Lessons from the Debt-Deflation Theory of Sudden Stops

合集下载

耶鲁金融市场第11课

耶鲁金融市场第11课

美国耶鲁大学网络公开课《金融市场》视频笔记11耶鲁大学网络公开课《金融市场》由罗伯特.J.希勒(Robert J. Shiller)教授主讲。

共26课(集),每课时长均为一个多小时,配有字幕。

[第11课] 股票(时长1小时15分)(上课伊始,希勒先介绍了下次讲座嘉宾史蒂芬.施瓦茨曼的基本情况)史蒂芬.施瓦茨曼(Stephen Schwarzman)是耶鲁大学的毕业生,也是本世纪的伟大传奇之一。

史蒂芬于1985年白手起家,创建了最大的私募股权公司,后来公司上市,获得了巨大的市值,足以与纽约最大的历史悠久的诸多投资银行相比。

史蒂芬和彼得.彼得森(Peter Peterson)创建了这家公司。

所以,听他的讲座会是非常有趣的。

而且,你们会有机会向他提问,问问他所做的事情(笑)。

我在阅读材料上放了一篇《纽约客The New Yorker》上刚发表的文章,大概是几周前发表的,列入到教学大纲里了。

我觉得,在史蒂芬来之前,我应该把这篇文章撤下了(笑),我之所以要这样做(笑),是因为他对这篇文章可能不会喜欢。

这是一篇很尖刻的批评性文章。

史蒂芬必定是一位强硬的商人,才能达到他现在的位置。

《纽约客》的这篇文章谈到,史蒂芬在纽约有一套公寓,其价格创下新高(笑),还讲了诸如此类的一些事。

昨天我在伦敦,那里的人们也喜欢八卦这样的事情,豪华轿车司机送我去机场时,他指着车外的伦敦景点,他说,你认识那栋大楼吗?有一个阿拉伯酋长花了一亿英镑,买了那栋楼的顶层公寓,这个酋长还为自己订了一架空客,就是那种大型客机(空中巴士),作为私人飞机,还镀上金子(笑)。

你们有谁听过这个故事(笑)?是真的吗?那个司机就在昨天告诉我的,(笑)他说,他得花5亿英镑左右才能做到这样。

当然,这都是八卦闲话了,而实质是,这个人为世界做了什么贡献?所以,我在这里收集了一些慈善机构名录,史蒂芬.施瓦茨曼是这些机构的一位主要的慈善家。

史蒂芬在黑石集团(the Blackstone Group)下建立了“黑石基金会The Blackstone Foundation”,他也是许多慈善组织的主要资助者或合作人,例如弗里克藏馆(The Frick1Collection)、惠特尼博物馆(The Whtiney Museum)、凤凰楼戒毒所(Phoenix House)、红十字会(The Red Cross)、贫民区奖学金基金(The Inner City Scholarship Fund—ICSF)、纽约城市拓展基金(New York City Outward Bound)、(美国)亚洲协会(The Asia Society)。

经济学 好不容易找到的

经济学  好不容易找到的
for retirement or the children’s college education. When they choose to spend an
extra dollar on one of these goods, they have one less dollar to spend on some
people to make clothing, and still others to design computer software. Once soci-
ety has allocated people (as well as land, buildings, and machines) to various jobs,
perfect, way to
allocate resources
Learn what
determines some
trends in the overall
economy
4
PART ONE
INTRODUCTION
it must also allocate the output of goods and services that they produce. It must
decide who will eat caviar and who will eat potatoes. It must decide who will
drive a Porsche and who will take the bus.
The management of society’s resources is important because resources are

费雪的债务-通缩理论

费雪的债务-通缩理论

费雪的债务-通缩理论The debt-deflation theory of great depressions,Irving Fisher,1933译文:介绍在<<繁荣与萧条>>一书中,根据统计资料,我从理论上提出了一个解释大萧条的“债务-通货紧缩”理论。

在该书的前言中,我曾经提及,这些研究结果“似乎”很有新意。

之所以说“似乎”,是因为对于这一领域的大量文献我并不熟悉。

<<繁荣与萧条>>一经发表,其研究结论即广为接受。

到目前为止,在以前的文献中还没有发现有过类似的研究结果,尽管有好几个人,包括我本人在内曾经对此作过认真的文献考证。

这一领域的两位文献方面的权威向我保证,“这些研究结果既有新意又重要”(引用他们两个人的话)。

部分是为了明确那些结果是富有新意的,部分是为了将这些结果与这一领域已有的研究结果相结合,我写了这篇文章。

简单的说,就是借此表达我对所谓周期理论的全部信念。

全文共计49款,其中,结合传统的观点,新老观点并列。

之所以说是信念,简单的说,是因为表述过程是独断的,没有充足的证据。

但是,我的这些的理论上的信念并不取决于证据-即使在出现新的证据的情形下,我也无意对此作出修改。

这个意义上,它不是一个信念,而是一个尝试性的工作。

其他研究者可以将它视为一个挑战,以此为原料加工出更好的产品。

以下就是共计49款的研究结果。

1、一般的“周期”理论(1)一个经济系统有无数的变量-“物品”(实物财富,财产权,以及服务)的数量,这些物品的价格和它们的价值(数量与价格的乘积)。

很多的原因可以使得这一系列变量中的部分的或全部的变量发生变化。

仅仅在想象中,这些变量才会按照人们设想的那样,通过“供给和需求”的力量平衡达到稳定的均衡态。

(2)经济学的理论研究有如下的方向:(a),诸如此类的想象中的理想的均衡态-稳定或不稳定的;(b)非均衡态。

前者是静态的经济学,后者是动态的经济学。

CATTI一级笔译考试心得

CATTI一级笔译考试心得

CATTI一级笔译考试心得相比两三年前,如今CATTI的知名度更大了,考试的人数也在增加,不少人已经拿到了二级笔译证书。

相比之下,一级笔译参加和通过的人数则要少一些,下面我就和大家分享CATTI一级笔译考试心得,希望能够帮助到大家,来欣赏一下吧。

CATTI一级笔译考试心得本人英语翻译专业毕业,研一过了二笔(64分)二口(69分),研二65分过了一级笔译。

目前工作已有一年半时间,所以考试具体的内容记得不太清楚,更多地是谈谈我如何准备这门考试,以及个人认为考试通过需要具备哪些素质。

先说大家比较关心的字典和考试结构。

我参加一级笔译时带了《牛津·外研社英汉汉英词典》,英译汉和汉译英都可以用。

考试题型为一篇英译汉,一篇汉译英,一篇英译汉校对,一篇汉译英校对。

考试时间是3个小时,建议大家2小时内做完翻译部分,1小时做校对。

个人认为,一级笔译英译汉部分比《经济学人》浅显,汉译英比政府工作报告浅显,不涉及专业内容,跟二级笔译应该差不多,区别可能在于改分会更加严格。

一级笔译的备考,我没有找专门的教材和资料进行练习,主要是靠一直笔译兼职来锻炼(后文简称为实践)。

文件涉及范围广而杂:博鳌亚洲论坛、美国加州选举法、央视节目、电影字幕、安踏集团、股市投资等。

我也建议各位考生多实践,实践能更好地提高自己的翻译能力。

翻译5万字、10万字、50万字,你的感受和认识都是不一样的。

经过实践,你会发现一级的内容其实更简单,考试也不会那么慌。

对于外语类学生而言,实践的难点在于专业知识的理解以及行文是否符合内行人的习惯,阅读股市投资的英文材料有助于理解语境和句子,阅读中文材料有助于理解股市投资背后的逻辑思维以及所谓的“行话”是怎么说的。

比如trader在股市称为【操盘手】,close losing positions叫做【把亏损头寸平仓】。

这些知识需要自己去涉猎,而且日后对实践也有很大的裨益。

无论是英译汉还是汉译英,个人主张不要删减原文信息,但要让原文更加“灵活”一些,在考试和实践中都应如此。

The-Great-Depression

The-Great-Depression

The process
The stock market turned upward, returning to early 1929 levels by April.
Early 1930
A total of $30 billion in wealth disappeared.
November 13 1929
Great Depression
Content
Introduction
Background
The process
Economic and social problems
Causes
Historical influence
Introduction
The Great Depression was a severe worldwide economic depression that took place mostly during the 1930s, beginning in the United States. The timing of the Great Depression varied across nations; in most countries it started in 1929 and lasted until the late-1930s. It was the longest, deepest, and most widespread depression of the 20th century.
the expansion of American economic forcestechnological innovationfixed capital innovationrationalization of enterprise production and management

费雪大萧条的债务-通缩理论(Fei Xue the debt deflation theory of the Great Depression)

费雪大萧条的债务-通缩理论(Fei Xue the debt deflation theory of the Great Depression)

费雪大萧条的债务-通缩理论(Fei Xue the debtdeflation theory of the Great Depression)费雪大萧条的债务-通缩理论(Fei Xue the debt deflation theoryof the Great Depression)费雪:大萧条的债务-通缩理论2011-04-19在《繁荣与萧条》一书中,根据统计资料,我从理论上提出了一个解释大萧条的“债务,通货紧缩”理论。

在该书的前言中,我曾经提及,这些研究结果“似乎”很有新意。

之所以说“似乎”,是因为对于这一领域的大量文献我并不熟悉。

《繁荣与萧条》一经发表,其研究结论即广为接受。

到目前为止,在以前的文献中还没有发现有过类似的研究结果,尽管有好几个人,包括我本人在内曾经对此作过认真的文献考证。

这一领域的两位文献方面的权威向我保证,“这些研究结果既有新意又重要”(引用他们两个人的话)。

部分是为了明确那些结果是富有新意的,部分是为了将这些结果与这一领域已有的研究结果相结合,我写了这篇文章。

简单的说,就是借此表达我对所谓周期理论的全部信念。

全文共计49款,其中,结合传统的观点,新老观点并列。

之所以说是信念,简单的说,是因为表述过程是独断的,没有充足的证据。

但是,我的这些的理论上的信念并不取决于证据,即使在出现新的证据的情形下,我也无意对此作出修改。

这个意义上,它不是一个信念,而是一个尝试性的工作。

其他研究者可以将它视为一个挑战,以此为原料加工出更好的产品。

以下就是共计49款的研究结果。

1、一般的“周期”理论(1)一个经济系统有无数的变量,“物品”(实物财富,财产权,以及服务)的数量,这些物品的价格和它们的价值(数量与价格的乘积)。

很多的原因可以使得这一系列变量中的部分的或全部的变量发生变化。

仅仅在想象中,这些变量才会按照人们设想的那样,通过“供给和需求”的力量平衡达到稳定的均衡态。

(2)经济学的理论研究有如下的方向:(a),诸如此类的想象中的理想的均衡态,稳定或不稳定的;(b)非均衡态。

MONEY,BANKINGANDFINANCE:货币,银行与金融

MONEY,BANKINGANDFINANCE:货币,银行与金融

MONEY, BANKING AND FINANCECEU, Economics DepartmentLecturer: Prof. Jacek RostowskiCourse: 4 creditsAims of the courseThe aim of the course is to develop the students' understanding of the microeconomics of money and banking, of the role of the monetary and banking systems in a market economy, and of the macroeconomic impact of the behaviour of banking firms. Students should also develop a knowledge of the structure of banking systems, their place in the wider environment of the financial system and of the economy as a whole, as well as the implications both for microeconomic regulatory policy and national and global macroeconomic policy of bank behaviour. Lectures will concentrate on the structure of financial and banking systems and on the microeconomic theory of banking, as well as the impact of the banking sector on macroeconomic fluctuations and policy. A final section will address the issue of banking reform in the transition from Communism. Seminars will address a wide range of historical, empirical and policy topics, and will require broad reading, critical analysis of the recommended material and its succinct presentation in class.***Assessment:The course will consist of lectures and seminars. Students will be required to present a seminar paper on a specific topic relating to the course, to submit this paper after revision, as a term paper and to pass a written 3 hour essay-type exam at the end of the course.The purpose of this form of assessment is to help develop students’ presentational and writing skills, as well as their ability to summarize arguments, cogently and convincingly.GradingTerm paper 45%Term examination 55%Course Outline:PART ONE: INTRODUCTION - THE STRUCTURE OF FINANCIAL SYSTEMSPART TWO: REASONS FOR THE EXISTENCE OF BANKS.PART THREE: BANK RUNS AND BANK REGULATION.PART FOUR: OTHER REASONS FOR BANK REGULATION.PART FIVE: THE EVOLUTION OF BANKING REGULATION SINCE THE 1930s.PART SIX: INTEREST RATES, MONEY AND CENTRAL BANKS IN MACROECONOMIC POLICY.PART SEVEN: DEBT DEFLATION, BANKING AND THE MONETARY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM.PART EIGHT: BANKING REFORM IN TRANSITION.ECONOMICS OF MONEY AND BANKINGPART ONE: INTRODUCTION - THE STRUCTURE OF FINANCIAL SYSTEMS1. Wealth, real assets, financial assets and capital markets.2. Financial development and growth.3.Macro-financial ratios and the structure of the financial sector.4. Bank based v. Market based financial systems.5. Credit as a short term facilitator of investment.5. The interaction of bank credit and equity finance.PART TWO: REASONS FOR THE EXISTENCE OF BANKS.1. Traditional explanations for the existence of banks.2. Adverse selection, the ex-post verification problem and moral hazard.3. The bank - lender relation: why lenders need banks.4. Firm size and the relevance of the Diamond model.5. Firm bankruptcy costs and the existence of banks.PART THREE: BANK RUNS AND BANK REGULATION.1. Unconvincing arguments for bank regulation.2. Causes of bank runs: individual bank runs and runs on the system.3. Information based and irrational runs.4. What the authorities can do about bank runs.5. What banks can do to prevent bank runs.PART FOUR: OTHER REASONS FOR BANK REGULATION.1. Justifications of bank regulation.2. Neo-classical and Neo-Austrian views of banking competition.PART FIVE: THE EVOLUTION OF BANKING REGULATION SINCE THE 1930s.1. Main mechanisms of regulation during the "Keynesian" period.2. The erosion of controls since the 1960s and inflation.3. Changes in supply conditions: telecoms and computers.4. The decline of the banking industry.5. Implications of the decline of the banking industry for regulation.6. The "new regulatory framework".7. International harmonisation in the "New Framework".PART SIX: INTEREST RATES, MONEY AND CENTRAL BANKS IN MACROECONOMIC POLICY.1. Monetarist and Keynesian transmission mechanisms.2. Should central banks control interest rates or the monetary base?3. International capital mobility on the term structure of interest rates.4. Credit rationing and the "credit channel" for monetary policy.5. Other channels for the monetary transmission mechanism.PART SEVEN: DEBT DEFLATION, BANKING AND THE MONETARY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM.1. Net worth, equity rationing and business cycles.2. The Greenwald-Stiglitz model and credit rationing.3. Debt deflation and the Greenwald-Stiglitz model.4. Unemployment in the Greenwald-Stiglitz model.5. Anatomy of a debt deflation.6. Debt deflation via the aggregate demand channel.7. Including asset prices in the price level for monetary policy purposes.8. Asset prices in the inter-war period in the US.PART EIGHT: MONEY AND BANKING IN TRANSITION1. The Monobank system, Active and Passive Money, the MFO.2. The "Main Sequence" of banking reforms in Central Europe and the FSU Model.3. Radical Proposals for banking Sector Reform.4. The Payments System, Settlement Risk and Inter-enterprise Arrears.5. Banking Crises in PCEs and their Remedies.6. Progress with the wrong model?MONEY, BANKING AND FINANCE- SEMINAR TOPICS -[* marks reqired reading for all students, not just presenters]1. Assess the "real bills doctrine"and the "principle of reflux" which figured prominently in the three cornered debates between the currency school, the banking school and the free banking school in mid-nineteenth century England.A.J. Schwartz "Banking School, Currency School, Free Banking School" in TheNew Palgrave Dictionary of Economics: Volume on Money, eds. J. Eatwell, M. Millgate and P. Newman, MacMillan, 1989.*R. Green "The Real Bills doctrine" in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics:Volume on Money, eds. J. Eatwell, M. Millgate and P. Newman, MacMillan, 1989.V.Smith The Rationale for Central Banking and the Free Banking Alternative, Liberty Press, Indianapolis, 1990.2. Discuss the controversy between bullionists and the currency school on the one hand and supporters of the banking school on the other.D. Laidler "The Bullionist Controversy" in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics: Volume on Money, eds. J. Eatwell, M. Millgate and P. Newman, MacMillan, 1989.*A.J. Schwartz "Banking School, Currency School, Free Banking School" in TheNew Palgrave Dictionary of Economics: Volume on Money, eds. J. Eatwell, M. Millgate and P. Newman, MacMillan, 1989.3. Why are middle developed countries particularly subject to banking crises?Kaminsky,G. and C.Reinhart (1996) "The Twin Crises: the Causes of Banking andBalance of Payments Problems" International Finance Discussion Papers, no. 544,Federal Reserve, washington,D.C.*Sundararajan, V. and Balino, J.T., Banking Crises: Cases and Issues, IMF, 1991,Chapter 1.*4. Does a "hard-peg" exchange rate system make a country more susceptible to banking crises?Temzelides, T. (1997) "Are Bank Runs Contagious?" Business Review, Federalreserve Bank of Philadelphia, November, Philadelphia.*Santiprabhob,V. (1997) "Bank Soundness and Currency Board Arrangements",Working Paper PPAA/97/11, International Monetary Fund, Washington,D.C. 5. Discuss the arguments for and against the independence of central banks.A.S. Posen "Why Central bank Independence Does Not Cause Low Inflation: Thereis no Institutional Fix for Politics", Finance and the International Economy: 7, TheAMEX BANK Review 1993.*Alesina "Politics and Business Cycles in the Industrial Democracies", EconomicPolicy, April 1989.C.A.E. Goodhart "Central Bank Independence" in The Central Bank and the Financial System, C.A.E. Goodhart, 1995.6. Should central banks supervise the banking system, and if so should they supervise non-bank financial institutions as well?Goodhart, C. (2001)"The Organizational Structure of Banking Supervision”, in Financial Stability and Central Banks, a global perspective, eds. J.Healey and P.Sinclair, Routledge and Bank of England, pp.254.Peek,J., E.Rosengren and G.Tootell (2001) in Prudential Supervision: What Works and What doesn’t ed. F.Mishkin, NBER and Chicago University Press, Chicago, pp.368.7. How do regulation and ownership affect banking sector performance and stability?Barth, J.R., G.Caprio and R.Levine (2001) “Banking Systems around the Globe: Do Regulation and Ownership affect Performance and Stability?” in Prudential Supervision: What Works and What doesn’t ed. F.Mishkin, NBER and Chicago University Press, Chicago, pp.368.Brealey,R. (2001) “Bank capital requirements and the control of bank failure”, in Financial Stability and Central Banks, a global perspective, eds. J.Healey and P.Sinclair, Routledge and Bank of England, pp.254.8. Assess Argentina’s attempt at creating a credible and partly market-based system of bank regulation. Does it hold lessons for other emerging market and transition economies?Calomiris, C. and A.Powell (2001) “Can Emerging Market Regulators Establish Credible Discipline? The Case of Argentina, 1992-99” in Prudential Supervision: What Works and What doesn’t ed. F.Mishkin, NBER and Chicago University Press, Chicago, pp.368.De la Torre, A., E.Levy Yeyati,S.Schmukler (2002) “Argentina’s Financial Crisis: Floating Money, Sinking Banking”, mimeo, paper presented at the London School of Economics Conference on Euroization and Dollarisation, March 18-19, available on /~ely/papers.html .9. Does the stringency of bank supervision affect the macroeconomy? Berger,A., M.Kyle and J.Scalise (2001) “Did US Bank Supervisors get tougher during the Credit Crunch? Did they get easier during the Banking Boom? Did it matter to Bank Lending?” in Prudential Supervision: What Works and What doesn’t ed. F.Mishkin, NBER and Chicago University Press, Chicago, pp.368.10. Can the ECB’s monetary policy function properly given the differences in legal and financial structure among the states participating in EMU?Cecchetti, S. (1999) “Legal Structure, Financial Structure and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism”, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No 7151, available on /papers/w7151 *11. Does a "pensions overhang" threaten the macroeconomic stability of the developed countries?International Monetary Fund World Economic Outlook, Focus on Fiscal Policy, pp50-60.*E. Phillip Davis "The Development of Pension Funds: an approaching FinancialRevolution for Continental Europe" Finance and the International Economy: 7, TheAMEX BANK Review 1993.The World Bank Averting the Old Age Crisis, Oxford UP, 1994.12. How convincing is the evidence that financial sector development leads to faster economic growth?Levine,R. (1997) "Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda",Journal of Economic Literature, Vol.35 (June), pp.688-726.*King,R.G. and R.Levine (1993) "Finance, Entrepreneurship and Growth: Theory andEvidence", Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol.32, pp.513-542.13. Account for the existence of credit rationing. Is this phenomenon likely to be important in practice?Freixas, X. and Rochet,J-C. (1997) The Microeconomics of Banking, Chapter 5.*Stiglitz,J. and Weiss,A. (1981) "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information", American Economic Review, 71(3):393-410.Bester,H. (1985) "Screening v. rationing in credit markets with imperfect information", American Economic Review, 75(4):850-55.14. How important is the lending channel for macroeconomic policy? Kashyap, A. and Stein, J. "Monetary Policy and Bank Lending" in G, Mankiw ed.Monetary Policy, Chicago UP, 1994.*Miron, J., Romer, C. and Weil, D. "Historical Perspecties on the Monetary Transmission Mechanism", in G. Mankiw ed. Monetary Policy, Chicago UP, 1994.15. Assess the empirical evidence on the imperfection of capital markets.Fazzari, S., Hubbard, R. and Petersen, B. (1988) "Financing Constrains and Corporate Investment", Brookings Papers in Economic Activity, I, 141-206.*Kashyap,A., Lamont, O. and Stein, J. (1994) "Credit Conditions and the CyclicalBehavoiour of Inventories", Quarterly Journal of Economics.Deveroux, M. and Schiantarelli, F. (1990) "Investment, Financial Factors and CashFlow: Evidence from UK Panel Data", in Assymetric Information, Capital Marketsand Investment, ed. R. Hubard, Chicago UP.16. Is "relationship banking" superior to other kinds of banking? Ongena,S. and D.Smith (2000) "Bank Relationships: a Review" in Performance ofFinancial Institutions: efficiency, innovation, regulation, eds. P.Harker andS.Zenios,Cambridge UP.*Dewenter,K. and A.Hess (2000) "Risks and Returns in Relationship and Transactional Banks: evidence from returns in Germany, Japan, the UK and theUS." in Performance of Financial Institutions: efficiency, innovation, regulation, eds.P.Harker and S.Zenios, Cambridge UP.17. Should financial institutions specialise or diversify so as to maximise their efficiency and profits?Meador, J., H.Ryan and C,Schellhorn (2000) "Product focus vs. Diversification: estimates of X-efficiency for the US life insurance industry" in Performance of Financial Institutions: efficiency, innovation, regulation, eds. P.Harker andS.Zenios,Cambridge UP.*Eicholtz, P., H. Op t’Veld and M.Schweitzer (2000) "REIT Performance: does managerial specialization pay?" in Performance of Financial Institutions: efficiency,innovation, regulation, eds. P.Harker and S.Zenios, Cambridge UP.18. Discuss the effectiveness of the following financial institutions in Transition Economies:All presenters and students:Buiter,W., go and H.Rey (1999) "Financing Transition: Investing in Enterprises during Macroeconomic Transition" in Financial sectorTransformation: Lessons from Economies in Transition, eds. M.Blejer and M.Skreb, Cambridge UP, 401pp.*a) Universal Banks.Rostowski,J., 1998, "Universal Banking and Economic Growth in Post-Communist Economies" in Macroeconomic Instability in Post-Communist Countries, Chap. 13,Oxford UP.*Perotti,E. and Gelfer,S., (1998), "Investment Financing in RussianFinancial-Industrial Groups" CASE-CEU Working Papers Series, no10.*Fan, Q., Lee,U. and M.Schaffer, (1996), "Firms, Banks and Credit in Russia" in Enterprise Restructuring and Economic Policy in Russia, eds.mander,Fan,Q. and M.Schaffer, The World Bank.b) Commercial Banks.Pinto,B. and van Wijnbergen,S. 1994, "Ownership and Corporate Control in Poland:why State Enterprises Defied the Odds", Policy Research Working Paper No.1308, World Bank, Washington, D.C.*Baer,H. and Gray,C., (1996), "Debt as a Control Device in Transitional Economies:the experiences of Hungary and Poland" in Corporate governance in Central Europe and Russia, Vol.1, eds. R.Frydman, C.Gray and A.Rapaczynski, CEU Press.*Bratkowski,A., Grosfeld,I. And Rostowski,J., 1999, "Investment and Finance in de novo Private Firms: Empirical Results from the Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland", CASE_CEU Working Papers Series No.21, Budapest-Warsaw.Carare,O. and Perotti,E., (1997), "The Evolution of Bank Credit Quality in Romania since 1991" in Lessons from the Economic Transition: Central and Eastern Europe in the 1990s, ed. S.Zecchini, Kluwer.c) Privatization Funds:Coffee,J., (1996), "Institutional Investors in Transitional Economies: Lessons from the Czech Experience", pp.111-8 and pp.145-85 in Corporate governance in Central Europe and Russia, Vol.1, eds. R.Frydman, C.Gray and A.Rapaczynski,CEU Press.*Frydman,R., Pistor,K. and rapaczynski,A., (1996) "Investing in Insider Dominated Firms: a Study of Russian Voucher Privatization Funds" in Corporate governance in Central Europe and Russia, Vol.1, eds. R.Frydman,C.Gray and A.Rapaczynski,CEU Press.19. To what extent are the problems of the financial sector in China special?Mundell,R. "Monetary and Financial Market Reform in Transition Economies: the special case of China" in Financial sector Transformation: Lessons from Economies in Transition, eds. M.Blejer and M.Skreb, Cambridge UP, 401pp.* Li, David. , Qian,Yingyi , Wang, Yijiang and Bai, Chong-en. " Anonymus Banking and Financial Repression: How Does China's Reform Limit Government Predation without Reducing its Revenue?" CEPR Discussion Paper Series No. 2221.。

凯恩斯有效需求理论 中英文摘要

凯恩斯有效需求理论 中英文摘要

论凯恩斯的有效需求理论英文摘要:Keynesian theory system based on solving the employment problem as the center, and the logical starting point of the employment theory is the effective demand principle. The c ommunity employment is governed by the effective demand: so-called effective demand is the aggregate demand when the aggregate supply price and the aggregate demand price achieve equilibrium point. When the aggregate demand price is greater than the aggregate supply price, the community demand exceeds the supply of goods. The e ntrepreneurs will increase the employment and expand the production; conversely, the aggregate demand price is less than the aggregate supply price, the community supply exceeds the demand. The entrepreneurs are forced to sale articles, cut down the amount of employment and contract the scale of production. Therefore, the community employment is governed by the equilibrium point between the aggregate demand and the aggregate supply. In the short term, the production costs and normal profit do not fluctuate much. Thus the production that the e ntrepreneurs are willing to supply does not change a lot, the aggregate supply remains stable. In this way, the community employment actually depends on the aggregate demand. This aggregate demand that is balanced with the aggregate supply is the effective demand中文摘要:凯恩斯主义的理论体系是以解决就业问题为中心的,而他的就业理论的逻辑起点就是有效需求理论。

  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

Lessons from the Debt-Deflation Theory of Sudden StopsBy Enrique G. Mendoza*The “Sudden Stop” phenomenon of the recurrent emerging markets crises of the last ten years is one of the key questions facing International Macroeconomics. Sudden Stops are defined by unusually large recessions marked by: sharp, abrupt current account reversals, large contractions in output and absorption, and collapses in goods and asset prices. In Mexico’s 1995 Sudden Stop, for example, the current account shifted by nearly 9 percentage points of GDP, and GDP, consumption and investment fell by magnitudes that exceeded their business cycle standard deviations by about a factor of 3. Only the Great Depression shows a recession with comparable magnitudes in the country’s economic history.The dominant paradigms of the early 1990s, International Real Business Cycle Theory (IRBC) and the New Open Economy Macroeconomics, were unable to explain Sudden Stops because they assume a perfect global credit market that allows households to smooth consumption, and firms to finance production and investment efficiently. For example, small open economy (SOE) models in the IRBC tradition predict that, when a negative, transitory productivity shock hits, households borrow to smooth consumption, firms keep investment and production plans unaltered, and the current account falls slightly. If the shock has some persistence, households borrow less and adjust consumption more, and firms cut investment and production, resulting in regular, countercyclical current account fluctuations. Indeed, SOE-IRBC models proved quite good at mimicking the business cycles of industrial economies.Sudden Stops are strikingly different. At the time that output experiences Great-Depression-size declines, the current account takes an abrupt jump up and domestic absorption plummets. Just when the dominant paradigms predict that agents need capital markets the most, agents cannot borrow at all.A growing literature aiming to explain Sudden Stops emerged in recent years. The starting point of this literature is to replace the assumption of perfect credit markets with plausible financial frictions. Despite important progress in theoretical work, three key issues are still unresolved:(a) Sudden Stops are modeled as large, unexpected shocks. In most Sudden Stop models (for example, Guillermo A. Calvo (1998), Lawrence J. Christiano et al. (2004), V.V. Chari et al. (2005)), current account reversals are a surprise –a large, sudden exogenous shock to foreign borrowing. This assumption has several unappealing implications: First, the defining feature of Sudden Stops (the abrupt current account reversal) remains unexplained. Second, agents are not allowed to make optimal plans considering the probability that Sudden Stops may occur. Third, we cannot tell whether the predictions of particular models are robust to changes allowing agents to act on expectations of Sudden Stops. Precautionary savings theory suggests that this can be a flaw because, when faced with possible catastrophic events, agents build a buffer stock of savings to lower the long-run probability of these outcomes.(b) Sudden Stop models cannot explain the output collapse in the initial stages of a Sudden Stop. Most existing models consider financial frictions affecting consumption and/or investment, which affect output after the initial current account reversal. Moreover, growth accounting exercises (Raphael Bergoeing et al. (2002) and Enrique G. Mendoza (2005a)) show that capital and labor account for a small fraction of the initial output collapse, so even if the models could mimic observed investment collapses, they would not explain the output collapse. Since a current account reversal represents the loss of access to world credit for the economy as a whole, however, it makes sense to view the growth accounting results as indicative of endogenous links between measured TFP (e.g. Solow residuals) and Sudden Stops. This idea is appealing because Sudden Stops also feature large swings in imported input prices and capacity utilization (see David Cook and Michael B. Devereux (2006) and Mendoza (2005a)), and it is well-known that swings like these turn Solow residuals into a poor measure of true TFP (see Mary G. Finn (1995)).(c) The quantitative relevance of financial mechanisms driving Sudden Stop models is largely unknown. Narayana Kocherlakota (2000) casts doubt on the ability of credit constraints to yield sizable asymmetry,amplification and persistence in the responses of macroeconomic aggregates to adverse shocks. Also, Chari et al. (2005) argue that output cannot fall in response to an unanticipated shock to the current account. Moreover, because of the scarcity of quantitative findings, we cannot tell whether a financial friction with reasonable Sudden Stop features can produce Sudden Stops as infrequent events nested within typical fluctuations (as observed in the data). The structure of emerging economies does not change abruptly when they hit a Sudden Stop, so a theory that explains Sudden Stops by introducing frictions that result in unrealistic business cycles is not very helpful. It is equally important to distinguish mechanisms that enlarge business cycle variability from mechanisms that create Sudden Stops. Chari et. al (2005) mix the two in referring to Pablo A. Neumeyer and Fabrizio Perri’s (2005) model of large business cycles driven by large interest rate shocks as a model of Sudden Stops. Sudden Stops are not observable in standard business cycle moments because unusually large recessions are, by definition, swamped by typical cycles.This paper reports results for a class of equilibrium models with credit constraints that aim to make progress in addressing the above problems. The two key features common to these models are that: whether the credit constraints bind is an endogenous equilibrium outcome, and when they bind, they set in motion Irving Fisher’s (1933) debt-deflation mechanism. This mechanism induces nonlinear feedback between a country’s access to credit and the prices of goods and assets on which debt is leveraged. Several theoretical articles in the Sudden Stops literature study models with the debt-deflation mechanism (see Cristina Arellano and Mendoza (2003) for a limited survey). The contribution of the models reviewed here is the quantitative analysis of this mechanism in a dynamic, stochastic equilibrium framework.The quantitative debt-deflation models of Sudden Stops yield three key lessons:(1) Sudden Stops emerge endogenously without large, unexpected shocks. They are an endogenous outcome in environments in which agents plan their actions taking credit constraints and expectations of Sudden Stops into account. A Sudden Stop is an equilibrium response to typical realizations of adverse shocks to fundamentals (e.g. world interest rates, the terms of trade, or TFP) when agents are highly indebted. In turn, these high-debt states are reached with positive probability in the long run as a result of the equilibrium dynamics of the economy.(2) Collateral constraints do cause output declines during Sudden Stops. Output falls on impact when a Sudden Stop begins if access to working capital is hampered by credit constraints, or if the debt-deflation mechanism lowers the value of the marginal product of factors of production. In addition, contrary to the findings of Chari et al. (2005), output does fall after an initial current account reversal in the presence of endogenous collateral constraints that limit debt to a fraction of the market value of physical capital. (3) The quantitative effects of the debt-deflation mechanism are important. This mechanism yields significant amplification and asymmetry in the responses of macro variables to standard shocks. In addition, Sudden Stops are infrequent events nested within regular business cycles. If the credit constraints do not bind, the economy responds to adverse shocks as SOE-IRBC models predict. Precautionary saving rules out the largest Sudden Stops from the stochastic stationary state, but it does not rule out all Sudden Stops. Hence, Sudden Stops remain a positive-probability event even though they do not affect business cycle statistics.I. Debt-Deflation Models of Business Cycles and Sudden StopsThe models are based on Mendoza’s (1991) SOE-IRBC framework, which is not described in detail due to space constraints, but replacing the assumption of perfect credit markets with borrowing constraints. The models represent the decentralized competitive equilibrium of economies where the agents’ ability to borrow in a world market of one-period bonds (b) is limited to a fraction κ of the market value of the income or assets offered as collateral:()11,,,,,0t t t t t t b g p y k k b κκ++≥−≥ (1)The collateral function g(⋅) depends on a vector of market prices p (for goods, factors, or assets), on income, y , on asset holdings, k , and on existing debt. This credit constraint captures a wide variety of borrowing limits. At the extremes, κ=0 represents a no-borrowing constraint and κ=∞ is the perfect-credit-markets case. When g(⋅) is a constant, the constraint is an ad-hoc debt limit. The case with g(⋅)=q t αt+1k , where q t is the price of equity and αt+1 are equity shares of a constant capital stock, is Rao Aiyagari and Mark Gertler’s (1999) margin constraint. Kocherlakota (2000) examined the constraint g(⋅)=q t k , with k as a factor in inelastic supply (e.g. land). The case with g(⋅)=y t T +p t N y t N , where y T and y N are incomes from tradables and nontradables respectively and p N is the relative price of nontradables, is the liability dollarization credit constraint (foreign debt is in units of tradables but leveraged in part on nontradables income). The price of nontradables is endogenous and a drop in p N (i.e., a real depreciation) can trigger the constraint.On the side of firms, the credit constraint (1) can represent a limit on the firms’ access to working capital. For instance, b t+1 can represent working capital loans and g(⋅) could be the firms’ sales (as if these loans were trade credits guaranteed by sales) or the market value of the firms’ physical assets. Constraints of this type can be helpful in building a credit transmission channel that links the loss of access to world credit with an immediate drop in output, as Section II explains.A. Distortions Induced by Credit Constraints in Debt Deflation ModelsConstraints in the family defined in (1) introduce distortions akin to endogenous financing premia. In general, the consumption Euler equation of models with these constraints can be written as:[]1t t t t E R λλμ+=+ (2) where λt is the lifetime marginal utility of date-t consumption (i.e. the Lagrange multiplier on the budget constraint), μt is the Lagrange multiplier on the credit constraint, and R is the world-determined real interest rate (assumed to be time-invariant for simplicity). Defining the households’ intertemporal relative price of consumption as []11h t t t t R E λλ++≡, it follows that, when (1) binds, households face the following endogenous financing premium:[]11h t t t t t E R R μλ++⎡⎤−=⎣⎦ (3)In models that allow for asset accumulation, this premium alters excess asset returns as follows:[]()11111cov (,)[]q t t t t q t t t t R E R R E μκλλ++++⎛⎞−−⎟⎜−=⎟⎜⎟⎜⎝⎠, (4) where R q t+1 is the return on assets. Thus, a binding credit constraint has a direct effect that increases the equity premium by the fraction (1-κ) of the hike in the financing premium. This effect is limited to the fraction (1-κ) because, on the margin, agents can relax their credit constraint by holding more assets, with the marginal increase in “debt capacity” given by κ.1 A binding credit constraint also has the Heaton-Lucas indirect effect because the constraint hampers the ability of agents to smooth consumption, and hence makes the covariance between marginal utility and asset returns “more negative,” thereby increasing excess returns. The forward solution for the households’ asset valuations yields:[]11001j t t t i q t t i j i q E d E R ∞++++==⎛⎞⎡⎤⎛⎞⎟⎜⎟⎜⎢⎥⎟=⎜⎟⎜⎟⎟⎜⎜⎢⎥⎟⎜⎝⎠⎝⎠⎣⎦∑∏ (5) where d represents dividends. Expressions (4) and (5) show that a credit constraint that binds at present,or is expected to bind at any point in the future, increases excess returns and lowers asset prices bid by the agents facing the constraint. As Section II explains, however, this is necessary but not sufficient for equilibrium asset prices to fall when the credit constraints bind.In models in which firms face limits on working capital, firms face a financing premium that increases effective factor costs when this limit binds. If, for example, working capital financing is available up to afraction κf of the value of the firms’ assets at the end of the production period, the optimality condition for the demand for factor n j for which a fraction φ of the cost is paid with credit is:[]()1()j p A t n t t t F N p r R εεφχ=++ (6) ()j n t F N is the marginal product of n j in a production function F(N) that uses a vector of inputs N , r is the net interest rate on working capital (i.e., R-1), χt is the Lagrange multiplier on the working capital constraint, and εA and εP are shocks to TFP and the market price of n j . If χt =0, condition (6) reduces to the optimality condition of SOE-IRBC models with the standard working capital setup (e.g. Neumeyer and Perri (2005)). P. Marcelo Oviedo (2005) showed that these models require interest rate processes with high mean and variance for working capital to make a difference. In contrast, when the limit on working capital binds, the marginal cost of n j rises because the effective financing cost of working capital goes up by χt R . This endogenous financing premium amplifies the responses of factor demands to shocks, and this mechanism can be triggered by shocks to TFP or factor prices, even with a constant interest rate. Moreover, if the amplified factor demand responses make asset prices fall, the debt-deflation mechanism is set in motion because the fall in the value of the collateral tightens further the limit on working capital.The credit constraints examined here are endogenous because they respond to equilibrium prices and allocations (as in Macroeconomics literature on credit constraints by Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and John Moore (1997), Aiyagari and Gertler (1999) or Kocherlakota (2000)), but they are not modeled as outcomes of optimal credit contracts. Still, the above financing premia represent endogenous premia, varying across time and states depending on whether the credit constraints bind and on how binding they are, which foreign lenders could charge so that borrowers find it optimal to respect the credit constraints in a credit market where the constraints are not imposed directly.2 The justification for this could be that, for example, limited enforcement prevents lenders from recovering more than κ or κf of the market value of a debtor’s assets in case of non-repayment.B. Amplification, Sudden Stops & Debt Deflations: A Liability Dollarization ExampleThe endogenous, nonlinear feedback between price deflation and debt access sets the debt-deflation mechanism apart from other credit constraints studied in the Sudden Stops literature. This is an important point that can be illustrated with an example based on a simple deterministic, two-sector model. The model features a time-invariant endowment of nontradables and a sequence of tradables endowment tilted towards the future (so that agents wish to borrow at present).3 With standard stationarity assumptions and perfect credit markets, the equilibrium of this economy is a textbook example of Permament Income theory: tradables consumption is perfectly smooth, nontradables consumption and the relative price of nontradables are constant, and the current account moves to keep tradables consumption as a constant fraction of wealth (with wealth equal to the present value of the tradables endowment). Add now the liability dollarization credit constraint b t+1 ≥ -κ(y t T +p t N y t N ), and hit the economy with wealth-neutral shocks that reduce y 0T and increase y 1T . As long as the credit constraint does not bind, the equilibrium with perfect credit markets is preserved. There is, however, a critical value of y 0T low enough for the constraint to bind, and below this value the frictionless equilibrium is no longer attainable.Figure 1 illustrates the date-0 equilibrium of this debt-deflation model. The equilibrium with the credit constraint binding must satisfy two conditions: First, the resource constraint for tradables with debt set at the borrowing limit must hold (which is the case along the SS line — notice that SS shifts horizontally to the left as y 0T falls). Second, p 0N must equal the marginal rate of substitution between consumption of tradables and nontradables. This condition is represented by the PP curve. The line TT represents tradables consumption with perfect credit markets (or when the credit constraint does not bind), which is independent of the price of nontradables. TT and PP intersect at the equilibrium withperfect credit markets (point A). The curve SS is drawn for the critical value of yT at which the constraint begins to bind, so SS intersects TT and PP at point A. This is a case with negligiblyconstrained debt that still yields the frictionless equilibrium.Assume that yT falls below its critical level causing SS to shift to SS′. The new equilibrium is determined at point D, and the change from A to D can be broken down into three moves. First, if prices were sticky and the borrowing constraint were set as an ad-hoc debt limit, the new equilibrium would be at point B. At B, however, tradables consumption is lower than in the perfectly smooth case andequilibrium requires pN to fall. Thus, the second move, from B to C, reflects the pure balance sheet effect of liability dollarization (as in Calvo (1998)). If the credit constraint were independent of the nontradables price (i.e., without debt deflation), C would be the new equilibrium, with a lower nontradables price and lower tradables consumption. But at C the debt deflation has yet to take place. Hence, the third move, from C to D, occurs because the lower price at C in the PP line tightens the credit constraint by lowering the value of the nontradables endowment. This forces tradables consumption to fall so as to satisfy theconstraint at a point in SS′, but at that point pN falls again to re-attain a point along PP, but at that point tradables consumption falls again because the credit constraint tightens further. This debt-deflationprocess continues until it converges to point D. In short, the response to the shock hitting yT is amplified because of the combined balance sheet and debt-deflation effects.Two important observations about the Sudden Stop equilibrium: First, the abrupt current account reversal is an endogenous response to a domestic shock, not the result of a big surprise hitting world capital markets. Second, the Sudden Stop occurs even with fully flexible prices and is not the result of a self-fulfilling shift across multiple equilibria.Mendoza (2005b) conducts some numerical experiments with this basic model using parameter values set to match roughly key features of emerging economies, particularly the elasticity of substitution between consumption of tradables and nontradables. This elasticity is crucial because it determines the response of p N to a given contraction in tradables consumption. The results show that the amplification generated by the debt-deflation mechanism dwarfs that produced by the balance sheet effect. For example, setting κ=0.34, a 5-percent wealth-neutral shock to y0T reduces the debt position by 15percentage points of permanent income, and makes tradables consumption and pN fall to levels nearly 60 percent below those of the equilibrium with perfect credit markets. The debt-deflation mechanism contributes all but 3 percentage points of these declines in consumption and the price of nontradables.II. The Quantitative LessonsIn order to make progress in addressing the problems affecting existing Sudden Stop models, we need to move beyond analytically tractable, but by necessity simple, models and consider instead quantitative dynamic, stochastic models that can be compared with the data.A. Liability Dollarization RevisitedMendoza (2002) examines a dynamic general equilibrium model with the liability dollarization credit constraint that considers uncertainty and production of nontradables with labor demand and supply decisions. The credit constraint limits households’ tradables-denominated debt to a fraction of their income, as is standard practice in household debt markets (where lenders use scoring algorithms to set ceilings on debt-income ratios). Since the production technology is Cobb-Douglas, this translates atequilibrium into the constraint bt+1 ≥ -κ(ytT+ptN ytN). Agents know that this constraint is a feature of thecredit market and they take it into account in formulating their optimal plans. The credit constraint binds occasionally as an endogenous equilibrium outcome, and Sudden Stops occur in response to “typical” realizations of shocks to TFP, the world interest rate, and an inflation-equivalent consumption tax. Moreover, in these Sudden Stops output falls on impact because a collapse in ptN lowers the value of the marginal product of labor, and hence labor demand.Simulations based on a calibration to Mexican data show that, as the level of debt moves above the critical level at which adverse shocks trigger the credit constraint, the impact responses of macro aggregates to these shocks are amplified significantly. Comparing with the responses under perfect credit markets, the current account reversal is 5 percentage points of GDP larger, consumption and nontradables output fall 10 percentage points more, and the price of nontradables falls 8 percentage points more. However, agents build a large stock of precautionary savings, worth about 35 percent of GDP in terms of the mean net foreign asset position, and with this “war chest” the long-run probability of binding credit constraints is only about 1/3 of a percent.This model features offsetting supply-side effects. On one hand, labor demand falls when negative shocks hit the value of the marginal product of labor either directly (as a productivity shock) or indirectly (as a fall in the price of nontradables).4 On the other hand, if these negative shocks trigger the credit constraint, the marginal gain of labor supply increases because agents know that extra labor income allows them to borrow more. This second effect dominates at very high debt levels (i.e., with a very tight credit constraint), producing increases in output, labor, and the nontradables price. Because of precautionary savings, however, these very high debt states have zero long-run probability.B. Debt-Deflation Mechanics in Global Asset TradingThe debt-deflation spiral can affect asset prices if the collateral constraints affecting some agents coexist with trading frictions that produce a less-than-infinitely-elastic demand for assets from other agents. This is so that agents that hit collateral constraints and fire-sale assets in efforts to “meet margin calls,” trade with agents that have downward-slopping asset demand curves. Asset prices therefore fall, and as they do the collateral constraint tightens further, setting the debt-deflation mechanism in motion (and magnifying the direct and indirect asset pricing effects of collateral constraints). If the agents fire-selling assets could trade in a frictionless, competitive market, in which market demand is infinitely elastic at the fundamentals price q f t (i.e., the expected present value of dividends discounted at the world interest rate), asset prices cannot fall and the debt-deflation mechanism does not function.Mendoza and Smith (2006) model the asset trading friction as trading costs incurred by foreign securities firms, which may include conventional trading costs as well as costs due to informational, institutional or other intangible frictions. Mendoza and Smith study a two-agent equilibrium asset pricing setup in which domestic agents face the Aiyagari-Gertler margin constraint b t+1 ≥-κq t αt+1k . Explicit lending on margin takes place mainly amongst investors in securities markets, and regulators also impose statutory margin requirements. In addition, widely-used risk management tools (e.g. value-at-risk collateralization) operate as implicit margin requirements by making creditors sell assets and cut credit when systemic shocks increase market volatility, resulting in even higher volatility and further asset sales. Foreign traders incur trading costs also of the Aiyagari-Gertler form:()()2**12t t t a q ααθ+−+, where a is a trading cost coefficient and θ represents costs paid regardless of trading activity. This setup produces a closed-form solution for the foreign traders’ demand function: ()()()**111f t t t t a q q ααθ+⎡⎤−=−−⎢⎥⎣⎦. Thus, the foreign traders’ demand elasticity with respect to the percent deviation of q f t from q t is 1/a .Mendoza and Smith calibrate the model to Mexican data and show that it can produce Sudden Stops as endogenous responses to productivity shocks of standard size when: (a) agents are sufficiently leveraged (i.e., when the ratio of debt to the market value of assets is sufficiently high), and (b) the asset market is relatively liquid (i.e., when short-selling limits are not binding).5 The ability of the model to yield asset price collapses hinges, however, on the foreign traders’ demand being sufficiently inelastic.Figure 2 shows the model’s conditional impulse responses (or, to be precise, conditional forecast functions of the nonlinear equilibrium Markov processes) to a one-standard-deviation, negative TFP shock when the liquidity and leverage conditions that yield a Sudden Stop are satisfied. The Figure showssimulations for an elasticity of 0.5 in the demand of foreign traders. Relative to the outcome with perfect credit markets, consumption collapses 8 percentage points more, the current account increases by 6 percentage points of GDP more, and asset prices decline by 8 percentage points more. Thus, the debt-deflation mechanism induces significant amplification effects. Moreover, the effects on consumption and the current account persist for several periods.The size of the trading costs predicted by the model can be assessed by examining total trading costs in percent of quarterly equity returns. Trading costs are negligible, at less than 1/5 of a percent of returns, when the collateral constraint does not bind, but they rise rapidly as the leverage ratio rises inside the Sudden Stop region (i.e., in the region of the state space where the constraint binds), peaking at about 6.4 percent of returns. Mendoza and Smith (2006) document findings from the finance literature suggesting that costs of this magnitude are in line with empirical evidence.C. The Debt-Deflation Mechanism in an Equilibrium Business Cycle ModelThe models reviewed in A. and B. are incomplete business cycle models because they abstract from capital accumulation and make strong simplifying assumptions about the supply-side of the economy (in Mendoza and Smith (2006), for example, output is unaffected by credit frictions and responds to TFP shocks just like in a frictionless economy). Mendoza (2005a) examines a business cycle model with the ≥-κq t k t+1 and a constraint limiting working capital financing to the fraction κf of collateral constraint bt+1sales. Chari et al. (2005) claim that these are subtle constraints for which there is little direct evidence. Firm-level data show, however, that corporate leverage ratios rise sharply in the run up to Sudden Stops, and collapse abruptly in the aftermath (see Figure 3). There are also extensive accounts of the role played by highly leveraged agents in these events (in the famous case of the Russian crisis, massive margin calls on these agents reached even U.S. capital markets and led the Federal Reserve to lower interest rates).In Mendoza’s (2005a) model, firms use working capital to pay for a fraction φ of the cost of imported inputs, for which they pay a world-determined price, and for costs of capacity utilization. Firms also face capital adjustment costs, so they feature a demand for investment (or supply of equity) that rises with the price of capital (i.e., Tobin’s Q). This is the trading friction that makes agents selling assets to keep up with collateral constraints interact with agents that buy equity only if the price falls. When Tobin’s Q falls as a result of the debt-deflation mechanism, it brings down investment, and with it future capital, output and wealth.Mendoza (2005a) calibrates the model to quarterly Mexican data for the period 1993:1-2004:4. The model includes shocks to R (the real rate on 90-day U.S. T-bills), shocks to the relative price of imported inputs, and TFP shocks. The latter are estimated using a production function for gross output that includes imported inputs and variable capital utilization, so as to correct for the bias affecting Solow residuals. Agents form their expectations using the stochastic process for these shocks taken from the data, without any large, unexpected shocks.The results show that the key findings of the other debt-deflation models extend to the business cycle model: The debt-deflation mechanism is a powerful vehicle for inducing amplification, asymmetry and persistence in the response of real variables to exogenous shocks of “typical” size. Sudden Stops occur when households and firms have debts large enough for the credit constraints to bind, and these high-debt states are reached with positive probability in the stochastic stationary state. Precautionary saving rules out the “largest” Sudden Stops and results in a long-run probability of binding collateral constraints of 1.7 percent (low but significantly higher than in the liability dollarization and asset trading economies)Sudden Stops occur in the model even if the limit on working capital never binds. Starting from a positive-probability Sudden Stop state where the collateral constraint binds and with κf high enough so that χt=0 always, the model predicts the following impact effects relative to the economy with perfect credit markets: an excess current account reversal of 6 percentage points of GDP, and excess drop in。

相关文档
最新文档