of the earth will rise, by perhaps 2.5 degrees centigrade, during the 21st century, with a concomitant rise in sea levels by perhaps half a meter due to thermal expansion and glacial melting.

The Framework Convention on Climate Change (FCCC) of 1992 and its Kyoto Protocol of 1997 addressed these issues, in a limited way, by acknowledging the problem, committing all signatory countries to deal with it, and obliging the rich countries (including the former communist countries of central Europe, Russia, and Ukraine) to limit by 2008-2012 their emissions of six specified GHGs to a stipulated fraction of their emissions of 1990, all in agreed CO2 equivalents.

In 2004 the Kyoto Protocol hangs in suspension, awaiting ratification by Russia, which would be sufficient to bring it into force. Russia is equivocating. Even if Russia ratifies, the Kyoto Protocol will have a limited impact on GHG emissions, since the USA and Australia have withdrawn their support, and the Kyoto Protocol in any case does not and cannot easily be extended to cover developing countries, including such important emitters as China, India, and others whose fossil fuel consumption is growing rapidly.

While forecasts of long-term energy use have been notoriously off the mark (see Abt (2002), Smil(2003)), the subject at hand is inherently quantitative and future-oriented, so a quantitative baseline is necessary to frame serious discussion. The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change has put

forward six different main scenarios to specify "business as usual" trajectories of GHG emissions over the course of the next century (IPCC, 2001). The Energy I nformation Administration of the US Department of Energy and the OECD-based International Energy Agency, among others, do 25-year forecasts of energy use, by region and by major fuel.

The IEA's World Energy Outlook 2004 will not be available until early 2005, so this paper will rely heavily on the International Energy Outlook 2004 published in April 2004 by the US Department of Energy (EIA, 2004). It shows world emissions of CO2 (on which this paper will focus, largely ignoring other GHGS, which however account for about 30 percent of greenhouse warming potential since 1800) rising from 23.5 million metric tons (mmt) in 2000 (up from 21.6 mmt in 1990, the base year of the Kyoto Protocol) to 37.1 mmt in 2025, an increase of 1.9 percent a year on the basis of an assumed annual average growth in gross world product (GWP) of 3.0 percent. China's CO2 emissions are assumed to grow by 3.3 percent a year, the highest rate in the world among large countries or regions, with Brazil and India not far behind. China's share of world CO2 emissions increases from 12 percent in 2000 to 18 percent in 2025, rapidly approaching the US share of 22 percent (underlying data from EIA 2004, Table A9).1 In view of these trends, the problem of GHG emissions cannot be seriously addressed without engaging China, Brazil, India, and other rapidly growing countries.

Worldwide agreement on national GHG emission targets that have enough bite to limit growth in atmospheric CO2 concentrations is likely to prove impossible, at least for several decades. It is hard to imagine an effective formula for national targets that will be acceptable both to rich countries such as the USA and to poor countries with aspirations for rapid growth, such as China and India (Cooper, 2001). The targets of the Kyoto Protocol are based on a base year, 1990, an approach that is unappealing to countries that desire and expect to grow rapidly.

Another approach is needed if human sources of climate change are to be addressed seriously.

A leading alternative approach is to focus on concrete national commitments to action rather than emission targets. One such action, favored by many economists to deal with negative externalities from

human activity, is to tax the offending activity, here atmospheric emissions o f CO2 -- and eventually other significant GHGs. The central idea is to levy a tax on CO2 emissions from major sources, and in particular on the burning of coal, oil, and natural gas and the making of cement, unless the CO2 released from such processes is prevented from entering the atmosphere through sequestration. The eventual rate of tax should be calibrated to the desired reduction in CO2 emissions. This paper will address the imposition of such a tax in China, already second largest CO2 emitter after the USA, with the most expected rapid growth in emissions, and by far the world's largest producer and user of coal.

China has not evinced major concern about the possibility of global climate change, although it officially accepts that it is a potential problem, and it is a signatory of the FCCC and the Kyoto Protocol.2 It has many higher priorities, among which are to maintain rapid economic growth (the official aspiration is to quadruple its GDP between 2000 and 2020, implying average annual growth of 7.2 percent); to provide employment for large numbers of people leaving agriculture (which still accounts for about sixty percent of the labor force) and those released from over-manned state-owned enterprises (SOEs), to assure political stability; and, under the environmental heading, to reduce floods and water and air pollution, while preserving energy security.

The attraction of a CO2 tax to China would not, therefore, rest mainly on its contribution to avoiding climate change, but rather its contribution to reducing air pollution, which derives heavily from use of coal and, increasingly, from automotive emissions in the larger cities; and, above all, as a source of revenue, which is badly needed by the central government. China is unlikely to impose a stiff CO2 tax alone, because of concerns about loss of international competitiveness in energy-intensive industries such as steel-making. But such effect could be neutralized if the tax were imposed as part of a broad international agreement to introduce such taxes, as proposed by Cooper (1998), to limit GHG emissions.

This paper will discuss the current state of China's energy sector and its outlook for the next few decades; the impact of a CO2 tax on the volume and composition of China's energy use; the revenue

implications of such a tax; and the possible impact of a carbon tax on the growth and structure of China's economy.

China's Energy Consumption and Outlook

Table 1 provides basic information on China's primary energy consumption in 1990 and 2000, and the reference case projection of China's energy use to 2025 by the US Department of Energy.3 It can be seen there that China is heavily dependent (nearly two-thirds in 2000) on coal, the most carbon-intensive fossil fuel, mainly for electricity generation but also for industrial and household use. Oil accounts for just over one quarter of primary energy use. Over the next 25 years the relative importance of coal is expected to decline, while that of oil rises (as more Chinese acquire automobiles, and truck traffic increases). But because of rapid growth, the use of coal is nonetheless expected to double by 2025, from an already large base. China is taking significant steps to increase the use of natural gas in households, industry, and for the generation of electricity, and to increase nuclear power, both of which are expected to grow rapidly, but by 2025 they together still account for only seven percent of China's primary energy consumption.

It is noteworthy that the EIA assumes that China over this period grows at "only" 6.1 percent a year, over a percentage point less than China's 7.2 percent growth aspiration, and that energy growth is not much more than half this expected growth in GDP, implying considerable improvements in efficiency in the use of energy as well as changes in the structure of the Chinese economy toward less energy-intensive activities. Despite lower growth, improvements in efficiency, and the relative decline of coal, China's CO2 emissions are expected to grow by 3.3 percent a year, the most rapid in the world.

The demand for electricity grows with increases in income, for it is relatively clean and convenient at the point of use. In 1997 China had 263 GW in installed electricity generating capacity, two-thirds coal-fired (74 percent of actual electricity generation), 23 percent hydro-electric, with the remaining ten percent relying on oil, nuclear, gas, and renewables, in that order (IEA, 2000, p.204).

The International Energy Agency expected China to add 500 GW of capacity by 2020, raising capacity by nearly a factor of three over existing capacity, two-thirds of which would be coal-fired, despite out-sized increases in gas-fired, nuclear, and hydro-power. This compares with a total of new generating capacity in the USA (Europe) of only 396 GW (477 GW, mostly gas) over the same period.4 China faces a basic dilemma in framing its future energy policy. It has abundant coal resources, but has so far had difficulty finding abundant oil or gas. Coal accounts for much of the air pollution -- 85 percent of sulfur dioxide (of which only 30 percent comes from power plants), for instance, and much particulate matter. In addition, the mines are mainly located considerable distance from the main sources of demand for energy, requiring extensive transportation. Switching to oil or gas, however, would also involve extensive investments in infrastructure, and will prospectively increase China's dependence on the rest of the world for primary energy, something that makes Chinese leaders uncomfortable. Their attempts to resolve this dilemma leads them to place heavy emphasis on hydro- and nuclear-power; to explore intensively for oil and gas (but not to the point of inviting foreign equity participation in Chinese production); and to diversify their sources of imports, notably by considering (expensive) oil- and gas-pipelines from Kazakhstan and from Siberia, in order to reduce inevitable growing dependence on sea-borne oil (and, in the future, gas) from the Persian Gulf.

China has extensive hydro-electric potential, 290 GW estimated to be economically exploitable, of which only 60 GW was developed in 1997. The controversial Three Gorges Dam will bring on an additional 18 GW by 2009. IEA assumes the total will rise to 171 GW by 2020 (IEA, 2000, p.205).

China's first nuclear power plant came on line in 1991 and by 2000 China had 2.1 GW of capacity. Official plans call optimistically for 40 GW by 2020 (CDF 2003, p.71), but IEA assumes because of cost, long lead times, and other difficulties that China will reach only 20 GW. (The capital costs of nuclear plants are about three times higher per kW than for new coal-fired plants in China.) China has discovered the many attractions of gas-fired power plants, in cost, scale, and low pollution. China's problem is insufficient economical gas. It has approved two LNG terminals, both on

the south coast, and has several more under consideration; it has contracted for Australian gas. Power plants will however have to compete with high priority residential and industrial uses of gas. The IEA nonetheless projects a 20-fold increase in gas-fired power plants between 1997 and 2020, from a low base (IEA, p.205).

The structure of the Chinese energy market is highly fragmented. While national policy is set in Beijing, actions by each province and municipality reflect local interests. End-use of energy, as in many countries particularly gas and electricity, is subject to local price control. This is partly to prevent exploitation of local monopoly in delivery, but also represents a residual of habits created during central planning days in the energy sector, which is seen as critical to many industrial activities. There are no national or even extensive regional electricity grids in China, so most power plants distribute only within the vicinity of the plants (over 95 percent of China's population has access to electricity). Long-distance gas pipelines are few, although construction is proceeding on the West-East pipeline to bring gas from the Tarim Basin in Xinjiang province to Shanghai and other eastern destinations. Thousands of small coal mines also serve mainly local needs, although vast amounts of coal are also shipped east and south by rail and coastal barge.

Furthermore, with few exceptions, energy is provided by SOEs, many now owned by provinces or municipalities. Oil production and distribution has been concentrated in three large national SOEs, mostly non-competing. Electricity production is typically provided by provincial or municipal enterprises. China is having difficulty placing SOEs under tight budget constraints; they have historically had ready access to bank credit, and while banks (all themselves SOEs) are under instruction to make loans only on a commercial basis, local politics continues to play an important role in credit allocation, especially (I suspect) to energy firms.

China is notably inefficient in its use of energy. Table 2 provides one indicator, the ratio of GDP per unit of primary energy consumed. It can be seen there that on this measure (which incorporates differences in economic structure as well as energy efficiency per se) China in 2000 produced less than

one-third in final output per unit of energy than did the United States, and only 15 percent of Japan (the most energy-efficient among the rich countries). China's energy efficiency is expected to improve over the projection period to 2025, at 2.4 percent a year, compared with 1.5 percent for the United States, but even then will remain under 40 percent of US efficiency (and under one quarter of Japan's).

According to the IEA, China's coal-fired generating plants operated at only 28 percent efficiency, 26 percent below the 38 percent average of the OECD countries in the late 1990s (IEA, p.204), despite more extensive pollution controls on the OECD plants. Generating plants in China were much smaller, coal consistency was uneven, and plants were down more often. New plants in China are typically much larger than average, over 300MW, but remain well behind world best-practice.

China's authorities are well aware of their energy needs, problems, and constraints. They acknowledge that energy should not simply serve the requirements of growth, but should also take into account cost, environmental factors, and security. They also acknowledge the need to separate more sharply policy formulation from regulation and supervision (at all levels of government), and the need to move to price-incentives based competitive markets subject to regulation to protect consumers from natural monopolies, particularly in final distribution, and taking into account environmental externalities (see statements by Qingtai Chen and Jiange Li of the Development Research Center at the China Development Forum on China's Energy Strategy and Reform, Beijing, November 2003). As is often the case in China, the difficult task is in translating coherent principles into actual practice.

One part of China's strategy seems to be to back out coal as rapidly as investment in gas, nuclear, and hydro permit, and to charge consumers of electricity what is necessary to finance the required investment.

A Carbon Tax

The basic proposal is for China to impose a tax on burning fossil fuels in proportion to CO2 emission, i.e. in proportion to the carbon content of the fuels. One would also want to include making

cement, which in addition to the energy consumed emits CO2 from the breakdown of carbonates, and in 2000 accounted for emissions of over six percent those arising from the energy sector (Johnson, 2003,p.6). The tax would be heaviest on coal, which is about 75 percent carbon by weight, lighter on oil. The tax would also be levied on natural gas, which is about 75 percent carbon by weight, but much lower than coal in terms of useful energy produced. The tax would thus discourage the use of all fossil fuels, relative to alternatives, with coal being discouraged the most, gas, which emits about half as much CO2 as efficient coal per unit of power, the least.5

Administratively, the tax would be m ost easily levied at the key bottlenecks in the fossil energy system: trunk pipelines for gas, refineries for oil, railroad heads for coal. China has thousands of small coal mines producing mainly for local consumption, and these would be difficult to reach except by local authorities. China supposedly closed down over 30,000 such mines in the late 1990s, as being unsafe, polluting, and inefficient. During the fuel crisis of 2003 many were re-opened, some with approved work-safety improvements, others illegally. Presumably many of these mines will be closed again as the rationalization and efficiency of China's energy system improves.

The idea of imposing a carbon tax is in complete harmony with China's official energy strategy, adopted in 2002, which i n the words of one senior Chinese official (Wu Yin, Deputy Director-General of the Energy Department of the National Development and Reform Commission, 4/23/04) "will constantly improve the macro control and power market regulatory system, deepen the power system reform, and try hard to build up an incentive mechanism for resource conservation, efficiency improvement, environmental protection, and development promotion." (Italics added) Creating appropriate incentive systems for efficiency and environmental protection are constantly mentioned by Chinese officials, as is the need to get the price of coal up to reflect its full social costs, including environmental costs (e.g. CDF 2003, p.93). A tax on an environmentally damaging emissions fits perfectly with this objective.

Several important questions arise with respect to a carbon emissions tax:

1) At what level should the tax be set?

2) How much will introduction of a tax influence behavior of households and firms?

3) What will be the impact on government revenue, and how will it be used?

4) What will be the macroeconomic impact of such a tax?

5) What will be the impact of the tax on long-run growth of the economy?

Each of these questions will be addressed in turn.

The tax rate should be set high enough to reduce CO2 emissions significantly. But by how much? We do not know the answer to that question, because much controversy surrounds the extent of likely global warming under business as usual; the damages that such warming would actually cause, after human adaptation to climate change; and the costs of such adaptation. Various attempts have been made at a cost-benefit analysis (see Nordhaus-Boyer 2000, IPCC Working Group III, 1996). There is no general consensus on what needs to be done, and how rapidly; indeed there is wide discrepancy among respectable analysts. Thus the process will inevitably involve trial and error, both with respect to the objective of reducing emissions and the impact of any given tax on such reductions. For purposes of analysis, this paper will be calibrated on $23 per ton of carbon emitted (= $6.20 per ton of carbon dioxide, 27 percent carbon by weight -- unhappily both measures are used in the literature, carbon by the IPCC, CO2 by the Kyoto Protocol).

Impact on emissions

Will a rise in the price of fossil fuels brought on by the tax lead to a reduction in carbon emissions by firms and households? It has already been noted that at present China's energy system is highly fragmented and often subject to price control. Furthermore, electricity costs are "rolled in" to a final charge to the ultimate consumer, regardless of the source of the electricity. Price signals do not drive either consumer behavior or investment. For purposes of this paper, however, we assume that the Chinese authorities succeed during the next decade in their stated objective of creating a competitive

energy market, albeit one that is regulated to prevent exploitation of natural monopoly; that a national or at least large scale electricity grid will be created; that the prices charged will cover costs; and that the costs will include consideration of environmental damage arising from the energy system, including (but not limited to) CO2 emissions. Under these circumstances, imposition of a carbon tax will raise the prices of fossil fuels and electricity generated with fossil fuels, and both intermediate and final energy users will thus experience price incentives to reduce their consumption of carbon-emitting fuels.

International experience suggests that higher prices can in the long run have a substantial impact on consumption of energy. While demand may be highly inelastic in the short run, over a period of time people adjust their behavior to higher prices. Following the large world oil price increases of 1974 and 1979-80, for instance, demand for oil dropped steadily in the United States, Japan, and Europe. High prices for gasoline lead people to buy smaller, more fuel-efficient automobiles than they otherwise would do. Household appliances have become much more efficient than they once were, as have jet engines and a host of other energy using equipment. Buildings are now constructed with energy consumption in mind, to a much greater extent than was true before the 1970s. And so on.

Limited experience in China with pollution taxes or fines re-enforce the observation that users respond to financial penalties by reducing the offending activity. Wang and Wheeler (1999) have shown that effluent charges and fines, levied locally within the framework of a national policy, have significantly reduced air and water pollution in China during since 1987. China is also experimenting with SO2 emission charges, to cut down on acid rain and air pollution.

The channels by which a carbon tax might reduce carbon emissions are several:

First, households can be expected to reduce their spending on energy directly, and on energy-intensive products, both of which will become more expensive after imposition of the tax. Thus less electricity (than otherwise) will be consumed, less coal or gas for heating, less gasoline. More insulation will be installed. Consumers will pay more attention to the life-time costs of appliances, automobiles, apartments and other long-term purchases as they become conscious of the higher energy costs, and

shift their purchases to products with lower energy usage.

Second, firms, sensitive to this shift, will concentrate more on products that are energy efficient. More importantly, they will cut back on their own use of energy in production by looking for ways to improve energy efficiency -- a process that was observed extensively in the United States following the four-fold increase in oil prices in the mid-1970s. Developers will use more energy-efficient building materials, will install more insulation, and will orient their developments to minimize the impact on dwellers of cold winter winds and maximize the impact of winter solar heating in northern latitudes, while maximizing the use of breezes and minimizing solar heating in southern latitudes (for examples of the possibilities, see Glicksman, 2003). Industrial boilers in China are notoriously inefficient; higher energy prices may drive some firms out of business, but most will adapt by improving their efficiency. As noted above, power generation in China, heavily dependent on coal, does not get maximum advantage of the latent heat in coal; big gains in efficiency are possible, although in some cases only by substituting large, modern generating plants for older, small ones -- something that will become possible with the development of extensive grids, a Chinese objective.

Finally, low carbon-emitting fuels may be substituted for high-emitting fuels in energy-using processes, e.g. nuclear, hydro, wind, or gas for oil and coal in electricity generation. In China this will probably be the least important of the three channels, at least during the next two decades, for two reasons. First, coal is far the cheapest way to produce electricity in China, given the availability of coal relative to oil and gas (both of which have strongly competing demands), and will remain so unless carbon taxes are very high.6

Second, China plans to build nuclear, hydro, and some gas plants as rapidly as possible in any case, and it is unlikely in the near future that relatively more expensive coal can accelerate those plans. China has ample wind resources, especially in Inner Mongolia, and plans are in the works for developing them; but their quantitative contribution is likely to remain small for the next two decades.7 One informed but still rough estimate of the impact on CO2 emissions in China can be

constructed from a study by the US Council of Economic Advisers of the costs to the United States of implementing the Kyoto Protocol under different assumptions about the possibility of trading permits (CEA, 1998). If the United States were to implement its Kyoto target alone, CEA estimated, the cost would be about $200 per ton of carbon. With trading among all the Annex B countries, the trading price (= marginal cost of avoiding another ton of carbon emissions) would drop to $56, largely because both Russia and Ukraine were given targets that turned out to be generous relative to their circumstances, so were expected to have many used emission rights to sell to others. If somehow China and India could be included within the trading regime (not envisioned in the Kyoto Protocol), the trading price of implementing the Kyoto targets would drop further to $23 a ton, reflecting the great possibilities in those two countries for improving energy efficiency. If we assume that the IEA's World Energy Outlook 2000 reflected a plausible trajectory for Annex B countries to 2010, the mid-point of the target period, then to meet their Kyoto targets Annex B countries would have to cut their CO2 emissions by 11.4 percent from the 2010 projection (which we now believe was too high for Europe, too low for the USA), or by 1526 million metric tons (calculated from IEA 2000, Table 10.1), and that China accounted for half of this if allowed access to the Annex B trading market, China would have achieved a 19 percent reduction from its 2010 carbon emissions as estimated by the EIA in 2004. Thus on the basis of this estimate a tax of roughly 100 percent on coal (assuming a coal price of $32 a ton with 75 percent carbon content), and correspondingly less on oil and gas per available btu (oil emits about three-quarters, and gas half that of an efficient coal power plant per unit of electricity), would lead to roughly a 20 percent reduction in China's carbon emissions.

Johnson (2003, p.7) reckons that by 2020 GHGs from China's energy sector could be reduced by 16 percent through greater efficiency, and an additional 12 percent through development of alternative energies, but he does not indicate the actions that would be required to achieve these results.

Ho and Jorgenson (2004) examine the impact of fuel taxes in China for the purpose of reducing

health-damaging pollution. Their analysis is applicable to CO2 emissions. They produce a multi-sectoral model of the Chinese economy, with exogenous technical change and savings rates, calibrated to Chinese data for 1997. They then notionally impose fuel taxes in relationship to the damage to health from pollutants caused by use of coal, oil, and gas, gas being negligible and oil being about 45 percent of coal, per ton (H&J, Table 7.9, implying about 22 percent of coal per useful btu). A 35 percent tax on coal (1.2 percent on oil) would reduce coal production by 30 percent after 20 years, compared with

a baseline (no tax) projection; carbon dioxide emissions would be reduced by 19 percent (H&J, Table

8.6, and communication from author). (The impact of a fuel tax is non-linear, in that a 23 percent tax would reduce coal production by 22 percent.)

Revenues

The impact of a carbon tax on tax revenues obviously depend on the tax rate, the enforcement of collection, and the behavioral responses discussed in the preceding paragraphs. There is of course a trade-off between revenue collection and social success of the tax in reducing emissions: the more successful the tax is in reducing carbon emissions, the less revenue will be raised. Thus a carbon tax does not necessarily represent a permanent source of revenue; eventually carbon emissions from the energy system may be greatly reduced. However, such a tax is likely to raise revenues for many, many years, measured in decades. This aspect will appeal to ministers of finance.

We can use the calculation above, combined with EIA projections for 2010, to calculate the revenue available in that year if such a tax had been put in place in, say, 2000, to provide time for the many adjustments discussed in the preceding section to take place. If at $23 a ton China would have reduced its carbon emissions by 19 percent from a projected level of 4063 mmt CO2, China's emissions after imposition of the tax would be 2537 mmt. As noted above, the implied tax per ton of CO2 is $6.20. Thus the revenue collected in 2010 would be $15.7 billion. EIA (2004) projects China's GDP in 2010 to be $2228 billion in dollars of 1997, or $3272 billion in 2010 dollars if the

Chinese deflator, measured in dollars, rises by three percent a year. Thus carbon tax revenues on this calculation would be 0.5 percent of GDP, or about 2.5 percent of government revenues if the latter are 20 percent of GDP.

Demands for government expenditures are heavy in China, as is rivalry between municipalities, provinces, and the central government for new revenues. In 1998 the central government had available for central government use only 5.9 percent of GDP [WDR 2000/2001], extraordinarily low. Yet it has responsibility for national projects such as the long-distance highway system and the long-distance pipelines, re-capitalizing the banking system, developing the western part of the country (requiring large infrastructure expenditures), modernizing the military forces, and probably, in the final analysis, nationalizing parts of the social security and pension system. If the carbon tax were a central government tax (as it should be), it would augment significantly available central government revenues.

Macroeconomic Impact

Significant new taxes can have macroeconomic effects. However, in this case the macroeconomic effects would be negligible, for two reasons.

First, the tax could be introduced gradually. CO2 emissions and climate change is a long-term problem, not an urgent one. It is important to address it soon, but it is not necessary to create great short-run economic damage in doing so. Since many of the behavioral changes such a tax might bring about can take place only over a period of time, often involving different forms of investment (e.g. in energy efficient housing), what is important is to put economic agents on notice that the tax is coming, and perhaps drive the point home by introducing the tax, but at a rate lower than the target rate. The tax rate can then be raised every year to two until it reaches the target rate.

Second, of course, the revenues will not be withdrawn from the income stream. They will somehow be dispersed. They could be dispersed either as reductions in other taxes, a point taken up below, or more likely in the case of China would be used to cover central government expenditures,

also to be discussed further below. As the taxes will be introduced gradually, the use of the revenues can also be planned ahead, so no macroeconomic shock need occur. Fuel taxes will of course reduce temporarily the real income of households, hence their c onsumption of goods and services. But the impact on aggregate demand can be neutralized by slow phase-in combined with parallel increases in government expenditures.

Impact on Growth

Some will be concerned that raising prices on energy will discourage economic growth, since energy is a critical input to all modern economies. The impact of a carbon tax on long-term growth is likely to be negligible, at least with the right complementary policies. The issue can be discussed under four headings; energy as a direct input to production; use of the carbon tax revenue; impact on the cost of capital and hence potentially on the rate of investment; and impact on international competitiveness and hence potentially on export growth.

Energy is a key input to most aspects of modern economies, including agriculture. Surely raising the price of energy will discourage production? Recall, however, that in China for a variety of reasons energy is used very inefficiently, relative to actual practice in other countries. Thus the possibility often exists to produce the same output with a lower input of energy. Sometimes this change simply requires an adequate incentive (i.e. higher energy price); sometimes it requires the incentive plus new knowledge about better practice; sometimes it requires an incentive plus new investment in more energy-efficient structures or equipment. And of course investment requires funding. On the other hand, many energy-saving investments would yield handsome rates of return, particularly i f energy prices were higher. So investment may be diverted from other destinations to energy saving, and on that account could lower growth. On the other hand, China must make huge investments in power generation -- $67 billion a year 2001-2030 on one estimate (IEA 2003, p.353), over two percent of GDP -- to support its growth aspirations, and to the extent energy efficiency can be improved further, such investment could be

reduced. The energy sector itself need not grow so rapidly, thus releasing both capital and labor to be used elsewhere in the economy, thus contributing to growth.

As noted above, the carbon tax will raise revenues. How those revenues are used can influence the rate of growth. If they are used to reduce growth-inhibiting taxes on capital, as Jorgenson suggests, the net impact might even be to accelerate growth. If, as is more likely, they are used to finance expenditures, the impact on growth will depend on the magnitude and growth-efficiency of the expenditures. Expenditures on transport infrastructure will presumably contribute to growth, as would expenditures on under-funded agricultural research and dissemination, or on education. Modernizing the PLA, in contrast, would not contribute much to growth. Thus the Chinese government would have substantial discretion over how much the carbon tax could be directed toward enhancement of growth.

A third channel of influence on growth would be through the cost of capital goods, hence the real investment that could be undertaken for any given nominal level of investment spending. Raising the cost of capital goods, other things being equal, will reduce growth. Raising the price of energy would increase the cost of those capital goods that are high in direct energy content, such as construction steel and cement. The impact on capital goods prices would of course be mitigated to the extent, per the first point above, that as a result of the tax producers increased significantly the efficiency with which they used energy. It is even conceivable that capital goods prices fell, as efficiency improvements outweighed increased energy prices. Furthermore, in a sufficiently long run technical change can be expected to reduce prices again. There has been no secular decline in the real return to capital in rich countries, those on the technological frontier, as capital-saving technical change has compensated on average for the declining returns that might be expected to flow from the tremendous accumulation of capital that has occurred during the past half century.

Finally, higher energy prices, other things being equal, will increase the relative price of energy-intensive products, hence reduce competitiveness of such products on world markets. A serious loss of competitiveness could, through a variety of channels, reduce economic growth.

Here the international environment in which China imposes a carbon tax comes into play. Climate change is a global issue. While the impact may be uneven (and at this stage highly uncertain) across regions of the world, the concern is a global one. It is difficult to imagine China acting alone to limit GHG emissions. On at least one calculation, China may not expect much net damage from at least modest climate change, indeed might even be a small net beneficiary (Nordhaus and Boyer, 2000, p.160).

Thus, China is likely to introduce a carbon tax (as opposed to other pollution taxes) only in the context of an international agreement of some type that calls on all China's competitors to introduce similar taxes or comparable restrictions on carbon emissions that will have the effect, like a carbon tax, of raising the relative price of fossil fuels, especially coal, and indirectly of all energy-intensive products. In such a setting, concerns about international competitiveness arising from the carbon tax should be minimal.

Endnotes

1. The EIA also produces high and low trajectories for world energy use, and emissions, in addition to its reference case. On the high variant, China's primary energy consumption increases by 4.2 percent a year 2001-2025, on the low variant, by

2.7 percent. China's share of world energy consumption rises from 14.0 percent on the low variant to 14.9 percent on the high variant.

2. Some Chinese are concerned with climate change, however, and the official Energy Research Institute has a Center for Energy, Environment, and Climate Change Research which seeks ways to reduce GHG emissions without compromising China's development objectives. See CDF 2003, pp.116-125.

3. Normal units of measurement have been converted into quadrillion British thermal units (quads) at the following rates:

petroleum: 1 million barrels a day = 2.03 quads per year

coal: 1 million short tons = 0.0184 quads

gas: 1 trillion cubic feet = 1.034 quads

nuclear power: 1 billion kwh = 0.0105 quads

4. China is expected to invest over 2001-2030 a total of $795 billion in new power generation, compared with $654 billion in the USA and Canada, $525 billion in the European Union, and $274 billion in Japan. IEA, 2003, p.353

5. For electricity generation conventional coal fired produces 962 metric tons of CO2 emissions per GWh, fluidized bed production produces 961 tons, integrated gasification combined cycle produces 748, oil-fired produces 726 tons, and gas-fired produces 484 tons. From Owen 2003, drawing on IEA 1989.

6. China's average incremental busbar costs per kwh are as follows: $.038 for pulverized coal, .045 for natural gas combined cycle, .048 for clean coal, .053 for nuclear, .068 for hydro, all assuming that coal costs $32 a ton and gas costs $4 per GJ. Allowance is made for capital costs: $700 per kwh for coal, $550 for gas, $1800 for nuclear, $1500 for hydro. (Logan 2004)

7. CDF 2003, p. 81, reports that 3-5 GW of wind capacity might be installed by 2010, and 10-30 GW by 2020, up from .46 GW in 2002.

Table 1

China’s Primary Energy Consumption

(quadrillion Btu)

1990 2000 2010 2020 2025

2001-25 Growth (%)

Total 27.0 37.0 54.6 77.7 91.0 3.5 Coal 20.7 23.6 32.0 43.6 50.7 2.9 Oil 4.7 9.7 15.4 22.3 26.0 4.0 Nat. Gas 0.5 1.0 2.0 3.7 5.2 6.9 Nuclear 0 0.2 0.7 1.5 1.6 9.7 Hydro 1.3 2.3 4.2 5.9 6.8 3.8 Source: calculated from EIA (2004), Appendix A

Table 2

Energy Intensity ($ 1997 trillion per quad)

1990 2000 2010 2020 2025 Change per

year 2000-2025

China 15.9 30.3 40.8 49.9 54.7 2.4 USA 80.8 94.4 111.2 129.0 138.3 1.5 Japan 212.7 201.6 212.8 238.0 249.5 0.9 Source: calculated from EIA (2004), Tables A1, A3

References

Abt, Clark, 2002, "The Future of Energy from the Perspective of Social Science," in Richard N. Cooper and Richard Layard, eds.,

What the Future Holds, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

China Development Forum, 2003, China's National Energy Strategy and Reform: Background Papers, Beijing: Development Research Center of the State Council, November 2003.

Cooper, Richard N., 1998, "Toward a Real Global Warming Treaty," Foreign Affairs, 77(March/April), 66-79.

Cooper, Richard N., 2000, "Internatonal Approaches to Global Climate Change," World Bank Research Observer, 15 (August), 145-72.

Cooper, Richard N., 2001, "The Kyoto Protocol: A Flawed Concept," Environmental Law Review, 31 (December), 11484-92.

Council of Economic Advisers, 1998, "The Kyoto Protocol and the President's Policies to Address Climate Change."

Garbaccio, Richard F., Mun S. Ho, and Dale W. Jorgenson, 1999, "Controlling Carbon Emissions in China," Environment and Development 2, part 4 (October), 493-518; reprinted in Dale W. Jorgenson, Economic Growth in an Information Age, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2002.

Glicksman, Leon R., 2003, "Energy Conservation in Chinese Residential Buildings: Progress and Opportunities in Design and Policy," presented at China Development Forum 2003: Energy Strategy and Reform, Beijing, November 16-17, 2003.

Ho, Mun S., and Dale W. Jorgenson, 2004, "Policies to Control Air Pollution Damages," Harvard University Center for the Environment, Proceedings of the Fourth US-China Workshop on Reconciling Economy, Energy, and Environment, Beijing, September 2002, mss.

Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, 1996, Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change, Cambridge University Press.

International Energy Agency, 2000, World Energy Outlook 2000, Paris: OECD.

人教版六年级上册、下册英语短语及词组总汇汇编

六年级上册短语 1、come to 来到… 2、make noise 制造噪音 3、be doing 正在进行时 4、 a list of 一览表,清单 5、hand in 上交 6、on time 准时,按时 7、ask questions 问问题 8、be quiet 安静 9、tell sb to do sth 告诉某人做某事 10、at home 在家 11、make a mess 乱扔乱放东西 12、help to do sth 帮助做某事 13、watch TV 看电视 14、go to bed 上床睡觉 15、keep…clean 保持…清洁 16、go home 回家 17、too late 太晚 18、wait for 等候… 19、keep off 不接近 20、take good care of 照顾好… 21、in front of 在…前面 22、hold up 举起 23、tell sb about sth告诉某人做某事 24、go to school 去上学 25、from…to 从…到 26、get home 回到家 27、in the morning 在上午,在早晨 28、in the evening 在晚上 29、have breakfast 吃早饭 30、have lunch 吃午饭 31、have dinner 吃晚饭 32、get up 起床 33、have classes 上课 34、be glad to do…很高兴做 35、be kind to 对…好 36、take a walk 散步37、play with 和…一起玩 38、go out 出去,外出 39、go shopping 去购物 40、stay up late 熬夜 41、want to do 想要做… 42、talk with 和…交谈 43、quick lunch 快餐 44、go on 继续,进行 45、learn from 向…学习 46、have meals 吃饭 47、be going to do 将要做… 48、be interested in 对…感兴趣 49、collect stamps集邮 50、collect candy paper 收集糖纸 51、collect picture cards 收集图画卡 片 52、play table tennis 打乒乓球 53、on the farm 在农场 54、be good at 擅长于… 55、grow vegetables 种植蔬菜 56、make tools 制作工具 57、plant flowers 种花 58、raise animals 喂养动物 59、cut out 剪下 60、talk about 谈论… 61、want to do 想要做… 62、I would like = I’d like 63、pick up 接人;拾起 64、light the candles 点燃蜡烛 65、make a wish 许愿 66、cut the cake 切蛋糕 67、have a good time 玩得愉快/开心 68、 a cup of tea 一杯茶 69、 a glass of juice 一杯果汁 70、 a piece of cake 一块蛋糕 71、blow out 吹灭 72、go camping 去野营/夏令营 73、go back to 回到 74、think of 考虑;关心;想起 75、lots of 许多 76、come out 出来(在课文中译为苏醒) 77、farm the land 耕地 78、go camping 野营 79、look at the flowers 看花 80、fly kites 放风筝 81、enjoy oneself 过得愉快 82、plant rice 种水稻 83、play on the beach 在沙滩上玩 84、look for shells 寻找贝壳 85、make a sandcastle 垒沙堡 86、pick apples 摘苹果 87、cut rice 割稻子 88、feed the animals 喂动物 89、play with snow 玩雪 90、sweep the snow 扫雪 91、make a snowman 堆雪人 92、cut the grass 割草 六年级上册时态及语法知识 1、正在进行时 be doing 2、将来时 be going to 3、被动语态 be﹢动词过去式 4、形容词+er and 形容词+er 越来越……例 如:warmer and warmer 5、形容词+er 为形容词的比较级例如: warmer 更暖 6、形容词+est 为形容词的最高级(需要注 意在最高级前用the 修饰,以元音字母+辅音 字母结尾的词要双写词尾再+est) 7、在句子中,如果主语是“第三人称单数” 那么它所跟随的“动词”需要加“s”例如: He enjoys playing basketball. 一年中的节日及日期 1、January(一月Jan)is the first month of the year. 节日:New Year’s Day(新年). January 1st (1月1日) 2、February(二月Feb)is the second month of the year. 节日:Spring Festival(春节).In January or February. 3、March (三月Mar)is the third month of the year. 节日:Tree Planting Day(植树节)。On March 12th 4、April (四月 Apr)is the fourth month of the year. 节日:Easter(复活节).It can be on any day from March 20th to April 20th . 5、May (五月May)is the fifth month of the year. 节日:Mother’s Day(母亲节)、Labour Day (劳动节).Labour Day is on May 1st. 6、June(六月 Jun)is the sixth month of the year. 节日:Children’s Day(儿童节)、Father’s Day(父亲节). Children’s Day is on June 1st. 7、July(七月Jul)is the seventh month of the year. 8、August(八月Aug)is the eighth month of the year. 节日:Army Day (建军节).It’s on August 1st. 9、September(九月Sep)is the ninth month of the year. 节日:Teachers’Day (教师节).It’s on September 10th. 10、October(十月Oct)is the tenth month of the year. 节日:National Day(国庆节).It’s on October 1st.

鲁教版英语六年级上册听力

鲁教版英语六年级上册听力 篇一:鲁教版六年级上册英语听力任务型阅读 一、听力测试(共20小题,计20分) (一)听句子,选择与句子内容相符的图片按顺序写出答案(其中 有一幅多余)(5分) A BC D E F 1._________ 2.__________ 3.__________ 4.___________ 5._________ (二) 听句子,选择恰当的应答语。(5分) ( )6. A.Mary B. His name’s Eric. C. I’m Gina. ( )7. A.Yes, I have one.B.Yes, I do.C. Yes, I am. ( )8. A.It’s black.B. Yes, it is. C. It’s in the backpack. ( )9. A.Yes, I do. B.Yes, thank you. C.No, I don’t. ( )10.A.That’s a baseball. B. No, it isn’t. C. That sounds good. (三) 听对话,选择最佳答案。(5分) ( )11. What color is the chair? A.Red B. Blue C.yellow ( )12. The boy has a _________. A.tennis ball B. volleyball C. ping-pong ball

( )13. The girl likes _________. A.pears B.strawberries C. oranges ( )14. Where is the ruler?_______________ A.In the backpack. B. On the desk. C. Under the backpack. ( )15. The girl likes fruit for_____. A.breakfast B.lunch C.dinner (四)听短文,填入恰当的内容完成表格。(5分 ) ( )16.A.ping-pong ball B.basketball C.volleyball D.soccer ball ( )17.A.bedB.desk C.tableD.chair ( )18. A.tennisB.volleyball C.baseball D.basketball ( )19. A.pears B.eggs C.banannas https://www.360docs.net/doc/4c16182609.html,k ( )20.A.vegetablesB.carrots C.tamatoes D.chicke 根据短文内容及首字母提示,在空白处填入一个适当的单词。 Jenny is my cousin. She is an E____1____ girl. She likes s___2___. She two ping-pong balls and one baseball. She p__3___ baseball very well. Jenny likes f___4___ and v____5___, so she is very h. For fruit, she has apples and bananas. For vegetables, she has carrots and

那一刻我感受到了幸福_初中作文

那一刻我感受到了幸福 本文是关于初中作文的那一刻我感受到了幸福,感谢您的阅读! 每个人民的心中都有一粒幸福的种子,当它拥有了雨水的滋润和阳光的沐浴,它就会绽放出最美丽的姿态。那一刻,我们都能够闻到幸福的芬芳,我们都能够感受到幸福的存在。 在寒假期间,我偶然在授索电视频道,发现(百家讲坛)栏目中大学教授正在解密幸福,顿然引起我的好奇心,我放下了手中的遥控器,静静地坐在电视前,注视着频道上的每一个字,甚至用笔急速记在了笔记本上。我还记得,那位大学教授讲到了一个故事:一位母亲被公司升职到外国工作,这位母亲虽然十分高兴,但却又十分无奈,因为她的儿子马上要面临中考了,她不能撇下儿子迎接中考的挑战,于是她决定拒绝这了份高薪的工作,当有人问她为什么放弃这么好的机会时,她却毫无遗憾地说,纵然我能给予儿子最贵的礼物,优异的生活环境,但我却无当给予他关键时刻的那份呵护与关爱,或许以后的一切会证明我的选择是正确的。听完这样一段故事,我心中有种说不出的感觉,刹那间,我仿拂感觉那身边正在包饺子的妈妈,屋里正在睡觉的爸爸,桌前正在看小说的妹妹给我带来了一种温馨,幸福感觉。正如教授所说的那种解密幸福。就要选择一个明确的目标,确定自已追求的是什么,或许那时我还不能完全诠释幸福。 当幸福悄悄向我走来时,我已慢慢明白,懂得珍惜了。 那一天的那一刻对我来说太重要了,原本以为出差在外的父母早已忘了我的生日,只有妹妹整日算着日子。我在耳边唠叨个不停,没想到当日我失落地回到家中时,以为心中并不在乎生日,可是眼前的一切,让我心中涌现的喜悦,脸上露出的微笑证明我是在乎的。

爸爸唱的英文生日快乐歌虽然不是很动听,但爸爸对我的那份爱我听得很清楚,妈妈为我做的长寿面,我细细的品尝,吃出了爱的味道。妹妹急忙让我许下三个愿望,嘴里不停的唠叨:我知道你的三个愿望是什么?我问:为什么呀!我们是一家人,心连心呀!她高兴的说。 那一刻我才真正解开幸福的密码,感受到了真正的幸福,以前我无法理解幸福,即使身边有够多的幸福也不懂得欣赏,不懂得珍惜,只想拥有更好更贵的,其实幸福比物质更珍贵。 那一刻的幸福就是爱的升华,许多时候能让我们感悟幸福不是名利,物质。而是在血管里涌动着的,漫过心底的爱。 也许每一个人生的那一刻,就是我们幸运的降临在一个温馨的家庭中,而不是降临在孤独的角落里。 家的感觉就是幸福的感觉,幸福一直都存在于我们的身边!

六年级下册英语短语

六年级下册英语短语 M1: 1.look good 看起来很好2.want to 想要…… 3.how much 多少钱4.be careful 小心5.lots of 许多 M2:1.get up 起床2.have breakfast 吃早饭3.have a picnic 野餐4.at half past twelve 在十二点半5.in the sky 在空中6.on the pond 在池塘里7.have lunch吃午饭8.a beautiful day 一个艳阳天9.go to the park 去公园10.go to school 去学校11.play chess 下象棋12.to go 剩余13.look like 看来好像 M3: 1.look at 看2.write to me给我写信3.on the pond 在池塘里4. have a picnic 野餐5.have a lovely time 玩得很愉快6.have a very interesting day 度过非常有趣的一天7.on Saturday 周六8.start to rain 开始下雨9.fly away 飞走10.clean my room 打扫我的房间11.play hide-and-seek 玩捉迷藏12.look out of the window 向窗外看 M4: 1.buy…for…给……买…… 2.happy birthday 生日快乐3.have a birthday party 举办一个生日派对4.get on/off the bus上/下车5.at the supermarket 在超市6. be careful 小心7.fall down 跌落8.on the phone 打电话 M5: 1.play the suona 吹唢呐2.eat dinner 吃晚饭3.ride a bike骑自行车4.start to rain 开始下雨5.watch TV 看电视6.read a book 读书7.the third time 第三次8.cross the street过马路9.do exercise 做操10.walk in the park 在公园散步11.wake up 醒来12.fly in the sky 在空中飞

六年级英语上册第一单元测试卷含听力材料

P E P小学六年级英语第一单元检测题 Listening Part(听力部分) I. Listen and choose(听音,选择你所听到的单词。) ( )1. A. bookstore B. science museum C. hospital D. cinema ( )2. A. hospital B. cinema C. store D. post office ( )3. A. left B. right C. straight D. crossing ( )4. A. next B. near C. beside D. behind ( )5. A. far B. follow C. feature D. street II. Listen and choose(听音,选择你所听到的句子。) ( )1.A.Let’s go straight and turn left at the crossing. B. Let’s go straight and turn right at the crossing. ( )2. A. How can we get to the hospital? B. How can we get to the crossing? ( )3. A. The museum shop is near the door. B. The museum shop is near the bookstore. ( )4. A. Where is the science museum? B. Where is the museum shop? ( )5. A. There is a science museum next to my home. B. There is a post office next to my home. III. Listen and choose(听问句,选择恰当的答语。) ( )1. Where is the bookstore? A. It’s next to the zoo. B. It’s behind the zoo. C. It’s in front of the zoo. ( )2. Is there a hospital near here? A.I don’t know. B. Yes, there is. C. No, there isn’t. ( )3. How can we get to the restaurant?

关于我的幸福作文八篇汇总

关于我的幸福作文八篇汇总 幸福在每个人的心中都不一样。在饥饿者的心中,幸福就是一碗香喷喷的米饭;在果农的心中,幸福就是望着果实慢慢成熟;在旅行者的心中,幸福就是游遍世界上的好山好水。而在我的心中,幸福就是每天快快乐乐,无忧无虑;幸福就是朋友之间互相帮助,互相关心;幸福就是在我生病时,母亲彻夜细心的照顾我。 幸福在世间上的每个角落都可以发现,只是需要你用心去感受而已。 记得有一次,我早上出门走得太匆忙了,忘记带昨天晚上准备好的钢笔。老师说了:“今天有写字课,必须要用钢笔写字,不能用水笔。”我只好到学校向同学借了。当我来到学校向我同桌借时,他却说:“我已经借别人了,你向别人借吧!”我又向后面的同学借,可他们总是找各种借口说:“我只带了一枝。”问了三四个人,都没有借到,而且还碰了一鼻子灰。正当我急的像热锅上的蚂蚁团团转时,她递给了我一枝钢笔,微笑的对我说:“拿去用吧!”我顿时感到自己是多么幸福!在我最困难的时候,当别人都不愿意帮助我的时候,她向我伸出了援手。 幸福也是无时无刻都在身旁。 当我生病的时候,高烧持续不退时,是妈妈在旁边细心

的照顾我,喂我吃药,甚至一夜寸步不离的守在我的床边,直到我苏醒。当我看见妈妈的眼睛布满血丝时,我的眼眶在不知不觉地湿润了。这时我便明白我有一个最疼爱我的妈妈,我是幸福的! 幸福就是如此简单!不过,我们还是要珍惜眼前的幸福,还要给别人带来幸福,留心观察幸福。不要等幸福悄悄溜走了才发现,那就真的是后悔莫及了! 这就是我拥有的幸福,你呢? 悠扬的琴声从房间里飘出来,原来这是我在弹钢琴。优美的旋律加上我很强的音乐表现力让一旁姥爷听得如醉如痴。姥爷说我是幸福的,读了《建设幸福中国》我更加体会到了这一点。 儿时的姥爷很喜欢读书,但当时家里穷,据姥爷讲那时上学可不像现在。有点三天打鱼两天晒网,等地里农活忙了太姥爷就说:“别去念书了,干地里的活吧。”干活时都是牛马拉车,也没机器,效率特别低。还要给牲口拔草,喂草,拾柴火,看书都是抽空看。等农闲时才能背书包去学校,衣服更是老大穿了,打补丁老二再接着穿,只有盼到过年时才有能换上件粗布的新衣服。写字都是用石板,用一次擦一次,那时还没有电灯,爱学习的姥爷在昏暗的煤油灯下经常被灯火不是烧了眉毛就是燎了头发。没有电灯更没有电视,没有电视更没有见过钢琴,只知道钢琴是贵族家用的。

小学六年级下册英语单词汇总

小学六年级下册英语单词汇总 词汇量(六年级) 1. 名词 (1) 与学校有关的词以及学习用具: bag(书包) , class(班级) , classroom (教室) , grade (年级),desk(书桌) , book(书) , pen(钢笔) , pencil (铅笔), pencil box(笔盒) , picture(图画、照片) , English[英语、英国(人)的] , ruler(尺子) , stamp(邮票) , school(学校) , student(学生), computer(电脑), flag(旗), kite(风筝), letter(字母、信), notebook(笔记本), storybook(故事书), Chinese[中国(人)的、中国人、汉语] , maths(数学), PE(体育), science(科学), art(美术), music(音乐), eraser(橡皮擦,黑板擦), dictionary(字典), group(组), paper(纸),homework(作业),song(歌 曲),sports(运动),word(词语),email(电子邮件),libraly(图书馆),CD-ROM(光盘),question(问题),race(比赛) (2) 称谓\人称: mother(母亲), father(父亲) , mum(妈妈) , dad(爸爸), teacher(老师), brother(兄弟) ,sister(姐妹), girl(女孩) , boy(男孩) , child[小孩(单数)] , children[小孩(复数)], friend(朋友), pupil(小学生), aunt(伯母,婶母;姨母,姑母;舅母), uncle (叔伯;舅父;姑父,姨父), baby(婴儿), daughter(女儿), son(儿子), man(成年男子), woman(成年女人), family(家庭),grandma(祖母),grandpa(祖父),Mr(先生),Ms(小姐),parent(父母),pen friend(笔友) (3) 房间: door(门), wall(墙), bed(床), window(窗) , living room(客厅),bedroom(卧室), doll(玩具娃娃), floor(地板), house(房子), picture(图片) , present(礼物), toy(玩具), home(家),chair(椅子),room(房间)

六年级英语下册1--8单元词组短语综合复习

六年级下册各单元短语Unit 1 1.in the forest 在森林里 2.walk by 走过… 3.wake ... up 唤醒狮子 4.want to 想… 5.some day 某一天 6.small and weak 又小又弱 7.the next day 第二天 8.get out 出去 9.just then 就在那时 0.from then on 从那时起 11.let …go 释放;放开 12.Aesop’s Fables 《伊索寓言》 13.a Chinese idiom book 一本中国成语书 14.find many animal stories 发现许多动物故事 15.play table tennis 打乒乓球 16.be good at =do well in 擅长 17.hit the ball hard 用力击球 18.find a hole in the ground 在地上发现一个洞 19.reach it 够到它 20.have an idea 有一个好办法 21.bring some water 带来一些水 22.pour …into …把…倒入… 23.well done 干得好 24.a shopping centre 一个购物中心 25.on the floor 在地板上 26.take to 把…带入… 27. cheer for...为。。。欢呼 28. too deep太深 29.the sweet shop 糖果店 30.it doesn’t matter. 没关系。 Unit 2 1.good habits/ a good habit 好习惯 2.bad habits/ a bad habit 坏习惯 3.go to bed early睡得早 4.put ... in order 把...整理得井井有条 https://www.360docs.net/doc/4c16182609.html,st night 昨晚 6.go into 走进,走入 7.brush one’s teeth 刷牙 8.before bedtime 睡觉前

PEP版六年级英语上册听力专项复习卷(一)

听力专项复习卷(一) 题号一二三四五六总分得分 一、听录音,选出所听句子中出现的一项。(10分) ()1. A. ant B. angry C. afraid ()2. A. bus B. by C. businessman ()3. A. count B. country C. crossing ()4. A. far B. fall C. feel ()5. A. gave B. get C. gym 二、听录音,选出与所听内容相符的图片。(10分) () 1. A. B. C.

() 2. A. B. C.

() 3. A. B. C.

() 4. A. B. C.

() 5. A. B. C.

三、听录音,选择正确的答语。(20分) () 1. A. It's a bookstore. B. It's in the bookstore. C. It's in front of the museum. () 2. A. I usually come to school at 7:30. B. I live near school. C. I often come to school on foot. () 3. A. I'm going to have a music lesson. B. I like drawing pictures. C. I don't like the park. () 4. A. He likes reading books. B. She likes going hiking. C. He is going to sing a song. () 5. A. Yes, he does. B. Yes, he is. C. Yes, we are. 四、听对话,根据对话内容判断以下内容正误,正确写T,错误写F。(20分) () 1. Amy often goes to school by bus. () 2. Linda is going to buy a comic book this afternoon. () 3. Amy's uncle studies Chinese in Beijing. () 4. Sam's grandfather works in a big factory. () 5. Peter's brother was ill, but he feels well now. 五、听短文,连线。(20分)

小学生作文《感悟幸福》范文五篇汇总

小学生作文《感悟幸福》范文五篇 小草说,幸福就是大地增添一份绿意;阳光说,幸福就是撒向人间的温暖;甘露说,幸福就是滋润每一个生命。下面是为大家带来的有关幸福650字优秀范文,希望大家喜欢。 感悟幸福650字1 生活就像一部壮丽的交响曲,它是由一篇一篇的乐章组成的,有喜、有怒、有哀、有乐。每一个人都有自己丰富多彩的生活,我也有自己的生活。我原本以为,吃可口的牛排,打电脑游戏,和朋友开心玩乐就是幸福。可是,我错了,幸福并不仅仅如此。 记得有一次,我放学回到家里放下书包就拿起一包饼干来吃。吃着吃着,突然我觉得牙齿痛了起来,而且越来越痛,痛得我连饼干也咬不动了。我放下饼干,连忙去拿了一面镜子来看。原来这又是那一颗虫牙在“作怪”。“哎哟哟,哎哟哟,痛死我了……”我不停地说着。渐渐地,那牙疼得越来越厉害,疼得我坐立不安,直打滚。后来在妈妈的陪伴下去了医院,治好了那颗虫牙。跨出医院大门时,我觉得心情出奇的好,天空格外的蓝,路边的樟树特别的绿,看什么都顺眼,才猛然一悟,幸福是简单而平凡的,身体健康就是一种幸福! 这学期我发现我的英语退步了,我决定要把这门功课学好,于是,我每天回

家做完作业后,都抽出半小时时间复习英语,在课上也听得特别认真,一遇到不懂的题目主动请教老师。经过一段时间的努力,终于,在上次考试的时候,我考了97分。妈妈表扬了我,我心里美滋滋的。我明白了经过自己的努力享受到成功的喜悦,这也是一种幸福。 …… 每个人都无一例外的渴望幸福。不同的人有不同的感受,其实,幸福就是那种能在平凡中寻找欢乐、能在困境中找到自信的一种心境。同学们,幸福其实很简单,就在我们的身边,触手可及。用心去认真地品味吧,它一直未曾离开我们身边! 感悟幸福650字2 有的人认为幸福就是腰缠万贯,有的人认为幸福就是找到意中人,“采菊东篱下,悠然见南山”是陶渊明对邪恶幸福,“从明天起做一个幸福人,喂马、劈柴、周游世界。从明天起,关心蔬菜和粮食,我有一所房子,面朝大海,春暖花开。”这是海子的幸福。一千种人就有一千种对幸福的理解。 我对幸福的理解就是幸福使简单而平凡的,是无处不在的! 我的牙疼得奇怪而顽强不是这颗牙疼就是那颗牙疼;不是吃冷的疼就是吃热

六年级上英语听力材料和答案

2012—2013学年度第一学期 小学英语六年级期中测试卷听力材料及答案一、Listen and choose(听音,根据你所听到的内容,选择相符合的 一项,并将其字母编号写在题前的括号里。) 1. Go straight. 2. I am going to Australia by plane. 3. Red means stop. 4. I usually go to school on foot. 5. I often plant trees in March. 6. There are twelve months in a year. 7. What are you going to do this weekend? 8. We’re going to play chess under the big tree. 9. Sometimes I go to school by bus. 10. Get on the No.3 bus 参考答案: A C C A A A B C B B 二、Listen and judge. 你将听到一个句子或一组对话,根据所听到的内容, 在每小题的大图中圈出相符的图片。别忘了先浏览选项!每小题读两遍。 1.I usually go to Canada with my parents by plane. ( picture 3) 2.No entry. (picture 1) 3.The science museum is near my home. So I often go there with my classmate on the weekend. (picture 2) 4.Excuse me, how can I get to the cinema ? Turn left at the zoo. It’s on the right. (picture 3) 5.I am going to buy a dictionary for my brother this weekend. (picture 2) 6.Where is my toy bus, dad? Look! It’s behind the desk. (picture 2 ) 7.Turn left at the park, you will see the bookstore. It’s near the park. (picture 1) 8.Where is John going next Sunday? He is going to the Great Wall.

关于以幸福为话题的作文800字记叙文5篇

关于以幸福为话题的作文800字记叙文5篇 ----WORD文档,下载后可编辑修改---- 下面是作者为各位家长学生收集整理的作文(日记、观后感等)范本,欢迎借鉴参考阅读,您的努力学习和创新是为了更美好的未来,欢迎下载! 以幸福为话题的作文800字记叙文1: 那是我生病后的第三天,妈妈从早上五点就起来为我准备早点。她蹑手蹑脚地走着“针步”,下楼煮早点,“啪”的一声,妈妈打开了煤气。在拿肉丝,打鸡蛋的她全然不知我正躲在楼梯口“监视”着她的一举一动。不一会儿,蛋炒好了。 她开始切肉丝,一不小心,妈妈的手指切破皮了,鲜血正一滴一滴地流下来,为了不影响我的睡眠,她把手指放在嘴里吸了一下,坚持把剩下的肉丝切完。 此时的我,心中犹如打翻了五味瓶,眼里的泪像断了线的珍珠般掉了下来,我再也忍不住了,一个劲地冲到妈妈面前,她赶紧把手背了过去,生怕让我知道了什么。 她吃惊地问我:“妈妈太吵了,吵到你了?”“不,不,没有”她见我这么早起来就让我再回去补个觉。我关心地问:“妈,你的手没事吧?”她吱唔着说:“没事,擦破点皮,不碍事!”我仔细地帮她清洗了伤口,贴了一片创可贴。 吃饭时,妈妈一直地往我碗里夹肉,“孩子,病刚好,多吃点!”可是我见她始终都没吃一块肉。我也夹了两块放在她的碗里。“儿子懂事了,你自己快点吃吧!补身体要紧!”我冲她点点头笑了笑,“嗯。” 这就是幸福,一份简简单单的幸福!我祈祷这幸福能伴我成长。 以幸福为话题的作文800字记叙文2: 在我眼中,成长就是记录我们长大过程中一点一滴的小事情的,而幸福就在这点点滴滴中。 在我的成长记忆中,永不磨灭的是2017年11月的一天。妈妈要去云南,妈妈早上四点半要到指定地点集合,这么早,妈妈要两三点就起来,可是最近我咳嗽比较严重,所以天天给我煮萝卜汤喝。 “叮铃铃,叮铃铃”闹钟叫了起来,把我从睡梦中吵醒,一醒来,去找妈妈,

【免费】小学六年级英语下册单词表

小学六年级英语下册单词表 unit 1 weigh weigh 有重:重 kilogram kilongram 千克;公斤(缩略形式kg)centimetre centimetre 厘米(缩略形式cm) taller taller 更高的 fan fan (足球,电影)迷;爱好者 fantastic fantastic 极好的 themselves themselves 他们自己;她们自己;它们自己theatre theatre 剧院 go fishing go fishing去钓鱼 enjoy oneself enjoy oneself 玩的愉快;得到乐趣 get in get in 收割 unit 2 life life 生活 writer writer 作家 photographer photographer 摄影师 film film 胶卷 digital digital 数码的 street cleaner street cleaner 环卫工人 sweep sweep 扫地

broom broom 扫帚 drive drive 驾驶 street sweeper street sweeper 扫地车 wife wife 妻子 poor poor 贫穷的;差的;次的 fairy fairy 仙子;小精灵 wish wish 愿望;祝愿 by hand by hand 用手 right away right away 立即;马上 in a short time in a short time 很快 unit 3 carry carry 被;提;拿 online online 在线地;在线的 head teacher head teacher 校长 ps附言(用于信末) mountain mountain 由:山脉 even even 甚至 space space 太空 dinosaur dinosaur 恐龙 a piece of a piece of 去野餐 better and better better and better 越来越好

外研版英语六年级下册短语汇总

Module 1 hot dog热狗 I don’t know. 我不知道 look good 看起来不错 Can I help you? 我能帮你吗 how much多少钱 here you are. 给你 Thank you. 谢谢你 enjoy your meal 祝你用餐愉快 be careful 当心 I’m sorry 我很抱歉 want to 想要 lots of /a lot of 许多,大量的come in 进来 Module 2 get up 起床 have breakfast 吃早餐 have lunch 吃午餐 have dinner 吃晚餐 have a/our picnic举行野餐 be going to打算,将要 in the park在公园 go to the park去公园 at half past twelve 十二点半What time is it now? 现在几点了one hour to go 差一个小时 on the pond在池塘上dark clouds 乌云 in the sky在空中 I don’t thank so.我不这样认为 a beautiful day 一个好天 Let’s go 让我们走 oh dear 天哪 oh no 不 look at 看 look like看来好像 stay hungry继续挨饿 after dinner 晚餐之后 play chess 下象棋 go to bed 上床睡觉 have a good night 祝你好梦 read a book 看书 at home 在家 Module 3 naughty bird 淘气的小鸟 little dog 小狗 How are you?你好吗 have a very interesting day 非常有趣的一天 send you some photos 寄给你一些图片miss everyone 想念每个人 write to me soon 快点给我回信 in the tree在树上 start to rain 开始下雨 fly away飞走 clean the room 打扫房间 in this photo在这张照片中

六年级英语上册单元测试听力材料与答案

六年级英语上册单元测试听力材料及答案(一) 听力材料: 一、听录音,选出你所听到的单词。 1. hospital 2. cinema 3. right 4. crossing 5. turn 二、听录音,填入所缺单词,每空一词。 1. How can I get to the science museum ? 2. Go straigh t and turn right at the bookstore. 3. Turn left at the hospital . 4. The hospital is next to the bank. 5. Where is the cinema ? It ’s near the library. 三、听音,选图画。 1.Excuse me. Where is the hospital? 2.—How can I get to the bookstore? — Turn left at the cinema. 3.Where is the museum shop? I want to buy a post card. 4.I’m hungry. I like pizza. Let’s go to the restaurant. 5.--Excuse me. Is there a post office near here?— Yes, there is. 四、听句子,选择合适的答句。 1.Excuse me, where is the museum shop? 2.How can we get there? 3.I want to send a post card. 4.Is there a bookstore near the school? 5.Where is the park? Turn left here? 答案: 一、CAACA 二、略 三、CACAB 四、ACAAB 五、 1-5BBACA 6-10ABCCC 六、 1.Where is the cinema? 2.It ’s next to the hospital on Dongfang Street. 3.How can I get to the post office? 4.Turn right at the hospital. 5.What a great museum! 六年级英语上册单元测试题(二) 听力原文:

最新整理高中关于幸福的议论文800字范文3篇

最新整理高中关于幸福的议论文800字范文3篇 范文一 什么是幸福?当我把一个棒棒糖递给六岁的邻居小妹妹时,她满足的笑容告诉我,这是她的幸福。当我轻轻地走过妹妹的写字台时,我瞥见埋在桌上的妹妹的僵硬的表情。我笑笑,走近,她抬头,水汪汪的眼睛望着我,似乎带着某种渴求。我说:出去玩吧!她笑了,蹦蹦跳跳地跑了出去。我诧异,这么真诚的笑。玩耍是她的幸福。 暑假到了,马上面临实习的哥哥回来了。可没过几天,就不见人影了,好容易盼他回来,暑假也结束了。他说他去了内蒙的好多地方。我关切的问他累吗?他说:累啊!随后又骄傲地说:“可是我学会了许多东西,我相信那对我以后的人生路是有帮助的。”我笑,大声地喊:哥,你是我的榜样。在他看来,他的暑假是充实的,他是幸福的! 夜幕降临,繁星点点。隔着一层帘,我看见常年劳作的父亲坐在那里,默默地吸着一支烟。灯光打在他的脸上,我看不清他的表情,只有那斑白的鬓角依稀可见。父亲真的老了,每天早出晚归来支撑这个家,他一定很累了。眼泪盈满了眼眶,最后还是不争气的流了下来……“咳、、咳、、”一阵剧烈的咳嗽声传来。我擦干眼泪,走到父亲旁边,父亲把那支烟熄灭,慈祥的笑笑,说:爸爸老了,不中用了。我说:没有啊!父女两开怀的笑了,笑声混着一个个烟圈飘向远方……我问父亲:爸,这么多年付出,这么多年劳作,你幸福吗?他坚定地告诉我,幸福!他说:“只要你们开开心心快快乐乐地成长,我做的一切都值得。”他又说:“霞,好好读书,爸爸赚钱供你上大学,我还没老呢,至少还能干XX年,20年……然后是一片寂静,我和父亲看着远方,那里有希望。 年迈的姥姥是家里的大长辈,他常常念叨:平安就是福。那也许是经历了人生的酸甜苦辣后的感悟吧!每逢新春,一大家人在姥姥家围着看电视时,那应该是她的幸福吧! 幸福是什么?它不是你一个人拥有一座豪宅,它是一家人在并不宽敞的屋子里谈笑风生。它不是你一个人有拥山珍海味,它是一家人和和乐乐的吃一些普通

相关文档
最新文档