金融学外文翻译---金融体系的比较

合集下载

毕业论文(设计)外文文献翻译及原文

毕业论文(设计)外文文献翻译及原文

金融体制、融资约束与投资——来自OECD的实证分析R.SemenovDepartment of Economics,University of Nijmegen,Nijmegen(荷兰内梅亨大学,经济学院)这篇论文考查了OECD的11个国家中现金流量对企业投资的影响.我们发现不同国家之间投资对企业内部可获取资金的敏感性具有显著差异,并且银企之间具有明显的紧密关系的国家的敏感性比银企之间具有公平关系的国家的低.同时,我们发现融资约束与整体金融发展指标不存在关系.我们的结论与资本市场信息和激励问题对企业投资具有重要作用这种观点一致,并且紧密的银企关系会减少这些问题从而增加企业获取外部融资的渠道。

一、引言各个国家的企业在显著不同的金融体制下运行。

金融发展水平的差别(例如,相对GDP的信用额度和相对GDP的相应股票市场的资本化程度),在所有者和管理者关系、企业和债权人的模式中,企业控制的市场活动水平可以很好地被记录.在完美资本市场,对于具有正的净现值投资机会的企业将一直获得资金。

然而,经济理论表明市场摩擦,诸如信息不对称和激励问题会使获得外部资本更加昂贵,并且具有盈利投资机会的企业不一定能够获取所需资本.这表明融资要素,例如内部产生资金数量、新债务和权益的可得性,共同决定了企业的投资决策.现今已经有大量考查外部资金可得性对投资决策的影响的实证资料(可参考,例如Fazzari(1998)、 Hoshi(1991)、 Chapman(1996)、Samuel(1998)).大多数研究结果表明金融变量例如现金流量有助于解释企业的投资水平。

这项研究结果解释表明企业投资受限于外部资金的可得性。

很多模型强调运行正常的金融中介和金融市场有助于改善信息不对称和交易成本,减缓不对称问题,从而促使储蓄资金投着长期和高回报的项目,并且提高资源的有效配置(参看Levine(1997)的评论文章)。

因而我们预期用于更加发达的金融体制的国家的企业将更容易获得外部融资.几位学者已经指出建立企业和金融中介机构可进一步缓解金融市场摩擦。

金融学专业外文翻译---对简便银行的简单见解

金融学专业外文翻译---对简便银行的简单见解

中文3696字本科毕业论文外文翻译出处:Infosys Strategic Vision原文:Insights from Banking SimpleBy Ashok VemuriIntroduction“A simpler way of banking.We treat with you respect. No extraneous features. No hidden fees.” For the unini tiated, this is the mantra of BankSimple, a Brooklyn-based startup which has positioned itself as a consumer-friendly alternative to traditional banks. BankSimple pushes a message of user experience—sophisticated personal finance analytics, a single “do-it-all” card, superior customer service, and no overdraft fees.Though branchless and primarily online-based, BankSimple is also planning to provide some traditional customer service touches, including phone support and mail-in deposits. Interestingly, BankSimple will also likely not be a bank—at least not in the technical, FDIC sense of the word. Rather, BankSimple’s strategy is to be a front-end focused on the customer experience. The back-end core “bank” component will be FDIC-insured partner banks. Unfettered by years of IT investments and entrenched applications, BankSimple’s team has the freedom to build an innovative, user-friendly online interface, customer service program, and the associated mobile and social bells and whistles that more and more consumers are demanding. One way to look at it is as a wrapper insulating the consumer from the accounting, compliance, and technology challenges that many banks face.Like personal finance sites and Wesabe before it, BankSimple is looking to tap into a perceived gap between what major banks provide and what consumers want.A recent survey by ForeSee Results and Forbes found that consumers view online banking as more satisfying than banking done offline. Though good news for the industry as a whole, the survey also found that the five largest banks in the country scored the lowest in the study. Cheaper and more customer friendly, digital banking is the future—but many consumers are finding it is better done with credit unions, community banks, and (down-the-road) startups like BankSimple.As you read, significant investments are being made by banks to improve their online, mobile, and IVR customer-friendliness. Major banks are embracing these channels, and customer satisfaction will likely improve over time. Even so, startups like Bank- Simple should be viewed as a learning opportunity. Their ideas are disruptive and often highlight pain points that need to be addressed. BankSimple’s first two stated philosophies are a good place to start: “A simpler way of banking” and “We treat you with respect.”Ask the Right Questions to Achieve SimplicityBankSimple’s “simpler way of banking” tenet is primarily driven by its business model.A relatively small number financial products and services (bill pay, savings/checking account, loans, account transfers) will allow BankSimple to declutter its offerings.This minimalist approach is embodied in the first planned product—a single card providing checking, savings, rewards, and a line of credit. Obviously, major banks have a much different business model. Higher wallet share is necessary to grow revenue and increase market share. Product innovation and cross selling are two methods used to achieve this.With banks in the midst of a reputation crisis, customer service has taken on more importanceUnfortunately, cross selling efforts often congest and complicate the banking experience. Consumers can get lost in a maze of clicks, confusing products, and fine print. Simplicity and straightforward banking are not easy to implement. If they were, we wouldn’t be having this discussion. However, by asking a few important questions you can set your bank on a path to simplicity:l Where are the headaches? Where are you receiving the most customer service complaints and queries? How long does it take to complete basic activities (i.e., open an account or enroll in online banking)? Once these pain points are identified, process reengineering can be undertaken to improve speed and customer satisfaction.l Are your customers happy with their channel of choice? Certain customers prefer using online banking or mobile banking. Others prefer phone and branch banking. Can all of their needs be met through their channel of choice? Do predominantly mobile bankers have to make unnecessary trips to the bank branch? Availability of products and services through the channel of choice can be a powerful switching mechanism. The usability and simplicity of the online channel is another important consideration. How intuitive is your website? Can customers quickly find what they are looking for? Mapping customer activities while on the site, customer surveys (incentives help encourage participation), and focus groups are some techniques used to identify potential bottlenecks and pain points.l Are the benefits of your products and services clear and understandable? The burgeoning number of products banks offer can be a nightmare for many time and attention-strapped customers. A multitude of channels to navigate through often compounds the complexity. Side-by-side comparisons, easy to understand terms and conditions, and easy access can add a dash of simple to any bank.l Do you really know your customers? Intelligent and effective use of analytics can unlock what products and services are applicable to a given customer. The rise of unstructured analytics allows financial institutions to sift through data outside of the database—blogs, social media sites, emails, wikis, and even audio and video. From unstructured data, banks can derive more complete profiles of their customers. Patterns and preferences can be pinpointed—improving the efficacy of marketing and customer service campaigns.Online Banking: Increasing Adoption, Access, and UsageThe report recommends that banks adopt a more aggressive strategy that will givefinancial institutions a competitive advantage with Internet-savvy and younger consumers who will fuel banks’ profits in the decade ahead. The report surveyed the top 30 U.S. full-service retail bank Web sites and identifies the appropriate level of adoption of four key initiatives that the report recommends. The report also details the current level of Internet access, online banking adoption, and customer satisfaction with the online banking experience. Highlights of this report include: . Internet access now stands at 74 percent and limits the universe of customers who can sign up for onli ne banking. It’s only a matter of time before the younger cohorts who have integrated the Internet into their day-to-day life become an important customer segment and drive online banking adoption higher. Banks have been investing heavily in the online experience and have dramatically increased their online customer satisfaction scores over the past 10 years. Banks now outperform online retailers, once considered the gold standard for quality online experiences.. Banks are executing a number of initiatives that are increasing online banking adoption, access, usage, and relationship depth. Continuing to promote online banking capabilities at every opportunity is essential for success, and, when successful, online banking creates additional “impressions” that enhance brand and cross selling effectiveness.. Mobile banking is an essential ingredient to an online banking strategy and broadens access, increases usage, and provides a platform for innovative products and services in the future. Banks need to expand the capability of their online banking solutions to increase usage and deepen their relationships with customers. In addition to offering mobile banking, banks need to expand their EBPP capabilities with eBills, provide easy to use “lite” personal financial management solutions, and add consumer check image capture to capabilities. “Online banking has continued to gain adoption over the past decade and will eventually outrank branch location in the list of decision criteria when a consumer chooses a bank,” said Bob Landry, vice president of Mercator Advisory Group’s Banking Advisory Service. “While the promise is clear, banks must continue to promote online banking to increase adoption, expand access with mobile banking, and increase usage by adding new capabilities,” Landry added. “Those banks that continue to execute an aggressive online banking strategy will not only reduce costs, they will also be the choice of the next generation of consumers who have integrated the Internet into their lifestyle. They will naturally gravitate to the banks that meet them where they work andMost bank customers (36 percent) prefer to do their banking online compared to any other method, according to a new ABA survey. Last year, 25 percent of customers favored online banking. The annual survey of more than 1,000 consumers was conducted for ABA by Ipsos-Public Affairs, an independent market research firm, on Aug. 14-15, 2010. "Clearly, online banking has fully penetrated the market," says Nessa Feddis, ABA vice president, senior counsel and retail banking expert. "Online banking is the future of banking as more Generation Y-ers enter the marketplace. This means the industry will need to continue investing in technology that supports online banking because consumers see it as quick, convenient, accurate and safe." Survey results showed that the popularity of online banking was not exclusive to the youngest consumers: It was the preferred banking method for all bank customers under the ageof 55. Consumers over 55 still prefer to visit their local branch (33 percent). Online banking for this age group was the second favorite way to conduct banking transactions (20 percent). Among all consumers, the preference for online banking was followed by visiting branches (25 percent), and using ATMs (15 percent). The use of mobile banking (cell phones, PDAs, etc.) was preferred by three percent of consumers, primarily among 18 to 34 year olds. The popularity of ATMs was down in all age groups. Consumers who cited online banking as their favorite banking method were more likely to be under 55 years of age, have an income over $75,000, and live in the Western part of the United States. For the survey, a nationally representative sample of 1,010 randomly-selected adults aged 18 and over residing in the United States was interviewed by telephone via Ipsos' U.S. Telephone Express omnibus. Embrace Social Media to Convey RespectBankSimple promises its cust omers “no more getting passed around the call center.” In other words, “we treat you with respect” boils down to one thing: customer service. From the branch, to the customer service representative, to the IVR, to email and chat, customer service has evolved considerably over the last 50 years. With the banking industry in the midst of a reputation crisis, customer service has taken on even more importance.Traditionally, customer service has been a numbers game. More customer service representatives means more problems solved and questions answered. However, with the growth of social media, banks find themselves with an opportunity to deliver improved customer service with a non-linear cost structure. Online forums provide customers an opportunity to share frustrations, find answers to questions, and help one another out. Twitter and Facebook-based customer service representatives can answer multiple questions at once. Social media can be the catalyst for a customer service revolution if banks approach it with the right mindset.Archaic systems, a lack of integration, and molasses-like processes present a challenge to even the most agile of large banks. As customers become increasingly sophisticated and demanding, these weaknesses are amplified. BankSimple and other digital finance entities should be viewed as a source of inspiration and a guide for innovation and improvement. The future of banking is a blend of simplicity, customer service, digital savvy and product and service diversity. Banking “simple” is just one stone on the path to Bank 2.0.ConvenienceIt’s probably safe to say that most people choose their bank or savings and loan on the basis of location,picking one that’s closest to their home or job.Before you do that,however,drop into the branch you are considering to see how it handles its customer traffic during the peak lunch-hour rush,particularly on Fridays. Is there an express line for customers with simple deposits or withdrawals?Is there a single line that move the people most efficiently to the next available teller?Are there enough tellers?Are there 24-hour automated teller machines?If you work in the city and live in the suburbans,will you be able to do your banking in either place?the answer is obviously.译文:对简便银行的简单见解一、引言本文探讨了简便银行的一些认识和简单的介绍了它的一些功能。

比较中美金融体系的异同

比较中美金融体系的异同

比较中美金融体系的异同第一篇:比较中美金融体系的异同比较中美金融体系的异同中美金融体系的相同点:1金融体系都是由金融市场、银行和外部公司治理及其在金融资源配置中所形成的相互关系和制度特征的总称。

2中美金融体系都包括以金融资产的交易、金融机构的构成和金融活动的监管为基础的多项内容。

中美金融体系的不同:第一,中国金融和美国处在不同的发展阶段。

美国出于金融市场的高度发展阶段,具体表现为市场规模大、金融工具多、产品链条长、资金能量强,这种“高度发展”在一定程度发展到“过度”,不但脱离了实体经济,而且会对实体经济产生负面作用。

而中国处于金融市场发展的初步阶段,具体表现为市场规模小、结构不合理、金融工具少、主体实力差,这种“初步”难以满足实体经济发展的需要,甚至在一定程度上制约了经济的发展,如多年存在的企业融资难、投资渠道狭窄等第二,中国金融和美国的运行机制不同。

美国金融市场化程度极高,华尔街具有超级话语权,具体表现为金融机构的趋利化、金融活动的自由化和金融业务的杠杆化,虽然这些特征目前在一定程度上面临下降和逆转,华尔街的话语权也在下降通道之中,但其高度市场化的根本特征不会改变。

反观中国,中国的金融市场化程度低,行政管制较强,金融压抑较为明显,具体表现在为,金融机构活力不足,例如金融创新严格审批、金融业务较为单一、金融服务能力较弱,等等。

当然,中国金融市场化程度低既有历史和客观原因,也有体制原因,我们需要的是正视这样的现实。

第三,开放程度的比较中国金融市场相对封闭,表现在难以有效运用全球资源,缺乏全球定价权和影响力,金融机构尚未完全参与国际竞争,这和中国经济的开放程度不想符合。

但是,美国的金融市场是完全开放,它是世界上最大的全球市场,表现在其金融机构全球发展、金融体系运用全球资源、金融市场有全球定价权和影响力。

总而言之,从整体角度讲,中国的金融市场还是发展不健全,政府对于银行的管制程度较高,各银行之间的竞争力度较小,整个金融市场的开放程度也较低。

美英日韩等国金融体系比较

美英日韩等国金融体系比较

一、美国金融体系概要(一)体系框架美国金融制度虽然形成时间不算早,要比英国晚,甚至在某种程度上说是仿效英国组建的。

但作为后来居上者,目前已是世界上金融体制最发达的国家。

美国的中央银行是联邦储备体系。

该体系由五大部分组成:联邦储备委员会、联邦储备银行、联邦公开市场委员会、四个顾问咨询委员会和会员银行。

其中,联储委员会是联邦储备体系的最高决策机构,是实际上的央行总行;联储银行是按经济区域设置的,是央行的执行机构,是实际上的央行分行;联储公开市场委员会是联储体系中专门负责制定执行公开市场业务的决策机构;会员银行是在联邦注册的国民银行和自愿加入的州立银行;四个顾问委员会是:联邦顾问委员会、学术交流顾问委员会、消费者顾问委员会和其他金融机构顾问委员会。

商业银行是美国金融体制中的主体,十分庞大。

但基本上可分为国民银行和州立银行两大类。

一般前者规模都很大,资本雄厚,后者规模不太大。

目前美国大约有5000家国民银行和13000多家州立银行。

商业银行的组织形式有四种:单一制、分支行制、连锁银行制和银行持股公司制,其中,持股公司制是发展最快的一种形式。

除商业银行以外,美国还有大量的为私人和为企业服务的金融机构,如:储蓄贷款协会、互助储蓄银行、信用联合社、人寿保险公司、销售金融公司、商业金融公司、投资银行、养老基金会、货币市场互助基金、信托公司、财务公司、财产保险公司等。

它们实际上属于非银行金融机构。

此外,美国政府也建有永久性的两类政府专业信贷机构:向住宅购买者提供信贷的机构、向农民和小企业提供信贷的机构。

美国的金融监管是多元化的。

负责实施监管的机构具有自上而下、相互配合的特点。

联储委员会是最主要和最权威的金融监管部门。

此外,财政部的货币监理官负责国民银行的注册并对其进行监管;联储体系负责对州立会员银行和银行持股公司的监管;存款保险公司负责对参加存款保险的所有银行的监管;证券交易委员会负责对证券交易的监管;联邦住宅贷款银行委员会负责对住宅贷款系统的各类机构及业务的监管;农业信贷管理署负责对农民贷款系统的监管;各州监理官负责对州立银行的监管。

中美金融体系差异

中美金融体系差异

• 现在的联邦储备银行系统包括联邦储备总裁委员 会;联邦公开市场委员会;12家区域性联邦储备 银行以及数千家私营的会员银行。联邦储备总裁 委员会是联邦储备银行系统的最高权力机构,它 由7名委员组成、负责决定全国货币政策,并对联 邦储备银行各区域性分行、会员银行和商业银行 的活动及业务有广泛的监督和管理职责。 联邦公开市场委员会是联邦储备系统用以执行货 币政策的主要机构,由联邦储备总裁委员会7名委 员和5名区域联邦储备银行的行长(其中必须包括 纽约联邦储备银行行长,其余各分行轮流参加)。 区域性联邦储备银行是按照1913年国会通过的联 邦储备法,在全国划分12个储备区,每区设立一 个联邦储备银行分行。
以完成金融体系解决不确定性风险 功能的方式不同为标准。
• 莱布泽斯基把金融体系分为两种基本形式: 银行导向体系和市场导向体系。他研究不 同金融体系对工业发展的作用,把金融体 系看作是对承受和分配风险的安排。
以完成金融体系解决激励机制功能 的方式不同为标准
• 珀林用“退场/发言”来形容两种体系。在 退场体系中,证券持有者靠出售他们的有 价证券来施加影响;在发言控制体系中, 银行与企业联系紧密,银行提供大量长期 贷款,金融资产缺乏高度发展的二级市场。
美国金融体系
• 美国金融体系主要由三部分组成,即联邦 储备银行系统,商业银行系统和非银行金 融机构,由美国联邦储备银行主导。
美国联邦储备银行系统
• 美国联邦储备银行系统起中央银行作用。 具有发行货币、代理国库及对私人银行进 行管理监督职能,更为重要的是为美国政 府制订和执行金融货币政策。联邦储备系 统可以通过它所制订的政策直接影响货币 的供应和信贷的增长,从而影响宏观经济 的各个方面。
美国商业银行
• 美国商业银行在美国金融体系中占有主要 位置,1980年,美国共有商业银行15082 家,总资产为21147亿美元,占金融界资产 总额的30%左右。商业银行以存款和贷款 为主,70年代以来各主要商业银行为扩大 业务经营范围,增强生存能力,积极开展 存贷款以外的业务。由于1933年制定的格 拉斯—斯蒂格尔法禁止商业银行从事投资 业务,也不能经营证券发行和买卖,故许 多商业银行都设立信托部,参与证券经营

国际金融体系和我国银行体系

国际金融体系和我国银行体系

Page 9
国际间金融事务的协调与管理
各国实行的金融货币政策, 各国实行的金融货币政策,会对相互 交往的国家乃至整个世界经济产生影响, 交往的国家乃至整个世界经济产生影响, 因此如何协调各国与国际金融活动有关的 金融货币政策, 金融货币政策,通过国际金融机构制定若 干为各成员国所认同与遵守的规则、 干为各成员国所认同与遵守的规则、惯例 和制度, 和制度,也构成了国际金融体系的重要内 容。
Page 7
汇率制度的安排
由于汇率变动可直接地影响到各国之间经济 利益的再分配,因此,形成一种较为稳定的、 利益的再分配,因此,形成一种较为稳定的、为 各国共同遵守的国际间汇率安排, 各国共同遵守的国际间汇率安排,成为国际金融 体系所要解决的核心问题。 体系所要解决的核心问题。一国货币与其他货币 之间的汇率如何决定与维持, 之间的汇率如何决定与维持,一国货币能否成为 自由兑换货币,是采取固定汇率制度, 自由兑换货币,是采取固定汇率制度,还是采取 浮动汇率制度,或是采取其他汇率制度,等等, 浮动汇率制度,或是采取其他汇率制度,等等, 都是国际金融体系的主要内容。 都是国际金融体系的主要内容。
国际金融体系和我国银行体系
国际金融体系
国际金融体系(The 国际金融体系(The international financial 是指调节各国货币在国际支付、结算、 system) 是指调节各国货币在国际支付、结算、汇兑与转移 等方面所确定的规则、惯例、政策、 等方面所确定的规则、惯例、政策、机制和组织机构安排的 总称。国际金融体系是国际货币关系的集中反映, 总称。国际金融体系是国际货币关系的集中反映,它构成了 国际金融活动的总体框架。在市场经济体制下, 国际金融活动的总体框架。在市场经济体制下,各国之间的 货币金融交往,都要受到国际金融体系的约束。 货币金融交往,都要受到国际金融体系的约束。

国内外金融学的区别

国内外金融学的区别

国内外金融学的区别比较国内和国外对经济学科内的领域设置,需要特别澄清什么是金融学的问题。

我发现国内和国外对金融学(finance)这一领域的理解有很大的不同。

一个国内学生说他是学金融的,到了国外会发现他学的在那里不被称为金融。

相反,在国外是学的金融,在国内又可能不叫金融。

为什么会这样呢?这需要仔细地分析。

首先,国内所说的金融是指两部分内容。

第一部分指的是货币银行学(money and banking)。

它在计划经济时期就有,是当时的金融学的主要内容。

人民银行说我们是搞金融的,意思是搞货币银行。

第二部分指的是国际金融(international finance),研究的是国际收支、汇率等问题。

改革开放后,凡是以“国际”打头的专业招生分数都非常高的,更不要说加上金融二字了。

这两部分合起来是国内所指的金融。

为了避免混乱,我们且称之为“宏观金融”。

有趣的是,这两部分在国外都不叫做finance(金融)。

而国外称为finance的包括以下两部分内容。

第一部分是corporate finance,即公司金融。

在计划经济下它被称为公司财务。

一说公司财务,人们就会把它跟会计联在一起,似乎只是做做表格。

之所以应把corporate finance 译成公司金融而不译成公司财务,就是因为它的实际内容远远超出财务,还包括两方面。

一是公司融资,包括股权/债权结构、收购合并等,这在计划经济下是没有的;二是公司治理问题,如组织结构和激励机制等问题。

第二部分是资产定价(asset pricing),它是对证券市场里不同金融工具和其衍生物价格的研究。

这两部分合起来是国外所指的finance,即金融。

为了避免混乱,我们且称之为“微观金融”。

根据这一分析,我们便清楚了。

国内学生说自己是金融专业的,他们指的是宏观金融,但是按国外的说法,这一部分不叫finance(金融),而是属于宏观经济学、货币经济学和国际经济学这些领域。

国外说的finance(金融),一定指的是微观金融。

金融学融资融券中英文对照外文翻译文献

金融学融资融券中英文对照外文翻译文献

中英文对照翻译Margin Trading Bans in Experimental Asset MarketsAbstractIn financial markets, professional traders leverage their trades because it allows to trade larger positions with less margin. Violating margin requirements, however, triggers a margin call and open positions are automatically covered until requirements are met again. What impact does margin trading have on the price process and on liquidity in financial asset markets? Since empirical evidence is mixed, we consider this question using experimental asset markets. Starting from an empirically relevant situation where margin purchasing and short selling is permitted, we ban margin purchases and/or short sales using a 2x2 factorial design to a allow for a comparative static analysis. Our results indicate that a ban on margin purchases fosters efficient pricing by narrowing price deviations from fundamental value accompanied with lower volatility and a smaller bid-ask-spread. A ban on short sales, however, tends to distort efficient pricing by widening price deviations accompanied with higher volatility and a large spread.Keywords: margin trading, Asset Market, Price Bubble, Experimental Finance1.IntroductionHowever, regulators can only have a positive impact on the life-cycle of a bubble, if they know how institutional changes affect prices in financial markets. Note that regulation is a double-edged sword since decision errors may lead from bad to worse. Given the systemic risk posed by speculative bubbles and their long history, it may be surprising how little attention bubbles have received in the literature and how little understood they are. This ignorance is partly due to the complex psychological nature of speculative bubbles but also due to the fact that the conventional financial economic theory has ignored the existence of bubbles for a long-time. But even if theories on bubble cycles have empirical relevance, it is clear that the issues surrounding the formation and the bursting of bubbles cannot be analyzed with pencil and paper. Conclusions on bubble cycles must be backed with quantitative data analysis. Given the limited number of observed empirical market crashes and their non-recurring nature, an experimental analysis of bubble formation involving controlled and replicable laboratory conditions seems to be a promising way to proceed.The paper is organized as follows. Section II reviews the related literature, Section 0 presents the details of the experimental design and section IV reports the data analysis. In section V, we summarize our findings and provide concluding remarks.2. Leverage in asset marketsDo margin requirements have any effects on market prices? Fisher (1933) and also Snyder (1930) mentioned the importance of margin debt in generating price bubbles when analyzing the Great Crash of 1929. The ability to leverage purchases lead to a higher demand, ending up in inflated prices. The subsequently appreciated collateral allowed to leverage purchases even more. This upward price spiral was fueled by an expansion of debt. From the end of 1924, brokers’loans rose four and one-half times (by $6.5 billion) and in the final phase broker’s borrowings rose at more than 100% a year until the bubble crashed. Then, after the peak of the bubble, a debt spiral was initiated. Investors lost trust and started to sell assets. Excess supply deflated prices resulting in a depreciation of collateral. Triggered margin calls lead to forced asset sales pushing supply even further. An increase in defaults on debt, and short sales exacerbated supply and finally assets were being sold at fire sale prices. It only took 6 weeks to extinguish half of the total of brokers’credit. Finally, in 1934, the U.S. Congress established federal margin authority to prevent unjustifiable increases or decreases in stock demand since margin requirements can prevent dramatic price fluctuations by limiting leveraged trades on both sides of the stock market: extremely optimistic margin purchasers and extremely pessimistic short sellers.Recent experimental evidence suggests short sale constraints to increase prices. Ackert et al. (2006)and Haruvy and Noussair (2006) find prices to deflate–even below fundamental value in the latter study –while King, Smith, Williams, and Van Boening (1993) find no effect. In a setting with information asymmetries, Fellner and Theissen (2006) find higher prices with short sale constraints but not depending on the divergence of opinion as predicted by Miller (1977). In a setting with smart money traders, Bhojraj, Bloomfield, and Tayler (2009) report short selling to exacerbate overpricing, even though it reduces equilibrium price levels. Hauser and Huber (2012) find short selling constraints with two dependent assets to distort price levels. Our design deviates from the previous studies in several but one important way: We use a more empirically relevant facility in that traders have to provide collateral facing the threat of margin calls.3. Implementing Margin Purchasing and Short SellingWe conducted four computerized treatments utilizing a 2x2 factorial design as displayed in Table II. Starting from an empirically relevant situation where margin purchases Traders execute margin purchases when they purchase shares by using loan, collateralized with shareholdings evaluated at the current market value.11 In this case, traders make a bull market bet, i.e. they borrow cash to buy shares, wait for the price to rise and sell them with a profit. However, a decline in prices depreciates collateral while keeping loan constant. When prices fall below a certain threshold, such that the loan exceeds the value of the shareholdings (i.e. debt > equity), a margin call is triggered. Immediately, i) the trader’s buttons are disabled, ii) outstanding orders are cancelled, and iii) the computer starts selling shares at the current market price until margin requirements are met again or untilall shares have been sold.12 Traders execute short sales when they sell shares without holding them in their inventory, collateralized with sufficient cash at hand.13 In this case, traders make a bear market bet, i.e. they borrow shares to sell them in the market, wait for the price to decline, buy them back with a profit and return them. Note that the amount of debt equals the total amount the trader has to pay to buy back the outstanding shares. Thus, an increase in prices increases debt and reduces collateral (cash minus value of outstanding shares), simultaneously. When prices exceed a certain threshold, such that the amount to buy back outstanding shares exceeds collateral (i.e. debt > equity), a margin call is triggered. Immediately, i)the trader’s buttons are disabled, ii) outstanding orders are cancelled, and iii) the computer starts buying shares at the current market price until margin requirements are met again or until all short positions have been covered. Note that short sellers have to pay dividends for their short positions at the end of each period.14 After period 15, both long and short positions are worthless.15 In any case, a margin callcan lead to bankruptcy. However, the consequences of a margin call hold even during bankruptcy, i.e. outstanding positions continuously being closed although subjects are bankrupt. This is different to any other asset market experiment considering leverage4. Margin traders tend to make less money than othersBy leveraging purchases and sales, traders take more risks to be able to make more money. But do margin traders make more money at all? To evaluate this question, we classify traders into types, i.e. margin traders, who trade on margin at least once, and others. Table X shows the average end- of round-earnings within types for each treatment along with the number of subjects. The spearman rank correlation between type and end of round earnings is negative in both rounds and in all three treatments. The coefficient is significantly different from zero only in MP|NoSS and NoMP|SS when subjects are once experienced . Subjects, who executed both margin purchases and short sales in MP|SS earned less than subjects who refrained from trading on margin. This is significant only for inexperienced subjects . One final note on the distribution of earnings. Comparing the treatments by evaluating the dispersion of earnings using the coefficient of variation , we find that the average CV in the NoMP|NoSS is lower than any other treatment Although not statistically significant, the results indicate that it is less risky to participate in markets with margin bans than in the markets where margintrading is permitted.5. ConclusionIn an attempt to halt the decline in asset values, recent regulatory measures temporarily banned short sales in financial markets. To assess the impact of banning leveraged trading on market mispricing is a complicated task when being reliant on data from real world exchanges only. it is unclear if possible price increases following a ban on short sales would come from new long positions or from covered short positions, and the announcement of such measures affects an uncontrolled reaction of the market. Owed to the uncontrolled uncertainties in the real world, asset mispricing can be measured only with weak confidence.In comparison to other experimental studies where limits to margin debt and short sales are rare, our design involves margin requirements comparable to the real world. Highly levered investors face margin calls that lead to forced liquidation of positions, affecting a reinforcement of the swings of the market. We have studied the impact of leverage on individual portfolio decisions to find an increase in risk taking characterized by higher concentrations of risky assets eventually resulting in individual bankruptcies. Thus, our experimental results are in line with theories of margin trading by Irvine Fischer (1933) and by recent heterogeneous agents models (Geanakoplos 2009) which conjecture such effects on asset pricing and portfolio decisions. As in any laboratory experiment, the results are restricted to the chosen parameters. The baselineSmith et al. (1988) asset market design has been challenged in recent studies (e.g. Kirchler et al. 2011), arguing that some subjects are confused about the declining fundamental value and believe that prices keep a similar level in the course of time. So it would also be interesting to investigate the effects of bans Jena Economic Research Papers 2012 - 05826 of margin purchases and short sales, to see if our treatment effects can be repeated in an environment with non-decreasing fundamental values. However, recent experiments by Hauser and Huber (2012) show similar effects using multiple asset markets with a complexsystem of fundamental values but without margin calls. It would also be interesting to see how margin requirements change performance in multiple sset markets. We leave these open questions to future research.ReferencesAbreu, D., and M.K. Brunnermeier, 2003, Bubbles and crashes, Econometrica 71, 173–204.Ackert, L., N. Charupat, B. Church and R. Deaves, 2006, Margin, Short Selling, and Lotteries in Experimental Asset Markets, Southern Economic Journal 73, 419–436. Adrangi, B. and A. Chatrath, 1999, Margin Requirements and Futures Activity: Evidence from the Soybean and Corn Markets, Journal of Futures Markets, 19, 433-455. Alexander, G.J, and M.A Peterson, 2008, The effect of price tests on trader behavior and market quality: An analysis of Reg SHO, Journal of Financial Markets 11, 84–111.Bai, Y., E.C Chang, and J. Wang, 2006, Asset prices under short-sale constraints, Mimeo. Beber, A., and M. Pagano, 2010, Short-Selling Bans around the World: Evidence from the 2007-09 Crisis, Tinbergen Institute Discussion Papers TI 10-106 / DSF 1.Bernardo, A. and I. Welch, 2002, Financial market runs, NBER Working Papers 9251, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.Bhojraj, S., R.J Bloomfield, and W.B Tayler, 2009, Margin trading, overpricing, and synchronization risk, Review of Financial Studies 22, 2059–2085.Blau, B. M., B. F. Van Ness, R. A. Van Ness, 2009, Short Selling and the Weekend Effect for NYSE Securities, Financial Management 38 (No. 3). 603-630Boehmer, E., Z.R Huszar, and B.D Jordan, 2010, The good news in short interest, Journal of Financial Economic 96, 80–97.Boehme, R.D, B.R Danielsen, and S.M Sorescu, 2006, Short-sale constraints, differences of opinion, and overvaluation, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41, 455–487.融资融券禁令在实验资产市场摘要在金融市场,因为专业的交易者杠杆交易允许以较少的保证金进行更大的交易。

  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

Comparative Financial SystemsFranklin Allen Wharton SchoolUniversity of PennsylvaniaPhiladelphia, PA 19104allenf@Douglas GaleEconomics DepartmentNew York UniversityNew York, NY 10003Douglas.Gale@April 20011 What is a Financial System?The purpose of a financial system is to cha nnel funds from agents with surpluses to agents with deficits. In the traditional literature there have been two approaches to analyzing this process. The first is to consider how agents interact through financial markets. The second looks at the operation of financial intermediaries such as banks and insurance companies. Fifty years ago, the financial system could be neatly bifurcated in this way. Rich house-holds and large firms used the equity and bond markets,while less wealthy house-holds and medium and small firms used banks, insurance companies and other financial institutions. Table 1, for example, shows the ownership of corporate equities in 1950. Households owned over 90 percent. By 2000 it can be seen that the situation had changed dramatically.By then households held less than 40 percent, nonbank intermediaries, primarily pension funds and mutual funds, held over 40 percent. This change illustrates why it is no longer possible to consider the role of financia l ma rkets and financial institu tions separately. Rather than intermediating directly between households and firms, financial institutions have increasingly come to intermediate between households and markets, on the one hand, and between firms and markets,on the o ther. This makes it necessary to consider the financial system as anirreducible whole.The notion that a financial system transfers resources between households and firms is, of course, a simplification. Go vernments usually play a significant role in the financ ial system. They are major borrowers, particularlyduring times of war, recession, or when large infrastructure projects are being undertaken. They sometimes also save significant amounts of funds. For example, when countries such as Norway and many Middle Eastern States have access to large amounts of natural resources (oil), the government may acquire large trust funds on behalf of the population.In addition to their roles as borrowers or savers, governments usually playa number of other important roles. C entral banks typically issue fiat money and are extensively involved in the payments system. Financial systems with unregulated markets and intermediaries, such as the US in the late nineteenth century, oftenexperience financial crises.The desire to eliminate these crises led many governments to intervene in a significant way in the financial system. Central banks or some other regulatory authority are charged with regulating the banking system and other intermediaries, such as insurance companies. So in most countries governments play an important role in the operation of financialsystems. This intervention means that the political system, which determines the government and its policies, is also relevant for the financial system.There are some historical instances wher e financial markets and institu tions have operated in the absence of a well-defined legal system, relyinginstead on reputation and other implicit mechanisms. However, in most financial systems the law plays an important role. It determines what kinds ofcontracts are feasible, what kinds of governance mechanisms can be used for corporations, the restrictions that can be placed on securities and so forth. Hence, the legal system is an important component of a financial system.A financial system is much more than all of this, however. An important pre-requisite of the ability to write contracts and enforce rights of various kinds is a system of accounting. In addition to allowing contracts to be written, an accounting system allows investors to value a company more easily and to assess how much it would be prudent to lend to it. Accounting information is only one type of information (albeit the most important) required by financial systems. The incentives to generate and disseminate information are crucial features of a financial system.Without significant amounts of human capital it will not be possible for any of these components of a financial system to operate effectively. Well-trained lawyers, accountants and financial professionals such as bankers are crucial for an effective financial system, as the experience of Eastern Europe demonstrates.The literature on comparative financial systems is at an early stage. Our survey builds on previous overviews by Allen (1993), Allen and Gale (1995) and Thakor (1996). These overviews have focused on two sets of issues.(1)Normative: How effective are different types of financial system atvarious functions?(2) Positive: What drives the evolution of the financial system?The first set of issues is considered in Sections 2-6, which focus on issues of investment and saving, growth, risk sharing, information provision and corporate governance, respectively. Section 7 considers the influence of law and politics on the financial system while Section 8 looks at the role financial crises have had in shaping the financial system. Section 9 contains concludingremarks.2 Investment and SavingOne of the primary purposes of the financial system is to allow savings to be invested in firms. In a series of important papers, Mayer (1988, 1990) docum ents how firms obtained funds and financed investment in a number of different countries. Table 2 shows the results from the most recent set of studies, based on data from 1970-1989, using Mayer’s methodology. The figures use data obtained from sources-and-uses-of-funds statements. For France, the data are from Bertero (1994), while for the US, UK, Japan and Germany they are from Corbett and Jenkinson (1996). It can be seen that internal finance is by far the most important source of funds in all countries.Bank finance is moderately importantin most countries and particularly important in Japan and France. Bond finance is only important in the US and equity finance is either unimportant or negative (i.e., shares are being repurchased in aggregate) in all countries. Mayer’s studies and those using his methodology have had an important impact because they have raised the question of how important financial markets are in terms of providing funds for investment. It seems that, at least in the aggregate, equity markets are unimportant while bond markets are important only in the US. These findings contrast strongly with the emphasis on equity and bond markets in the traditional finance literature. Bank finance is important in all countries,but not as important as internal fin ance.Another perspective on how the financial system operates is obtained by looking at savings and the holding of financial assets. Table 3 shows the relative importance of banks and markets in the US, UK, Japan, France and Germany. It can be seen that the US is at one extreme and Germany at the other. In the US, banks are relatively unimportant: the ratio of assets to GDP is only 53%, about a third the German ratio of 152%. On the other hand, the US ratio of equity market capitalization to GDP is 82%, three times the German ratio of 24%. Japan and the UK are interesting intermediate cases where banks and markets are both important. In France, banks are important and markets less so. The US and UK are often referred to as market-based systems while Germany, Japan and France are often referred to as bank-based systems. Table 4 shows the total portfolio allocation of assets ultimately owned by the household sector. In the US and UK, equity is a much more important component of household assets than in Japan,Germany and France. For cash and cash equivalents (which includes bank accounts), the reverse is true. Tables 3 and 4 provide an interesting contrast to Table 2. One would expect that, in the long run, household portfolios would reflect the financing patterns of firms. Since internal finance accrues to equity holders, one might expect that equity would be much more important in Japan, France and Germany. There are, of course, differences in the data sets underlying the different tables. For example, household portfolios consist of financial assets and exclude privately held firms, whereas the sources-and-uses-of-funds data include all firms. Nevertheless, it seems unlikely that these differences could cause such huge discrepancies. It is puzzling that these different ways of viewing the financial system produce such radically different results.Another puzzle concerning internal versus external finance is the difference between the developed world and emerging countries. Although it is true for the US, UK, Japan, France, Germany and for most other developed countries that internal finance dominates external finance, this is not the case for emerging countries. Singh and Hamid (1992) and Singh (1995) show that, for a range of emerging economies, external finance is more important than internal finance. Moreover, equity is the most important financing in strument and dominates debt. This difference between the industrialized nations and the emerging countries has so far received little attention. There is a large theoretical literature on the operation of and rationale for internal capital markets. Internal capital markets differ from external capital markets because of asymmetric information, investment incentives, asset specificity, control rights, transaction costs or incomplete markets There has also been considerable debate on the relationship between liquidity and investment (see, for example, Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen(1988), Hoshi, Kashyap and Scharfstein (1991))that the lender will not carry out the threat in practice, the incentive effect disappears. Although the lender’s behavior is now ex post optimal, both parties may be worse off ex ante.The time inconsistency of commitments that are optimal ex ante and suboptimal expost is typical in contracting problems. The contract commits one to certain courses of action in order to influence the behavior of the other party. Then once that party’s behavior has been determined, the benefit of the commitment disappears and there is now an incentive to depart from it.Whatever agreements have been entered into are subject to revision because both parties can typically be made better offby “renegotiating” the original agreement. The possibility of renegotiation puts additional restrictions on the kind of contract or agreement that is feasible (we are referring here to the contract or agreement as executed, rather than the contract as originally written or conceived) and, to that extent, tends to reduce the welfare of both parties ex ante. Anything that gives the parties a greater power to commit themselves to the terms of the contract will, conversely, be welfare-enhancing.Dewatripont and Maskin (1995) (included as a chapter in this section) have suggested that financial markets have an advantage over financial inter mediaries in maintaining commitments to refuse further funding. If the firm obtains its funding from the bond market, th en, in the event that it needs additional investment, it will have to go back to the bond market. Because the bonds are widely held, however, the firm will find it difficult to renegotiate with the bond holders. Apart from the transaction costs involved in negotiating with a large number of bond holders, there is a free-rider problem. Each bond holder would like to maintain his original claim over the returns to the project, while allowing the others to renegotiate their claims in order to finance the additional investment. The free-rider problem, which is often thought of as the curse of cooperative enterprises, turns out to be a virtue in disguise when it comes to maintaining commitments.From a theoretical point of view, there are many ways of maintaining a commitment. Financial institutions may develop a valuable reputation for maintaining commitments. In any one case, it is worth incurring the small cost of a sub-optimal action in order to maintain the value of the reputation. Incomplete information about the borrower’s type may lead to a similar outcome. If default causes the institution to change its beliefs about the defaulter’s type, then it may be optimal to refuse to deal with a firm after it has defaulted. Institutional strategies such as delegating decisions to agents who are given no discretion to renegotiate may also be an effective commitment device.Several authors have argued that, under certain circumstances, renegotiation is welfare-improving. In that case, the Dewatripont-Maskin argument is turned on its head. Intermediaries that establish long-term relationships with clients may have an advantage over financial markets precisely because it is easier for them to renegotiate contracts.The crucial assumption is that contracts are incomplete. Because of the high transaction costs of writing complete contracts, some potentially Pareto-improving contingencies are left out of contracts and securities. This incompleteness of contracts may make renegotiation desirable. The missing contingencies can be replaced by contract adjustments that are negotiated by the parties ex post, after they observe the realization of variables on which the contingencies would have been based. The incomplete contract determines the status quo for the ex post bargaining game (i.e., renegotiation)that determines the final outcome.An important question in this w hole area is “How important are these relationships empirically?” Here there does not seem to be a lot of evidence.As far as the importance of renegotiation in the sense of Dewatripont and Maskin (1995), the work of Asquith, Gertner and Scharfstein (1994) suggests that little renegotiation occurs in the case of financially distressed firms.Conventional wisdom holds that banks are so well secured that they can and do “pull the plug” as soon as a borrower becomes distressed, leaving theunsecured creditors and other claimants holding the bag.Petersen and Rajan (1994) suggest that firms that have a longer relationship with a bank do have greater access to credit, controlling for a number of features of the borrowers’ history. It is not clear from their work exac tly what lies behind the value of the relationship. For example, the increased access to credit could be an incentive device or it could be the result ofgreater information or the relationship itself could make the borrower more credit worthy. Berger and Udell (1992) find that banks smooth loan rates in response to interest rate shocks. Petersen and Rajan (1995) and Berlin and Mester (1997) find that smoothing occurs as a firm’s credit risk changes.Berlin and Mester (1998) find that loan rate smoothing is ass ociated with lower bank profits. They argue that this suggests the smoothing does not arise as part of an optimal relationship.This section has pointed to a number of issues for future research.• What is the relationship between the sources of funds for investment,as revealed by Mayer (1988, 1990), and the portfolio choices of investorsand institutions? The answer to this question may shed some light onthe relative importance of external and internal finance.• Why are financing patterns so different in developing and developedeconomies?• What is the empirical importance of long-term relationships? Is renegotiationimportant is it a good thing or a bad thing?• Do long-term relationships constitute an important advantage of bankbasedsystems over market-based systems?金融体系的比较1、什么是金融体系?一个金融系统的目的(作用)是将资金从盈余者(机构)向短缺者(机构)转移(输送)。

相关文档
最新文档