德国汽车工业 英文

德国汽车工业 英文
德国汽车工业 英文

Relocation, Offshoring and Labour Market Repercussions: The Case of the German Automobile Industry in Central Europe

By Peter Nunnenkamp*

Abstract:

The paper raises the proposition that Central Europe’s integration into the international division of labour has added significantly to competitive pressure in the German automobile industry. Based on production and trade data, we trace two dimensions of competitive pressure: relocation of assembly operations and offshoring of automotive parts production. The knowledge-capital model of multinational enterprises provides the analytical basis for the discussion of labour market repercussions. Vertical foreign direct investment in Central Europe may have helped the relatively favourable employment and earnings record of the German automobile industry, compared to other manufacturing industries. Yet recent industrial disputes can be attributed, though not exclusively, to the emergence of Central Europe as an attractive location for assembly operations and autoparts production. Employment and wages diverged considerably within the German automobile industry. Relative to skilled workers, the labour market situation of less skilled workers deteriorated significantly.

JEL codes: F14, F23, L62

Keywords: vertical FDI, trade in intermediates, relative wages, employment

* The Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Kiel, Germany. E-mail address: peter.nunnenkamp@ifw-kiel.de.

This paper is a substantially revised and updated version of Nunnenkamp (2005). Comments by Joergen Ulff-Moeller Nielsen and Konrad Pawlik from the Aarhus School of Business are gratefully acknowledged. The author also would like to thank the discussant, PD Dr. André Jungmittag, and the participants of the 69th Annual ARGE Meeting for critical comments and useful suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

I. Introduction

The automobile industry is widely regarded as an export champion in Germany. Only France and Japan exported more automobiles than Germany in 2004 (VDA a, 2005: 362). The contribution of exports of road vehicles (SITC 78) to Germany’s total exports of manufactures increased from 18.5 percent in 1993 to 22 percent in 2004 (OECD 2005). Moreover, employment and earnings opportunities have traditionally been favourable in the German automobile industry, compared to the manufacturing average (Spatz and Nunnenkamp 2002a, 2002b).

Yet the automobile industry offers a particularly interesting example to evaluate the fiercer competition from Central European countries as well as the production, trade and labour market repercussions in traditional locations such as Germany. The industry witnessed a series of industrial disputes in recent years, most of which were triggered by the threat of German companies to relocate production to cheaper locations, notably in Central Europe. For example, Opel, the German subsidiary of General Motors, decided in mid-2004 to locate part of its Zafira production in Gliwice, Poland, even though the assembly line at the company’s headquarter in Rüsselsheim had considerable spare capacity. The decision was based on a comparative analysis that revealed strong competitive advantages of the former location. Low-wage competition from the neighbouring Czech Republic notwithstanding, BMW decided to build its new production site in Saxony. However, Bosch, a major supplier of autoparts, revealed plans to relocate further 800 workplaces from France to the Czech Republic. Continental, a producer of tyres, announced in fall 2005 to close down production lines in Hanover, even though workers had agreed a few months earlier to longer working hours in order to reduce labour costs.

Against this backdrop, the paper raises the proposition that Central Europe’s integration into the international division of labour has added significantly to competitive pressure in the German automobile industry, including the production of autoparts, even though this industry is relatively skill and technology intensive and represents a traditional stronghold of advanced countries.1 According to the knowledge-capital model of multinational enterprises (Carr et al. 2001), the labour market repercussions can be expected to depend on the type of foreign direct investment (FDI) (Section II). Wage inequality or unemployment of less qualified

1Vickery (1996) and Wei? (2000) show that the development and manufacturing of automobiles requires increasing R&D and involves significant fixed costs.

workers in Germany are supposed to increase if vertical FDI, which involves the relocation of relatively labour intensive stages of production to lower-income countries, plays a major role with regard to the automobile industry’s engagement in Central Europe. The evidence on the relocation of assembly operations and offshoring of autoparts production, presented in Sections III and IV, suggests that this is indeed the case. The labour market effects of fiercer competitive pressure are assessed in Section V. We argue that the recent controversy on whether the automobile industry exemplifies the case of Germany degenerating into a bazaar economy misses an important point, namely diverging employment and earnings trends within this industry. Section VI concludes.

Background and Earlier Findings

II. Analytical

Based on standard theoretical models on the distributional effects of the liberalization of trade with, and foreign direct investment (FDI) in lower-income countries, the integration of Central Europe into international production and sourcing networks can be expected to negatively affect the labour market situation of relatively low skilled workers in high-income countries such as Germany (Spatz and Nunnenkamp 2002b: 477).2 In a recent survey on trade and wages, Feenstra and Hanson (2003) argue that trade in intermediate inputs is a potentially important explanation for the increase in the wage gap between skilled and unskilled workers in advanced economies. The literature on the motives and effects of FDI offers further insights which help analyse the labour market repercussions of automobile production in countries with relatively low per-capita income. Marin et al. (2003) and Marin (2004) suspect that the wage and employment effects of outward FDI by economically advanced countries in lower-income countries depend on the type of FDI :

?Companies undertaking horizontal FDI produce the same goods and services in their home country and in the host countries.3 This type of FDI is often motivated by trade barriers, transportation costs and other transaction costs that discourage exports (Carr et al.

2001). FDI is a means to avoid such costs. Horizontal FDI is driven by market considerations. That is why this type of FDI is also known as market-seeking FDI (UNCTAD 1998: 91).

2See also the literature given there.

3For an early model of horizontal FDI, see Markusen (1984); more recent models include Markusen and Venables (1998, 2000).

?Companies undertaking vertical FDI fragment the production process geographically and locate specific stages of the value chain in countries offering the relevant cost advantages.4 This type of FDI is motivated by cost considerations. Investors make use of varying factor endowments and differences in factor prices across countries (Zhang and Markusen 1999).

FDI of this type is also known as efficiency-seeking FDI (UNCTAD 1998: 91).

According to Marin et al. (2003), wage inequality or unemployment in economically advanced economies is likely to increase if outward FDI is of the vertical type. This is because the investor relocates the relatively labour intensive stages of production to lower-income countries, thereby reducing the demand for unskilled workers in the home country.5 Unless unskilled workers agree to lower relative wages, they will face deteriorating employment opportunities. By contrast, these authors do not expect horizontal FDI to have effects on wage inequality or employment opportunities in the advanced country.

In particular the so-called knowledge-capital model of multinational enterprises (Carr et al. 2001) offers several arguments to suspect that the engagement of German automobile companies in Central Europe is largely vertical in nature. In many respects, this engagement resembles the vertical production networks of US-based automobile companies with their affiliates in NAFTA partner countries, notably Mexico (Hanson et al. 2005). First, the motive for horizontal FDI to avoid high trade and transaction costs associated with exporting from the German home base should be of minor importance for serving Central European markets.6 These markets are fairly close to the home base of German investors (i.e., transportation costs are relatively low), and the protection of these markets is rather weak as trade costs resulting from import barriers have been removed since various countries prepared for EU membership.7 Second, markets for (new) automobiles in Central Europe are small compared to the German home market.8 This limits the potential to exploit (plant-level) economies of

4For an early model of vertical FDI, see Helpman (1984); see also Helpman and Krugman (1985).

5Feenstra and Hanson (2003) argue along similar lines. However, they consider foreign outsourcing which extends beyond FDI-related offshoring and includes arm's-length trade in intermediate goods.

6In Helpman’s (1984) model of vertical FDI, trade costs were assumed to be zero. As noted by Carr et al.

(2001), this assumption, in combination with plant-level economies of scale, removes the motive for horizontal FDI.

7Prospective EU member countries had abolished import duties on cars imported from the EU by 2001 (van Tulder 2004: 106).

8Even in Poland, i.e., the largest Central European market for automobiles, first registrations of passenger cars in 2001-2004 did not exceed one tenth of first registrations in Germany (VDA b).

scale in assembly operations located in Central European countries, which, in turn, should reduce the incentive to engage in horizontal FDI (Carr et al. 2001).

Third, different factor endowments and factor price differentials between Germany and Central Europe, in combination with low trade costs and geographical proximity, provide incentives to undertake vertical FDI. Central Europe tends to be better endowed of relatively skilled labour than many developing countries. According to Zhang and Markusen (1999: 237), the case for vertical FDI no longer exists if “countries become extremely different”, i.e., sufficiently skilled labour being so scarce in the potential host country that multinational companies will find it difficult to hire local staff such as technicians and administrative employees. Likewise, vertical FDI is supposed to depend on the host country meeting minimum standards with regard to power supply, transport and telecommunication infrastructure as well as legal institutions. In contrast to many developing countries, it can be assumed that Central European countries fulfil these basic requirements for vertical FDI to take place.

Nevertheless, the labour market repercussions of the engagement of the German automobile industry in Central Europe are open to question for both analytical and empirical reasons. The differentiation between horizontal and vertical FDI is not as clear-cut as it might appear at first sight.9 On the one hand, the labour market implications of vertical FDI depend on whether the cost reduction associated with such a strategy results in an overall expansion of the investing company, including complementary operations at home (Becker et al. 2005). On the other hand, FDI appears to be horizontal if automobile companies produce the same final good, namely finished cars, at home and abroad. Yet, under certain circumstances, this engagement may be motivated by cost considerations and can have labour market repercussions at home. For instance, this may be the case if the automobile company produces higher quality cars at home, but relocates the production of models serving the lower segment of the market to countries offering cost advantages in the assembly of such cars. Even FDI undertaken for the assembly of cars that are similar to those assembled at home can be

9According to Hanson et al. (2005: 666), different affiliates "fall in a continuum with pure horizontal FDI at one extreme and pure vertical FDI at the other extreme." Ekholm et al. (2003) model so-called export-platform FDI which has both horizontal and vertical features. The model of Markusen and Venables (2005) encompasses both market-serving and export-platform motives for fragmentation of production. While it mainly depends on trade costs whether countries engage in market-serving or export-platform activity, it is mainly determined by factor endowments whether countries specialize in production of components or assembly of final goods.

considered vertical as long as technology intensive and human-capital intensive activities such as the design and development of cars are concentrated in the relatively skill-abundant home country.10

Empirical studies portray an ambiguous picture with respect to the type of FDI in Central Europe and possible labour market repercussions.11 Earlier surveys typically suggest that market considerations are prominent motives for FDI in Central Europe (e.g., Lansbury et al. 1996: 104). Bechert and Cellarius (2004) note that “the great majority” of local employees of German subsidiaries in this region “are also involved in production that is intended for local markets.” As concerns the automobile industry, Sturgeon and Florida (1999: 53) find “a large measure of convergence toward building vehicles where they are sold.” Buch et al. (2005) show that the market size of host countries has a relatively large impact on German FDI in the automobile industry. The estimation results of Carstensen and Toubal (2003) indicate that both horizontal and vertical FDI exists in Central Europe.12 Marin et al. (2003) show that the affiliates of German companies in the machinery and transport equipment sector of Central and Eastern European countries deliver almost 40 percent of production to their German parents, which, according to Hanson et al. (2001), is a clear indication of vertical FDI. The incentives for vertical specialization are stressed by Marin (2004), who finds that German direct investors can reduce unit labour costs by about 70 percent in several Central European countries.

Few studies have assessed the repercussions of FDI-related relocation and offshoring on German labour markets.13 Becker et al. (2005) estimate a translog cost function to assess how outward FDI affects employment at home. With respect to German companies in Central and

10Carr et al. (2001) derive the motive for vertical FDI, i.e., locating knowledge intensive activities such as R&D where skilled labour is relatively cheap and production where unskilled labour is relatively cheap, from two assumptions: (i) knowledge intensive activities can be geographically separated from production and supplied to production facilities at low cost, and (ii) production requires less skills than activities such as R&D.

11This also applies to the earlier literature on the labour market effects of US FDI in lower-income countries (notably in Mexico in the context of NAFTA). This literature is shortly reviewed in Nunnenkamp (2006). See also Blomstr?m et al. (1997) as well as Braconier and Ekholm (2000) on Swedish FDI, and Federico and Minerva (2005) on Italian FDI.

12These authors find a robust and strong impact of the market potential of host countries on FDI. At the same time, relative unit labour costs are shown to exert a significant influence on FDI.

13The survey on the labour market implications of global production sharing by Feenstra and Hanson (2003) clearly reveals that the relevant literature is strongly concentrated on the case of the United States. Hardly any references are made to the case of Germany. At the same time, Feenstra and Hanson stress that more research is needed on outsourcing in Central and Eastern Europe, which should be of particular relevance to German companies.

Eastern Europe, it turns out that a one percent wage reduction at existing affiliates in this region reduces employment in German parent companies, though only by about 0.04 percent. By contrast, Konings and Murphy (2001) reject the hypothesis that FDI by European direct investors, about 30 percent of which were based in Germany, has contributed to a relocation of domestic jobs to Central and Eastern Europe. By estimating the labour demand function of German parent companies, Marin (2004) even finds that a 10 percent wage decline for affiliates located in Central European EU-accession countries increases employment at home by 1.6 percent. Domestic job creation is attributed to cost savings and, thus, improved competitiveness that parent companies achieved through FDI-related offshoring.

Apart from ambiguous findings, the aforementioned studies offer an incomplete picture of possible labour market repercussions of German FDI in Central Europe. In addition to the effects on employment in the parent companies, offshoring may affect employment in German companies which traditionally served as input suppliers of these parent companies. This suggests to assess labour market effects at the industry level, rather than only at the company level. Furthermore, vertical FDI in Central Europe may not only affect employment at home but also the wages paid there. Finally, none of the studies captures the distributional effects that can be expected to result from vertical FDI. More precisely, the question whether less skilled workers in Germany suffered deteriorating relative employment and wage prospects due to relocation and FDI-related offshoring to Central Europe is still unsettled.

Data constraints typically prevent an adequate differentiation between skill groups. However, as shown below for the automobile industry, industry-specific case studies may offer at least tentative insights into the distributional effects of vertical FDI. Before returning to this issue in Section V, we present some stylised facts on the relocation of automobile assembly (Section III) and offshoring of autoparts production (Section IV) that are supposed to reveal the type of FDI undertaken by the German automobile industry in Central Europe.

III. Relocation of Car Assembly to Central Europe

FDI by the German automobile industry, including autoparts, in Central and Eastern Europe has gained considerable momentum. FDI stocks soared fivefold since 1995 to € 6 billion in 2003 (Deutsche Bundesbank 2005). Since the late 1990s, Central and Eastern Europe has hosted higher FDI stocks than Latin America, which had traditionally been the preferred

investment location of the German automobile industry outside the advanced OECD area. Hungary, the Czech Republic and Poland accounted for 80 percent of FDI stocks in the region in 2003.14 FDI stocks held by the German automobile industry in Hungary exceeded those in China, even though automobile multinationals consider China to be the most promising market and are eager to build or acquire production capacities there.

As noted before, it is fairly difficult to clearly distinguish between horizontal and vertical FDI. Yet there are several indications that the activities of the German automobile industry in Central Europe are not restricted to horizontal FDI. The regime change in Central Europe, the region’s opening up to world markets and the accession of various countries to the EU not only promised new markets and export opportunities for German automobile producers, but also offered profitable investment opportunities.15 In contrast to China and Latin America, Central Europe has emerged as an important export platform for German automobile producers. Production and trade data for passenger cars (units) reveal that the character of German FDI in Central Europe differs from that in other low-income locations (Table 1).

In China and Latin America (proxied by the most important locations, Brazil and Mexico), car production of German companies developed independently from trade. German car exports to these markets hardly existed before companies invested there; exports were no reasonable option because of high import barriers. As a consequence, labour market repercussions in Germany resulting from exports being replaced by foreign production are highly unlikely. At the same time, German car imports from China and Latin America remained marginal throughout the period under consideration, largely because production in China and Brazil lacked international competitiveness and transportation costs are high. Hence, production in Germany could hardly be affected negatively by rising imports from these locations.

14 The Slovak Republic, most likely, accounts for much of the rest, mainly because of Volkswagen's

engagement in this country. However, the Slovak Republic is not listed as an individual host country in the Bundesbank statistics (Deutsche Bundesbank 2005).

15Humphrey and Memedovic (2003: 34) reckon: “The initial attraction for…extending production networks from…Western Europe to the peripheral regions was a combination of access to growing markets and reducing costs through the development of low-cost production sites.” For a similar line of reasoning with regard to Volkswagen’s acquisition of Skoda, see Pries (1999). The survey results of Dichtl and Hardock (1997) reveal that labour costs played an important role in motivating the first waves of relocation to Central Europe. Van Tulder and Ruigrok (1998) as well as van Tulder (2004) point out that European car manufacturers pursued different strategies: Some companies rated Central Europe primarily as a market, some as a production site, and some aimed at both.

Table 1 — Passenger Cars: Foreign Production by German Companies and German Imports and Exports, 1990–2004 (1000 units)

Central Europe a China Brazil and Mexico

prod. imp. exp. prod. imp. exp. prod. imp. exp.

1990 0.0 11.0 6.6 0.0 0.0 2.8 425.8 1.3 1.1 1996 240.1 68.9 126.2 226.4 0.0 4.0 735.0 6.9 11.9 2002 782.4 261.6 100.7 437.6 0.3 22.9 799.8 24.0 33.9 2004 817.3 233.3 114.8 575.5 5.6 44.2b 748.9 42.6 22.9 a Czech Rep., Hungary, Poland and Slovak Rep. – b 2003.

Source: VDA (a).

A different situation prevails with regard to Central Europe. Almost one third of car production by German companies in the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and the Slovak Republic was destined for the German market in recent years. German car imports from these countries have multiplied since the early 1990s.Van Tulder and Ruigrok (1998: 10) expect this development to have labour market repercussions in Germany, as “the (threat of) reimportations puts the domestic bargaining arena under pressure.”

Labour market repercussions resulting from car imports may be moderate for the time being. The ratio of imports from the four Central European locations to passenger car production in Germany increased substantially from 1.5 percent in 1995/96, but the ratio did not exceed the

5 percent mark in 2003/04. Moreover, it might be questioned that assembly operations in Germany were affected significantly since producers such as Volkswagen used production sites in Central Europe to complement their existing product range. Consequently, substitution effects may be minor even though the focus on relatively cheap lower-end cars may be characterized as vertical FDI (Section II).

However, German car exports to the four Central European countries increased by much less than German imports. As a result, Germany reported a considerable import surplus in recent years (Table 1). Furthermore, the import surplus is no longer in terms of units only, as observed in the 1990s by van Tulder and Ruigrok (1998). In value terms, the German trade balance for motor vehicles (including chassis) vis-à-vis the four Central European countries switched from an export surplus of € 250 million in 1995 to a deficit of almost € 3 billion in 2004 (VDA a).

The development over time of German exports of passenger cars to Central Europe provides further clues to substitution effects. Exports peaked in 1996 and remained almost flat thereafter, i.e., exactly when production by German automobile companies in the region soared from about 0.2 million units per annum to 0.8 million units in 2004 (Nunnenkamp 2005: Figure 2). It is almost impossible to decide how exports to Central Europe would have developed if German companies were not engaged in assembly operations in this region. Yet, it is striking that the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and the Slovak Republic together absorbed less German exports of passenger cars than neighbouring Austria in 2002 (Nunnenkamp 2004). Additional substitution effects may have occurred in third markets if German companies exported assembled cars from Central European production locations to markets other than the German home market.16

To summarize, the import and export patterns associated with assembly operations of German automobile companies in Central Europe suggest that production in this region is more likely to affect domestic production and, thus, labour markets than the assembly operations of German companies in other host countries with relatively low per-capita income. In contrast to Latin America and China, production locations in Central Europe allowed for an internationally competitive assembly of automobiles close to European core markets.

IV. Offshoring Production of Autoparts

Substitution effects at the level of assembled cars are not the only transmission mechanism through which the emergence of Central Europe as an important player in the automobile industry may have repercussions on German labour markets. Additional labour market effects can be expected to result from the offshoring of automobile parts production to Central Europe through vertical FDI by car assemblers and so-called follow sourcing by parts suppliers.17 This is even though Kleinert (2003) does not find strong support for the offshoring hypothesis in time-series data on German FDI. As noted by this author, the finding that it is not so much outward FDI by German companies but rather FDI by foreign

16Due to data constraints, it is not possible to assess the extent to which such exports replaced exports from Germany and, thus, affected domestic production of passenger cars.

17Follow sourcing results from the preference of car assemblers to use the same suppliers in various locations.

According to Kinkel (2004), there is strong pressure on parts suppliers to locate in the vicinity of their customers.

德国汽车工业质量标准

质量保证在技术和经济进步上决定着汽车制造及其配套工业的未来.必须从经济合理的观点去考虑由许多分过程组成的整个生产过程,以使质量、时间和成本达到最佳姿态。因此,VDA 提出了如下汽车工业质量指南: 在过程链中,用产品审核来反映内部/外部所生产产品的质量水平。 根据由产品审核了解到的有关质量水平的情况,可以对生产过程甚至是质量体系下结论。 产品审核得到的信息用于顾客和企业的质量持续改进过程(KVP )。 本标准的表达贴近实际,容易理解。 产品审核的策划者及进行产品审核的审核员可以本标准为操作指南. 本标准采纳了一些实例以完善对产品审核的论述。 德国汽车工业质量标准(VDA6) Quali ?ttsstandard der Deutschen Automobilindustrie(VDA6) VDA6 质量审核的 基本准则 Grundlagen f ür Qualit ?tsaudits 审核与认证 Auditierung und Zertifizierung VDA6 质量体系审核 第1部分 QM-Systemaudit VDA6 质量体系审核 第2部分 QM-Systemaudit 服务Dienstleistung VDA6 过程审核Proze ?audit 第3部分 VDA6 质量体系审核QM-Systemaudit 第4部分 生产设备Produktion VDA6 产品审核 第5部分 PRODUKTAUDIT VDA6 服务审核 第6部分 Dienstleistungsaudit

前言 1引言 2概念解释及产品审核的目的 2.1.概念解释 2。1.1质量审核(根据ISO8402:1994) 2。1。2产品(根据ISO8402:1994) 2。1。3产品审核 2.2目的 3 汽车制造厂及其供方的产品审核3.1 产品审核与其他审核方式及检验的区别3.2 产品审核流程 4 产品审核的筹备策划 4。1前提和职责 4.2审核大纲 4。3参考资料 4.4检验方法和检测器具 4.5审核员的资格 5产品审核提问表 5.1概述 5.2针对产品实体检验的提问 5.2.1研究所有资料 5.2。2随机抽样 6 产品审核的实施 6.1实施职责 6。2处理 6.3报告(纪要) 7 数据分析及缺陷原因调查 8 产品审核结果的评定 9 产品审核报告

德国工业标准

看看我这个单子里你需要哪个,给我个列 表。 国外标准\德国工业标准[DIN] (0 folders, 886 files, 452.57 MB, 452.57 MB in total.) CONE.pdf 2.54 MB DIN 2512.2513.2514.2519.2526.2559.pdf 112.19 KB DIN 2565~2569.pdf 153.43 KB DIN-A.PDF 1.80 MB DIN1.pdf 306.89 KB DIN10002.pdf 1.26 MB DIN10029.pdf 1.61 MB DIN1013.pdf 105.01 KB DIN1014.pdf 55.50 KB DIN10163.pdf 734.20 KB DIN1017.pdf 507.53 KB DIN1018.pdf 208.56 KB DIN1019.pdf 246.86 KB DIN1022.pdf 113.39 KB DIN1024.pdf 73.95 KB DIN1025.pdf 1.30 MB DIN1025B.pdf 1.17 MB DIN1026.pdf 232.76 KB DIN1026n.pdf 217.89 KB DIN1027.pdf 244.46 KB DIN1028.pdf 420.52 KB DIN1028B.pdf 730.30 KB DIN1029.pdf 440.03 KB DIN1029B.pdf 332.50 KB DIN103.pdf 725.27 KB DIN1142.pdf 70.87 KB DIN116.pdf 181.58 KB DIN1219.pdf 0.97 MB DIN125.pdf 816.72 KB DIN126.pdf 40.50 KB DIN127.pdf 226.93 KB DIN127B.pdf 171.95 KB DIN128.pdf 119.49 KB DIN1282.pdf 70.77 KB DIN1283.pdf 58.59 KB DIN13.pdf 83.41 KB DIN133.pdf 75.70 KB DIN1353.pdf 196.94 KB DIN137.pdf 201.57 KB DIN138.pdf 467.09 KB DIN13B.pdf 5.77 MB DIN13C.pdf 7.49 MB DIN14.pdf 422.23 KB DIN1410.pdf 151.47 KB DIN1433.pdf 299.97 KB DIN1434.pdf 293.25 KB DIN1435.pdf 313.79 KB DIN1435B.pdf 180.93 KB DIN1436.pdf 304.03 KB DIN1440.pdf 75.97 KB DIN1441.pdf 63.12 KB DIN1441B.pdf 52.18 KB DIN1444.pdf 346.87 KB DIN1445.pdf 174.52 KB DIN1448.pdf 138.78 KB DIN1471.pdf 250.79 KB DIN1473.pdf 86.21 KB DIN1476.pdf 306.71 KB DIN1478.pdf 154.80 KB DIN1479.pdf 107.71 KB DIN1481.pdf 373.50 KB DIN1498.pdf 212.96 KB DIN1499.pdf 282.28 KB

德国汽车及零部件工业的现状和特点.(DOC)

德国汽车及零部件工业的现状和特点[zt]

1、德国汽车工业现状: 德国汽车工业是德国国民经济的主要支柱产业,德国七分之一的就业岗位、四分之一的税收收入依赖于汽车工业和相关产业。2004年全年销售再创新高,达2277.66亿欧元,比上年增长了9.1%;国内汽车生产连续第七年超过500万辆大关,巩固了其全球第三大汽车生产国的地位;在巩固国内生产的同时,德国各大汽车厂家继续加紧实施全球化战略,加大在全球尤其是汽车市场增长较快的亚洲和东欧地区的投资,扩大海外生产规模。中国是德国汽车工业海外最重要的生产基地之一,大众和奥迪公司早已扎根中国,宝马和戴姆勒-克莱斯勒也纷纷在中国投资生产高档系列轿车。2003年宝马公司在中国的工厂正式投产,戴姆勒-克莱斯勒公司与中国合资生产高档轿车和商用车两个项目即将投产。目前中国生产的轿车中,德国大众汽车公司约占30%,居首位。 2004年全球汽车市场形势良好,但原材料价格飞涨,全年欧元持续走强,对德国汽车出口产生很大影响。德国汽车工业再次经受住了考验,出口再创新高,全年出口汽车392.4万辆,比上年增长了0.8%。其中,轿车出口366.65万辆,增长了0.3%;商用车出口25.75万辆,增长了8%。2004年德国汽车出口率为70.5%,比上年下降了0.7 个百分点,主要原因是国内需求增加。 海外市场对德国汽车工业日益重要。欧洲,特别是西欧,仍是德国汽车最主要的销售市场。德国汽车在欧洲汽车市场的占有率将近一半,柴油汽车表现尤为突出。在竞争激烈的高档车领域,德国汽车占十分之七,大众公司在欧洲仍稳居第一。 2、中德汽车配件市场状况: 德国汽配行业在2004年一如既往,发展态势良好。德汽车工业海外布局强大,汽车配置越来越高,汽车电子配置不断增加,这些都使德汽配行业大受其益。2004年汽配行业实现销售收入654亿欧元,比上年增长了10%,也达到新的历史水平。其中,国内销售381亿欧元,增长8%,出口273亿欧元,增长11%,均明显超过上年的水平。2004年德汽配出口占行业销售总额的41.8%,为历史最好。 2004年德国汽车生产企业的加工深度进一步降低,更多的加工和研发任务转移给了汽配企业。过去6年里,德国汽配工业的销售增长幅度均超过汽车生产厂商,但销售额主要集中于少数大型或跨国汽配企业,如博世、大陆、ZF、蒂森?克虏伯、西门子VDO、巴斯夫、及Hella等。 2004年德汽配行业销售增长了9%,达654亿欧元,取得了新的最好成绩。其中,国内市场销售约381亿欧元,增8%;出口273亿欧元,增11%,占整个销售额的42%,比上年增加了1个百分点;汽配行业从业人员32.93万人,占整个汽车工业从业人员的40%;其中新增2000人,基本上平衡了汽车生产企业2004年裁减的人数。 德汽配行业成功的基础是企业不断的技术创新,灵活并注重实施全球化战略。特别是全球化战略方面,德国汽配行业扎根市场、贴近用户,全球布局,充分利用各地有利资源,提高了自身的竞争能力。 自1996年以来,德国汽车工业几乎在全球所有主要地区的生产基地都增加了一倍以上。至2004年底,汽配行业在全球74个国家设立了1758个生产厂和许可生产厂。西欧作为德国汽车工业的重点区域,始终保持在34%的比例。而中东欧(如俄罗斯、乌克兰、保加利亚、罗马尼亚等)的

浅谈德国的汽车工业布局

学术探讨 浅谈德国的汽车工业布局 李广聪 (渤海大学外国语学院 辽宁 锦州 121000) 摘 要:大众汽车集团作为世界十大汽车集团之一,在进入中国汽车市场20多年的时间里经历了从兴盛、衰退、复兴过程。通过研究其在中国的品牌布局策略得失,我们发现它所具有的独特产品策略是其成功关键因素之一,本文就探讨分析其品牌策略,并为现今激烈的汽车市场指出它所具有的独特魅力。 关键词:大众汽车、品牌布局、汽车市场、营销 目前大众汽车集团(中国)已初步完成了对中国市场的战略布局,成为中国汽车市场上不可忽视的力量。而在2008年第一季度,德国大众汽车各项销售指标都名列榜首,大众在中国市场开始了“全面复兴”。所以,研究其发展进程,揭示其复兴的谜团对当今汽车行业有这至关重要的意义。 一、汽车品牌营销 品牌是汽车企业可持续发展的重要资源之一,在中国汽车市场发展过程中,品牌的概念正在受到越来越多的关注。品牌意味着市场定位;意味着企业和消费者之间的信任;意味着汽车产品的质量、性能、技术,并最终体现汽车企业的经营理念。 品牌策略是汽车企业市场营销活动的支柱和基础,直接影响和决定着其他营销策略,对于汽车市场营销的成败关系重大,在市场经济条件下每个汽车企业都应致力于汽车品牌的开发、汽车产品和服务质量的提高,以更好地满足汽车市场的需求,取得更好的经济效益。 世界汽车巨头无一例外的采取了品牌扩展和多品牌策略。所谓品牌扩展是指企业利用其成功品牌名称,推出改进或换代产品;多品牌策略一直是世界汽车市场采用的重要策略,指汽车生产企业同时生产经营多个汽车品牌,根据品牌的特性,进入不同的细分市场。 品牌定位要准确。品牌定位是指在消费者心中确立产品及品牌与众不同的有价值的地位的过程。“在某种意义上说,学习德国的经验,就意味着学习行业最先进的经验。”厦门金龙汽车座椅有限公司总经理方真群如是说。德国是世界上主要汽车品牌集中的国家。据德国一位参加展会的业内人士介绍,2005年德国前20位最有价值的品牌中,戴姆勒-克莱斯勒、奔驰、宝马、大众、奥迪等汽车品牌都榜上有名。德国的一家研究所从十几年前开始对汽车品牌进行专门评估。主要评估依据是市场占有率、产品形象和企业经营状况等。 作为全球第三大汽车生产国,德国各大汽车厂商无一不重视品牌价值。这使得德国汽车在竞争激烈的全球高档车市场中占据7/10的份额。 同样,德国的汽车零部件产业也有自己的品牌,如博世、大陆、ZF、蒂森?克虏伯、西门子VDO、巴斯夫等。在过去六年里,德国汽 配工业的销售增幅均超过整车工业,但市场主要被少数大型汽配企业占据。 二、德国大众(中国)多品牌布局成败分析 1.品牌产品开发重视其深度和宽度。德国大众进入中国市场表现了先驱者的勇气和睿智,并有着清晰的指导战略。与上汽合资,大众选择了专心制造,解决生产环节的大量问题,把市场的重任与风险留给了中方合作者。 这一时期,德国大众在中国投放的汽车品牌有:大众、奥迪。品牌产品由:桑塔纳、捷达和奥迪100组成。德国大众在中国轿车市场的份额高达90%以上,赢得了丰厚的市场回报和中国消费者的感情。 但在长达12年的时间里,德国大众并没有巩固自己市场领导者地位,通过引入更多的汽车品牌,像最早进入中国汽车市场一样,率先占领中国汽车的细分市场。而仅仅依靠三个品牌产品,在那个汽车市场竞争不饱和的大好环境下,玩弄南北大众之间的博弈。所采取的品牌扩展策略和多品牌策略,在深度和宽度都不够,在如此长的时间里,热衷于对老车型的技术改进。然而,核心技术知识产权,又被德国大众牢牢控制,中方并没有在“以市场换技术”的指导思想下,占到任何便宜。 2.分析市场需求,重视品牌布局。在竞争不饱和的前提下,德国大众采取的两家公司的品牌错位布局使得大众享受了在华十多年的繁华。 德国大众汽车中国市场份额的急剧滑坡,很大程度上要归咎于大众本身品牌策略的失误。首先在品牌布局上,一汽大众的奥迪、开迪、宝来、高尔夫、捷达都分别与上汽大众的帕萨特、途安、桑塔纳3000、POLO和桑塔纳交错重叠,在市场竞争中左右互搏。其次在引进新品牌缺乏市场调查。欧洲热销的高尔夫,到了中国水土不服,两门版的高尔,市场定位不准的开迪,这些车型的滞销,让德国大众更加难以抑制在中国汽车市场占有率的下滑。 随着中国汽车市场竞争格局变化,通用、丰田、福特等世界汽车工业巨头陆续进入中国,中国汽车升温并且“井喷”,新车倍增,价格日低,而德国大众汽车车型冲突与品牌分布矛盾也日益明显地暴露出来。之前的成功也令德国大众产生了市场错觉,对引进新产品、研发本土化、分析中国消费者需求等方面重视不足,这种市场错觉导致了大众近年来在市场策略上的进退失据。 客观的分析,随着汽车市场竞争的加剧,市场细分,单一品牌市场保有量会有所下降,但是如果自身内部的品牌协调好,采取宽度差异化战略、品牌深度战术,可以起到减缓下滑的作用。 3.品牌分布同企业形象联系起来,优化结构组合。在引入德国大众旗下另一个品牌———斯柯达后,并将其交由上海大众生产,我们可以看到一汽大众和上海大众的功能有了重新定位,即一汽大众未来将生产典雅型和精英型的车型,而上海大众的定位是经典型和时尚型的车型。也可理解为:一汽大众将生产高端车型,上海大众将生产大众化的车型。 德国汽车行业注重贴近市场,全球布局,利用各地有利资源,提高竞争力。自1996年以来,德国汽车厂商几乎在全球所有主要地区的产量都增加了一倍以上。至2004年底,该国汽配行业也在全球74个国家设立了1758个生产厂和许可生产厂。 德国汽车业在“老家”西欧始终保持着30%以上的占有率,其在俄罗斯、乌克兰、保加利亚、罗马尼亚等国家的市场比重也明显上升。同时,德国汽车厂商在北美地区设立了333个生产基地,汽配企业数量大幅增加。 德国汽车业近年还特别关注亚洲市场,中国是不少厂商海外最重要的生产基地之一,大众和奥迪公司早已在中国扎根,宝马和戴姆勒-克莱斯勒也在中国投资设厂。数据显示,目前中国生产的轿车中,德国大众汽车公司的车型占30%左右,居首位。对于大众、奥迪、斯柯达三个品牌,德国大众巧妙的采用了:“双塔”战略,即“奥迪+大众”形成一汽大众,“大众+斯柯达”构造上海大众。在未来的大众(中国)格局中,上海大众将形成:高尔、法比亚、波罗、朗逸、明锐、帕萨特领驭及速派的布局,产品价格主要覆盖6万~30万元之内。 一汽大众则日益成为中国汽车制造商中产品最完备的合资公司,除了现有的A级车新宝来、速腾、高尔夫(六代),豪华车奥迪系列,全新上市的帕萨特B6(迈腾),还有即将在一汽大众生产的帕萨特CC。由此,一汽大众将实现A级车到C级车的全线覆盖,实现15万~60万元的价格区间。 随着中国汽车市场竞争的加剧,如何保持自己的竞争优势是汽车制造企业的必思课程。通过德国大众(中国)的复兴之路,我们可以得出:第一,应该在全局意识指导下规划其品牌布局,品牌定位应该是互补而不是互斥。第二,品牌布局应该与市场细分相结合,适当的调整其产品线。第三,任何时间都应该具有一种居安思危的意识,准确把握市场发展的脉搏。 参考文献: [1] 菲利浦.科特勒:营销管理[M].上海人民出版社,2003.10[2] 刘志迎:市场营销十八讲[M].中国商业出版社,2004.5[3] 王宁.市场管理与营销[M].北京师范大学出版社,2012.6 ?335?

2021年[世界汽车工业发展状况和趋势分析5] 德国汽车工业发展状况

[世界汽车工业发展状况和趋势分析5] 德国汽车工业发展 状况 目录第一章世界汽车工业发展状况和趋势分析 5 一、世界汽车整车产业竞争格局 5 (一) 整车产品结构 5 (二)主要国家生产格局 6 (三)厂商生产格局 7 (四)主要国家消费格局 8 二、世界汽车工业发展特点 9 (一)汽车产业高度全球化 9 (二)市场成为决定汽车工业发展前景的关键因素 10 (三)世界汽车销售市场的重心逐渐东移 10 (四)生产经营集团化及跨国公司、寡头垄断格局已经形成 11 (五)生产能力与市场需求矛盾突出 11 (六)跨区域、跨国界的企业兼并与联合 11 三、世界汽车产业发展趋势12 (一)产品发展趋势 12 (二)产品更新周期越来越短 12 (三)大力采用通用底盘 12 (四)在全球范围内优化选购零部件来降低成本 13 (五)广泛采用新技术 13 (六)零部件向模块化供给方向发展 14 (七)生产方式向“柔性化”方向发展 14 四、结语 14 第二章中国轿车整车产业发展状况分析 15 一、中国轿车整车产业发展现状 15 二、中国轿车整车竞争格局 16 (一)上汽集团 17 (二)一汽集团 18 (三)东风集团 18 三、中国轿车市场发展前景 19 四、中国轿车整车行业利用外资分析 20 (一)跨国公司在中国轿车整车产业中的地位 20 (二)跨国公司的进入历程 21 (三)跨国公司进入中国的一般规律 24 五、结语 25 第三章中国加入WTO对汽车产业的影响 26 一、汽车产业与WTO的相关条款 26 (一)关税方面 26 (二)进口配额和进口许可证 26

(三)外商投资管理方面 26 (四)服务贸易方面 27 (五)加入WTO协议中没有承诺的保护措施 27 二、入世后的主要影响 27 (一)对整车制造厂商的影响 27 (二)对零部件业的影响 29 (三)对汽车服务贸易业的影响 31 (四)对外资开放的影响 32 三、中国汽车产业国际竞争力分析 33 (一)产业集中度和规模经济水平 33 (二)生产效率及生产经营成本 34 (三)研究与 ___ 34 四、结语 35 第四章汽车产业链及配套模式分析 36 一、汽车产业的产业链概述 36 (一)整车制造业 36 (二)汽车零部件制造业 37 (三)汽车相关工业 39 二、国外汽车生产配套模式现状及发展趋势分析 39 (一)几种典型配套模式介绍 39 (二)国外汽车产业配套模式的发展趋势 42 三、国内汽车产业配套模式现状分析(轿车) 44 (一)上汽配套模式 45 (二)一汽的配套模式45 (三)东风汽车公司的配套模式 46 四、结语 46 第五章国内外汽车零部件工业发展状况分析 48 一、世界汽车零部件工业现状及发展趋势 48 (一)世界汽车零部件工业发展现状 48 (二)世界汽车零部件工业发展趋势 49 二、我国汽车零部件工业的现状及发展趋势分析 52 (一)我国汽车零部件工业的现状 52 (二)国外汽车公司进入中国情况 57 (三)未来几年国内汽车零部件产业发展走势分析 60 三、结语 61 第六章天津 ___区及环渤海地区汽车零部件产业发展现状分析 62 一、天津 ___区汽车零部件产业发展现状分析 62 (一)天津 ___区汽车零部件产业总体状况 62 (二)天津 ___区汽车零部件产品配套能力分析 62 二、天津汽车

德国汽车工业 英文

Relocation, Offshoring and Labour Market Repercussions: The Case of the German Automobile Industry in Central Europe By Peter Nunnenkamp* Abstract: The paper raises the proposition that Central Europe’s integration into the international division of labour has added significantly to competitive pressure in the German automobile industry. Based on production and trade data, we trace two dimensions of competitive pressure: relocation of assembly operations and offshoring of automotive parts production. The knowledge-capital model of multinational enterprises provides the analytical basis for the discussion of labour market repercussions. Vertical foreign direct investment in Central Europe may have helped the relatively favourable employment and earnings record of the German automobile industry, compared to other manufacturing industries. Yet recent industrial disputes can be attributed, though not exclusively, to the emergence of Central Europe as an attractive location for assembly operations and autoparts production. Employment and wages diverged considerably within the German automobile industry. Relative to skilled workers, the labour market situation of less skilled workers deteriorated significantly. JEL codes: F14, F23, L62 Keywords: vertical FDI, trade in intermediates, relative wages, employment * The Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Kiel, Germany. E-mail address: peter.nunnenkamp@ifw-kiel.de. This paper is a substantially revised and updated version of Nunnenkamp (2005). Comments by Joergen Ulff-Moeller Nielsen and Konrad Pawlik from the Aarhus School of Business are gratefully acknowledged. The author also would like to thank the discussant, PD Dr. André Jungmittag, and the participants of the 69th Annual ARGE Meeting for critical comments and useful suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

加拿大中英文双语介绍

世界上福利最好的国家——加拿大 加拿大-全球最适宜居住的国家 据联合国发表的报告,加拿大在就业水平、人均国民生产总值、收入、教育及卫生水平等综合指标在全球160多个国家中名列第一。 优美的自然环境和安全先进的生活方式 加拿大位于北美洲的北半部,总面积997万平方公里,仅次于俄罗斯,是世界第二大国。人口2900多万,是世界上平均人口密度最低的国家之一,每3人占有一平方公里的土地。89%的土地没有永久性居民点。南部与美国为邻约5000公里,石油、矿产、木材、海产、水利资源十分丰富。加拿大四季分明,西面受太平洋季风的影响,四季宜人春季郁金香花争艳,夏季阳光明媚,秋季枫叶层林尽染,冬季万里雪飘,极具风情。 加拿大是由十个省和两个地区组成的联邦国家。民族构成一英裔、法裔、荷兰裔、德裔、波兰裔和华裔。官方语言为英语和法语。 加拿大有26个人口超过10万的市区和3个人口超过100万的城市。其中不少是北美洲最安全、最清洁、风光最美的市中心区。加拿大城市的严重犯罪率不到美国城市的一半。更为人称道的是多个不同种族的人们在一个国际性的环境中和睦相处。政府和工业界致力保持空气和食品的清洁,共同努力维护健康的环境。加拿大的城市都有高素质的歌剧院、乐团和舞蹈团、美术馆、博物馆以及公共图书馆。加拿大城市有国际著名的芭蕾舞团、歌剧团和交响乐团。同时亦经常邀请世界各国最优秀的艺术家到访演出。加拿大政府对艺术的人均补助位于世界前列。加拿大的城市融合了欧洲、亚洲、拉丁美洲和非洲的各种文化。例如,温哥华是众多的亚裔人聚居之地;多伦多融合了欧、亚及其他文化;魁北克则为北美洲添上一份英、法双语的欧洲风味。 加拿大的气候各地不一,往往令预计天气较冷的访客诧异。全国绝大多数人口聚居在离美国边境250公里以内的地区,而加拿大最南部的地区与美国加州北部处于同一纬度。因此,加拿大各大城市的气候多数与美国北部或北欧地区相似。加拿大的城镇提供舒适的生活设施,但是与其他国际性商业中心相比,生活费用确保持在很容易负担的水平上。 名列世界前茅的经济和科技发展水平 加拿大是西方七国之一,工业生产自动化、电气化和现代化水平在世界各国中处于领先地位。农业生产专业化、商品化和现代化的程度也很高,加拿大在电话、微波、卫星、光纤通讯等方面拥有世界先进水平,在航天、微电子工业和生物技术方面亦具有相当水平。加拿大的交通很方便,拥有铁路10万公里、公路73万公里、900 家航空公司和600个大型机场。 理想的投资之地 加拿大是个贸易强国。受过良好教育的劳动力以及合理的生产成本,加上政府在政策的支持,国际人士对加拿大的商业投资环境充满信心。 加拿大在七大工业国中经济增长强劲,通货膨胀率长期低于2%。生活标准指数名列第三位。许多未来的主导行业已经对加拿大经济作出了显著贡献。这些行业包括:通讯设备、激光产品、环保技术、生物技术、制药、航天和电脑软件等高科技工业。 许多国际企业正越来越多地以加拿大作为研究与发展的中心。加拿大是世界最富裕的市场。从1994年1月1日生效的《北美自由贸易协定》让加拿大的企业得到了无可比拟的便利。充裕的原料、廉价的能源、低廉的商业楼宇、先进高效的

德国汽车工业成汽车强国的七大战略特征

?德国汽车工业成汽车强国的七大战略特征 ?德国汽车工业发展的成就和战略特征,在整个欧洲最为突出和典型。从一定意义上讲,探讨德国汽车发展战略,就是探讨欧洲汽车发展战略。德国既是世界汽车的发源地之一,也是目前世界第四大汽车生产国。 根据欧洲汽车工业协会统计,2007年,德国汽车企业全球产量共1210万辆,占世界汽车总产量的16.9%。其销量占西欧汽车销售份额的47%。在汽车消费日益增加的新欧盟国家,德产车以超过44%的市场份额占主导地位。如果德国汽车业衰落了,欧洲汽车业在全球的优势地位也将丧失。因此,我认为,德国汽车的发展战略主导了欧洲的汽车发展战略,也代表了欧洲的汽车发展战略。面临这场全球性金融危机和经济衰退,德国汽车业的一举一动不仅影响着欧洲,也影响着世界。同时,危机也将考验德国汽车发展战略的正确性、适应性。下面我从七个方面归纳其战略特征。 [ 转自汽车连论坛 https://www.360docs.net/doc/671071904.html,/ ] 战略特征1 支柱产业地位突出

德国汽车工业为德国创造了74.4万个工作岗位;汽车工业实现的增加值约占德国国内生产总值的1/5。 美国是汽车轮子上的国家,德国则是制造汽车的国家。造世界一流的汽车几乎成为德国人的精神追求。汽车在给德国带来了巨大物质财富的同时,也成为德国科技实力的主要载体。精致一流的汽车成为德国的名片。截至2007年底的数字,可以反映出德国汽车工业在其国民经济中的重要地位。德国汽车工业为德国创造了74.4万个工作岗位,占德国工业岗位的1/7;德国国内1/4的税收来源于汽车工业;围绕着汽车开发、制造、销售和使用等环节,汽车工业实现的增加值约占德国国内生产总值的1/5;来自于汽车工业的科技创新投入,占德国所有工业科技总投入的1/3,并由此带动了德国其他领域的技术发展。这些数字彰显出,汽车工业是德国名副其实的支柱产业,它为德国创造了最多的就业、税收和技术创新成果。 战略特征2 技术领先战略突出 [ 转自汽车连论坛 https://www.360docs.net/doc/671071904.html,/ ]

德国汽车工业质量标准-VDA6.5产品审核标准

前言 质量保证在技术和经济进步上决定着汽车制造及其配套工业的未来。必须从经济合理的观点去考虑由许多分过程组成的整个生产过程,以使质量、时间和成本达到最佳姿态。因此,VDA提出了如下汽车工业质量指南: 在过程链中,用产品审核来反映内部/外部所生产产品的质量水平。 根据由产品审核了解到的有关质量水平的情况,可以对生产过程甚至是质量体系下结论。 产品审核得到的信息用于顾客和企业的质量持续改进过程(KVP)。 本标准的表达贴近实际,容易理解。 产品审核的策划者及进行产品审核的审核员可以本标准为操作指南。 本标准采纳了一些实例以完善对产品审核的论述。

目录前言 1引言 2概念解释及产品审核的目的 2.1.概念解释 2.1.1质量审核(根据ISO8402:1994) 2.1.2产品(根据ISO8402:1994) 2.1.3产品审核 2.2目的 3 汽车制造厂及其供方的产品审核 3.1 产品审核与其他审核方式及检验的区别 3.2 产品审核流程 4 产品审核的筹备策划 4.1前提和职责 4.2审核大纲 4.3参考资料 4.4检验方法和检测器具 4.5审核员的资格 5产品审核提问表 5.1概述 5.2针对产品实体检验的提问 5.2.1研究所有资料 5.2.2随机抽样 6 产品审核的实施 6.1实施职责 6.2处理 6.3报告(纪要) 7 数据分析及缺陷原因调查 8 产品审核结果的评定

9 产品审核报告 10 根据产品审核结果制订纠正措施 10.1概述 10.1.1针对主要缺陷的措施 10.1.2针对次要缺陷的措施 10.2纠正措施的监控 11 实例 11.1实例:换挡轴Müller+公司 11.2 实例:原材料(薄钢板)Thyssen钢铁股份公司11.3实例:激光和挤压缝焊接钢板Thyssen钢铁股份公司11.3.1 抽样 11.3.2 检验范围 11.3.3 工作流程 11.3.4 产品审核报告 11.3.5 缺陷处理方法 11.3.6 发货审核 11.3.7 责任 11.4 实例:轴瓦Kühnle,Kopp&kausch股份公司11.4.1 说明:SQFE(生产和采购的系统化质量评定) 11.4.2 SQFE方法的特征值 11.4.3轴瓦实例中的方法步骤 11.5 实例:气门德国TRW股份有限公司,发动机部件11.6实例:轮胎 Continental股份公司 11.6.1检验范围,检验频次 11.6.2技术规范,检验方法 11.6.3实施 11.6.3.1审核员 11.6.3.2目检 11.6.3.3用检测设备检验 11.6.4 记录存档 11.6.5评定 11.6.6表格 11.6.6.1目检 11.6.6.2均衡试验 11.7实例:整车福特股份公司 11.7.1 符合性检验 11.7.2 整车

500家德国汽车工业协会VDA零部件企业

德国VDA汽车零部件企业(Manufacturer Group III) More than 500 members supply parts and accessories. 1. ABC Umformtechnik GmbH & Co. KG 2. Abt Sportsline GmbH 3. ACTS GmbH & Co. KG 4. AFT Atlas Fahrzeugtechnik GmbH 5. AGC Glass Germany GmbH 6. Akkumulatorenfabrik Moll GmbH + Co. KG 7. Gebrüder Ahle GmbH & Co. KG 8. Manfred Albrecht GmbH 9. Alcan Singen GmbH 10. ALFMEIER Pr?zision AG Baugruppen und Systeml?sungen 11. ALLEVARD FEDERN GmbH 12. ALLGAIER WERKE GmbH 13. ALLIGATOR Ventilfabrik GmbH 14. Altran Holding Deutschland GmbH 15. AMK Automotive GmbH & Co. KG 16. Amphenol-Tuchel Electronics GmbH 17. Amtek Tekfor Holding GmbH 18. Antennentechnik ABB Bad Blankenburg GmbH 19. anvis Group anvis Deutschland GmbH 20. Apparatebau Kirchheim -Teck GmbH & Co. 21. Argillon GmbH 22. ArvinMeritor GmbH 23. Assmus Metallveredelung GmbH 24. ATERA GmbH 25. AURORA Konrad G. Schulz GmbH & Co. KG 26. AUTOLIV B.V. & Co. KG 27. Automobil und Kunststofftechnik AKTec GmbH 28. Automotive Lighting Reutlingen GmbH 29. Autoneum Germany GmbH 30. Autotest Iggingen GmbH 31. AVL Schrick GmbH 32. Axalta Coating Systems 33. baier & michels GmbH & Co. KG 34. BALO MOTORTEX GMBH 35. BASF Catalysts Germany GmbH 36. BASF Polyurethanes GmbH 37. Baumgarten automotive technics GmbH

国内外汽车零部件工业发展状况分析

国内外汽车零部件工业发展状况分析 一、世界汽车零部件工业现状及发展趋势 (一)世界汽车零部件工业发展现状 当前世界汽车零部件工业大体分为四种类型: (1)西欧:汽车零部件工业相当发达,超过汽车制造业而走在前面; (2)美国、加拿大:汽车零部件工业与汽车制造业力量基本相当,平起平坐; (3)日本、韩国:汽车零部件制造业相当强大,但仍受主机厂制约; (4)中国、俄罗斯:汽车零部件制造业基本上依附或从属于汽车制造业,没有相对独立地位。 2001年,世界上最大的50家汽车零部件企业中,美国有20家,日本12家,德国9家,法国5家,英国、瑞典、意大利、加拿大各有一家;50家最大的汽车零部件企业中至少有一半在某种程度上依赖汽车电子产品。 表17 2001年全球最大20家汽车零部件制造企业情况 名次公司名称国别销售总额 (百万美元) 主要产品 2001 2000 1 德尔福汽车系统Delphi Automotive Systems 美国24188 26480 转向系统、底盘、电动系统、引擎控 制、内饰件、电子零件 2 罗伯特-博世 Robert Bosch GmbH 德国18000 17800 车辆安全系统、喷油系统、刹车系统、 电动和电子系统 3 伟世通公司 Visteon Corp. 美国16945 18569 底盘、空调、电子零件、车身内饰、 燃油供给、引擎控制、仪表系统、传 动系统 4 日本电装美国国际公司 Denso Corp. 日本16250 16392 热能通风、电子零件、过滤器、燃油 管理系统 5 李尔公司 Lear Corp. 美国14625 14073 内饰件、座椅、仪表盘和门内饰塑料 件、车内地板和隔声系统电子线路分 布系统 6 江森公司 Johnson Controls Inc. 美国13620 12738 内饰件、座椅、电池、车门系统、照 明系统、电子零件、仪表盘 7 曼格纳国际公司Magna International Inc. 加拿大10500 10100 内饰件、外饰件、车身和底盘系统、 座椅、后视镜、发动机、变速箱 8 天合公司 TRW Inc. 美国9600 10200 转向系统、悬挂系统、刹车系统、发 动机零件、扣紧固件、乘客安全保护

VDA标准简介

一、概况汽车工业是一个典型的全球化产业,现在世界上大的整车厂都实行全球采购。中国进入 WTO 以后,外国的汽配企业一定会大批涌入,而同时也能使中国的汽配企业进入国际竞争的行列,关键看谁的质量好、价格优,谁就能生存。为此,中国的汽车配件生产企业必须要走出去,到全世界去找自己的市场生存支点。现在每家整车厂都有自己的采购标准,同时,也有国家规定的标准,如在德国,联邦政府对每年上路的汽车都有统一的标准,只有先达到了国家行政规定的标准,才能在这个基础和范围内突出自己品牌的特点。所以汽配企业也要先了解这些规定,才能进入这个国家和地区去给整车厂配套。VDA6.1 标准是德国汽车工业制定的一个统一的标准。只有达到了这个标准的企业和产品才能有资格进入德国汽配市场。由于德国在欧洲汽车业中的地位和欧盟的统一性,达到这个标准也就可以进入欧洲的市场了,这是一个准入证,是一张门票。有了这个准入证,才有资格凭借自己的质量、价格优势去争取整车厂的供货权。发布于 1991 年的 VDA 6.1 是德国汽车制造业的质量体系标准,它是由德国汽车制造业协会和其主要生产商与供应商发展出的汽车标准。 VDA 6.1 的主要内容乃是源源于 ISO 9000 质量管理体系标准。它分成管理以及产品与过程二个大类。它的要素主要有 ISO 9001 质量体系的模式和 ISO 9004-1 质量体系指南加上顾客特殊要求。 VDA 6.1 也取材部分 QS-9000 的条文和部分法国汽车工业质量标准(EAQF)。其中规定凡有设计功能的供应商,必须符合德国道路交通法的规定。VDA 6.1 的标准直接影响德国汽车工业的主要制造商与供应商,包括大众汽车、奥迪、奔驰、Porsche, Adam Opel 和 Ford-Were。大众汽车集团(包括大众、奥迪、Seat 和 Skoda)规定它的所有产品和零配件供应商必须通过 VDA 认证注册。VDA6 标准认证在我国已经开始。VDA 是德国汽车联合会的德文缩写,VDA6 标准是德国汽车行业用于质量审核的基本准则,这是德国汽车工业的主机厂对供方的要求。VDA6 标准同 QS9000 标准一样都是在ISO9001:1994 标准的基础上增加了本国汽车行业特殊要求后形成的。因同属大量生产的汽车工业质量体系要求范畴,故两者无大的区别,但在编写格式和细节方面也不尽相同。获得认证的条件一个按照 VDA6.1 要求有效运行的质量管理体系是以 ISO9001/ISO9002 及 ISO9004-1 为基础同时加上VDA 手册以及汽车待业相关的特殊要求.适用范围:VDA 中的要求主要适用于那些汽车部件的供诮商(包括直接供商和分供方),当然也推荐并适用于制造业中的其他方面。建立 VDA 的优点1、为汽车行业及其他制

德国汽车产业分析

德国汽车产业概述 德国汽车工业是德国国民经济的主要支柱产业,德国七分之一的就业岗位、四分之一的税收收入依赖于汽车工业和相关产业。 一、市场情况 2012年12月德国乘用车产销及出口概况。 二、汽车和汽车配件工业 德国是世界上汽车制造强国,奔驰、宝马老少咸知,大众、奥迪、保时捷有口皆碑。在全球中高档汽车市场上,德国汽车品牌占有重要地位,迈巴赫、宾利更成为身份高贵的象征。一说到德国汽车,人们首先想到的是安全、舒适、节能、环保、美观、耐用…。汽车工业之所以能以较多的优势领先于其他产业,长期保持德国第一产业地位,展现超群的实力和强劲的发展势头,其发展特点值得关注。首先,德国

汽车生产企业高度重视研发,努力提高核心竞争力。在最近10年间,德国汽车工业研发投入高达约2000亿欧元。德国工业领域28%的研发人员从事汽车的研发工作,而汽车工业九分之一的员工供职于研发部门。德国汽车工业平均每十天就有一项专利产生,每年获得的专利3650项,是名副其实的世界冠军。所有这些都确保了德国汽车工业在全球的技术领先优势,凸现了德国汽车工业在德国经济中的核心地位。 德国汽车工业研发工作的重点是提高汽车质量、改善安全性能、降低能耗。德国汽车工业正着力进行新一代混合动力发动机技术和替代燃料的研究,旨在提高发动机性能、减少二氧化碳等有害气体排放及噪音污染,适应环保、节能的大趋势和要求。同时不断推出新式车型开发和挤占市场。为实现这些目标,德国汽车公司不断加大投资力度,比如大众计划在2012-2016年投资327亿欧元开发新品,冀通过新技术至少降低30%的生产成本。大众将向在华合资企业注资140亿欧元。其次增加投入进一步巩固其全球主要汽车生产国的领先地位。第三,不断提供汽车电子技术含量。目前汽车电子技术含量在整车的比例约为40%。现在的高档汽车身上,电子和电器部分已占到汽车价值的一半。目前在德国境内运行的汽车中安装卫星定位导航系统已经比较普遍,新车中安装导航系统的比例迅速上升。根据欧盟要求,德国生产的汽车今后都要安装紧急呼救系统,一旦发生事故或故障,司机

德国工业化进程及其主要做法

德国工业化进程及主要作法 一、近代德国的工业化概况 德国资本主义工业的发展迟于英国约半个多世纪。由于封建割据和农奴制(见普鲁士农奴制改革)的长期统治,直到19世纪30~40年代,德国还是一个农业国,产业工人仅占全国人口总数的2.98%。1848年资产阶级革命后,机器大工业才逐步地确立起来。1871年德意志帝国建立以后,依靠对国内廉价劳动力的剥削和对国外军事侵略及战争赔款,实现了大工业的迅速发展。具体来讲,分为四个阶段。 第一阶段:19世纪30年代,德国纺织业促进了工业革命的兴起,1846年已建成初具规模的纺织厂约有313家,其中萨克森的开姆尼兹成为棉纺织业的中心。19世纪中期,为应对英国等发达国家在工业方面的冲击,德国制造业发展重点开始转移,从以纺织业为主的轻工业逐步转向以铁路建设为中心的重工业,其主要特点是以铁路建设带动其他工业发展,从而使德国在第一次工业革命中后来居上。 第二阶段:20世纪90年代中期,美国和日本在微电子技术、集成电路技术和信息技术等方面迅猛发展,德国仍然局限于机床、汽车、照相机等传统工业。为了缩小与日、美等国家在信息技术方面的差距,德国加大对计算机和信息技术的投入力度,实施快速赶超战略。1990—1994年,德国经济、科技、邮电三大部门对信息技术领域的投资年均增长825%,有效提升德国信息技术实力。早在16年前即1999年

年底,德国就有因特网用户1950万。1/4以上的人拥有个人电脑,1/10的人能够使用因特网。到2001年,德国的因特网及电子商务发展在欧洲遥遥领先。欧盟10个重点高科技地区中,有6个在德国; 第三阶段,为了应对东欧和亚洲国家廉价产品的挑战,德国再次调整发展策略,着手改进生产工艺,注重利用制造过程中的各种信息技术,提高资源使用率和保护环境。为此,德国投资4.5亿德国马克(约合3.2亿美元),实施为期五年的“生产2000”计划,其核心内容是“清洁制造、确保就业、提高竞争力”。该计划的实施大大提升了德国制造业的现代化水平。 第四阶段,从21世纪至今。德国是一个工业化高度发达而自然资源严重缺乏的国家,资源消耗量大,自身能源和资源不足问题日渐突出,制约其工业、经济向前发展。随着全球气候变暖加剧、极端天气及自然灾害频发,德国工业开始走上绿色发展之路,将重点放在新能源发展领域和可再生能源领域,主要包括有风能、生物质能、地热能和太阳能等。2013年,德国将“工业4.0”项目纳入了《高技术战略2020》的十大未来项目中,计划投入2亿欧元资金,支持工业领域新一代革命性技术的研发与创新。基于信息物理系统的智能化,开启人类步入以智能制造为主导的第四次工业革命。 二、德国的主要工业部门 (一)汽车行业

相关文档
最新文档