学术论文写作范例

合集下载

标准的学术论文范文(汇总35篇)

标准的学术论文范文(汇总35篇)

标准的学术论文范文(汇总35篇)为了进行管理创新,很多企业建立了研发实验室,或者制定了明确的创新目标。

但是有多少企业专门建立一个组织结构来培养管理创新呢?要成为一个管理创新者,首先要做的就是向整个组织推销创新的观念。

当面临一个困难时,员工的反应是怎样的呢?他们是会借助以前标准的解决方法,还是会深入的了解问题,努力寻找新的解决方法。

当然最后一条路才会将公司引向成功的管理创新,管理者应该鼓励员工寻找新的解决问题的方法,而不是选择逃避问题。

寻求不同环境中的类比和例证。

企业应该向社会体系学习,如议会民主制度,可以让员工在讨论中发现不足并提高自己,企业也可以鼓励员工去参加一些志愿活动。

鼓励员工去不同的国家工作也非常的有价值,开拓视野激发思维。

要持续的进行管理创新的实施。

真正的成功者绝不是仅仅进行一两次的管理创新。

他们是持续的管理创新者。

现实生活中有很多成功的典范,通用电器就是一个例子。

它不仅成名于其“群策群力”原则和无边界组织,还拥有很多更为古老的创新,例如战略计划、管理人员发展计划、研发的商业化等,这些古老的创新通用电器一直在执行,所以通用公司一直发展的很好。

所以创新管理不是一朝一夕就能见成效的。

现代社会中机械电子工程的特点十九世纪末到二十世纪以来科学技术得到了飞速的发展,在这个时期里很多学科都得到了提高和补充,学科间的关系也越来越密切,一系列利好因素的共同作用下,机械电子工程学得以产生并发展。

顾名思义,机械电子工程就是电子信息技术与传统的机械技术的一个结合,充分的发挥了两个不同学科在技术上的共同点,达到了物理上和信息功能上的连结。

这是一个跨学科的尝试,更是一个挑战,它可以将所有的机械工程信息进行分析,达到智能化的目的。

虽然依旧属于机械工程行业,但是显然已经拥有了自己的特点。

1)不同的设计方法机械电子工程与传统工程相比,已经不是单一的一个学科,它已经发展成为了有很多技术和科学共同组成的一个新学科,并且在工程设计上充分的吸纳了信息技术、机械技术,并为了使工程的各模块结构布局更加完整,设计人员一般都会采取自上而下的设计方法。

学术研究论文写作技巧模板

学术研究论文写作技巧模板

学术研究论文写作技巧模板在学术领域,撰写一篇优秀的研究论文是每位研究人员都要面对的挑战。

本文将介绍一些撰写学术研究论文的技巧,帮助您更好地组织和表达研究成果。

一、引言部分学术研究论文的引言部分起到承上启下的作用,用于引出研究问题、解释研究目的和意义。

在引言部分,您可以按照以下结构组织内容:1. 研究背景和意义:简要介绍研究背景,引出研究问题,并说明研究的重要性和意义。

2. 相关研究综述:回顾与您的研究相关的前人研究成果和存在的问题,并指出本研究的创新点和差异之处。

3. 研究目的和研究问题:明确您的研究目的,并列举研究问题,以引出您的研究方法和研究内容。

二、研究方法部分在研究方法部分,您需要详细描述您所采用的研究方法和实验设计。

在这一部分,您可以按照以下格式组织内容:1. 研究设计:说明您的研究是实验研究、调查研究还是文献综述等,并解释您设计该研究的理由和依据。

2. 研究对象和样本:描述您研究的对象或对象群体,并解释您选择该对象的理由。

同时,说明样本的选择过程和标准。

3. 数据收集方法:介绍您采集数据的具体方法和工具,例如问卷调查、实验记录等。

4. 数据分析方法:展示您使用的数据分析方法,例如统计分析、回归分析等。

三、研究结果部分研究结果部分是论文的核心,您需要清晰地陈述您的研究结果,并用适当的表格、图表或图像来展示数据。

遵循以下结构可以使您的研究结果更加清晰明了:1. 结果总览:简要总结您的研究结果,给读者一个整体认识。

2. 文字描述结果:通过文字描述详细介绍您的研究结果,可以使用段落或编号方式。

3. 图表展示结果:用适当的图表或图像展示您的数据结果,注意图表的清晰度和易读性。

四、讨论与结论部分讨论与结论部分是对研究结果进行解读和总结的部分,也是给读者留下深刻印象的关键部分。

总结您的讨论与结论部分时,考虑以下内容:1. 结果解读:对研究结果进行解读,将其与前人研究成果进行对比和分析。

2. 研究局限和不足:指出研究中存在的局限和不足之处,避免过于绝对的表述。

有引言的论文范例

有引言的论文范例

有引言的论文范例摘要:本文通过对不同学科领域中具有代表性的论文进行分析,呈现了多个包含引言部分的论文范例,旨在揭示引言在论文中的重要作用以及其常见的结构和写作要点,为学术写作者提供有益的参考。

关键词:论文;引言;写作技巧在学术研究的广袤领域中,一篇优秀的论文犹如一座精心构建的大厦,而引言则是这座大厦的基石和引路人。

引言不仅为读者开启了了解研究主题的大门,还为后续的论述奠定了坚实的基础。

下面我们将通过具体的范例来深入探讨有引言的论文的魅力所在。

范例一:《关于新型能源开发与可持续发展的研究》在全球能源危机日益严峻的背景下,新型能源的开发成为了各国关注的焦点。

能源的可持续供应对于经济的稳定增长、环境保护以及社会的可持续发展都具有至关重要的意义。

本研究旨在探索新型能源开发的潜力和途径,以应对传统能源逐渐枯竭所带来的挑战。

通过对太阳能、风能、水能等多种新型能源的技术分析和市场调研,我们期望为能源领域的发展提供新的思路和策略。

过往的研究在新型能源的某些方面取得了一定的成果,但仍存在诸多不足。

例如,对于新型能源转化效率的提升研究不够深入,相关技术的成本控制也有待进一步优化。

本研究将采用先进的实验方法和数据分析手段,对新型能源的开发进行全面而系统的研究。

同时,结合实际案例和市场需求,提出具有可操作性的建议和方案。

范例二:《数字化教育对学生学习效果的影响研究》随着信息技术的飞速发展,数字化教育在教育领域的应用日益广泛。

数字化教育以其独特的优势,如个性化学习、丰富的资源共享和便捷的交互方式,正逐渐改变着传统的教育模式。

然而,数字化教育在带来诸多便利的同时,也引发了一系列问题。

例如,部分学生可能过度依赖数字化工具而忽视了自主思考能力的培养,网络环境的不稳定可能影响学习的连续性等。

本研究旨在深入探讨数字化教育对学生学习效果的具体影响,包括学习成绩的提升、学习兴趣的激发以及学习能力的培养等方面。

通过对不同地区、不同年龄段学生的调查和分析,我们期望能够为教育工作者和决策者提供有益的参考,以优化数字化教育的实施策略。

学术论文摘要应用文写作范文精选

学术论文摘要应用文写作范文精选

学术论文摘要应用文写作范文精选
摘要是学术论文的重要组成部分,具有概括论文主要内容、突出论文贡献和吸引读者继续阅读的作用。

下面是一些学术论文摘要的写作范文精选,供参考。

范文一:(标题)
研究区域:XXX
关键词:XXX,XXX,XXX
本文研究了XXX的XXX,通过XXX,对于XXX的XXX进行了XXX分析。

结果表明XXX对于XXX起到了重要作用,这一发现对于XXX具有重要意义。

范文二:(标题)
研究区域:XXX
关键词:XXX,XXX,XXX
本文针对XXX进行了XXX的研究,通过XXX,对于XXX 的XXX进行了探讨。

实验证明了XXX的有效性,并且对于XXX 的改进具有重要意义。

范文三:(标题)
研究区域:XXX
关键词:XXX,XXX,XXX
本文探讨了XXX在XXX方面的应用,通过XXX,对于XXX 的XXX进行了评估。

结果显示XXX在XXX方面具有潜在的应用前景,并且为XXX提供了重要参考。

范文四:(标题)
研究区域:XXX
关键词:XXX,XXX,XXX
本文通过XXX对于XXX进行了研究,发现XXX对于XXX 具有重要作用。

这一研究结果为XXX提供了新的思路和方法,对于XXX的发展具有重要意义。

以上是一些学术论文摘要的写作范文精选,供参考使用。

在写作摘要时,可以结合自己的研究内容和成果,突出研究的特点和创新,同时简明扼要地介绍研究方法和主要结果,吸引读者进一步阅读论文。

(字数:XXX)。

学术论文范文

学术论文范文

学术论文范文学术论文范文(以下为文章内容示例,实际字数可能有所增加):在学术界,论文是一种重要的文献形式,被广泛用于学术交流、知识分享和科学研究。

一篇优质的学术论文应当具备清晰的结构、准确的论证和可靠的数据支持。

本文将以某学科领域的研究为例,展示一篇学术论文范文的写作过程,以供参考。

1. 引言在学术论文中,引言部分通常用于阐述研究的背景、研究问题的重要性和研究的目的。

同时,还需要引用相关文献来支持自己的观点。

例如,本研究将聚焦于气候变化对农作物产量的影响,并介绍了国内外学者在此领域的研究成果。

2. 文献综述文献综述部分是对已有研究成果的概述和分析,旨在展示个人的学术研究立场和对研究前景的认识。

文献综述可以按主题或时间顺序组织,分析现有研究的差距和不足,并提出本文研究的创新点。

例如,在气候变化对农作物产量的影响研究中,可以综述不同气象条件下的农作物适应性和生长表现,指出现有研究存在的不足,如缺乏长期观测数据或对不同地理区域农作物的系统分析。

3. 研究方法研究方法部分描述了研究者采用的实验设计、数据收集和数据分析方法。

研究方法的描述应当具体、清晰,以便读者能够重复实验并验证结果。

例如,在本文的研究中,我们采用了长期观测数据,并利用回归分析方法来研究气候因素对农作物产量的影响,从而得出准确的结果。

4. 结果和讨论结果和讨论部分展示了研究者通过实验和数据分析所得到的结果,并对结果进行解读和分析。

此部分应当与研究目的和研究问题相关,并围绕主题进行逻辑组织。

例如,本研究发现气候变暖对小麦产量的影响与区域差异密切相关,高温对南方产量影响更大,而降水对北方产量影响更大。

5. 结论结论部分对整个研究进行总结,并简明扼要地回答研究问题。

结论应该简明扼要,并且有所启发,为读者提供新的思路或者解决问题的方向。

例如,本研究结果表明,气候变化对农作物产量有重要影响,应当采取相应的适应措施来应对这一挑战。

6. 参考文献参考文献部分列出了在论文中所引用的所有来源。

学术论文写作范例

学术论文写作范例

学术论文写作范例在学术领域中,撰写一篇优秀的学术论文是学者们必须掌握的技能之一。

本文旨在提供一个学术论文写作范例,以帮助读者理解如何合理组织文档结构、提出观点和支撑论证,并以清晰、精确的语句表达思想。

一、引言部分引言部分是学术论文的开篇之处,它应该能够吸引读者的注意并简要介绍研究主题。

首先,需要提出一个有趣的研究问题或主题,以引起读者的兴趣。

接着,应该概述相关研究的现状和研究领域的重要性,从而凸显这项研究的意义。

最后,明确本文的研究目的和研究方法,为接下来的论证做铺垫。

二、文献综述文献综述部分需要对相关研究进行综合评述,以展示当前该领域已有研究和理论框架。

可以按主题和时间顺序进行组织,分别介绍不同领域的研究成果,并提出其中存在的问题。

可以引用过去研究的结论和观点,同时分析其优缺点,为接下来的研究提供参考。

三、方法研究方法部分需要详细描述研究的方法和过程。

首先,需要明确研究的范围和目标,然后介绍采用的研究方法。

例如,如果是实证研究,可以描述实验设计、样本收集和数据分析方法。

如果是理论研究,可以阐述采用的文献分析和理论推导方法。

此外,还需要讨论可能存在的局限性,并提出如何解决这些问题的建议。

四、结果与讨论结果与讨论部分是整个论文的核心,需要清晰地呈现研究结果,并对结果进行详细的分析和解释。

可以使用统计图表、表格等形式展示数据,并比较不同实验组之间的差异。

在分析结果时,要注意与前人研究的对比和相似之处,并结合相关理论解释结果的原因和意义。

此外,还可以讨论实验中可能存在的误差来源和结论的可靠性。

五、结论与展望结论部分需要对整个研究进行总结,并回答引言中提出的研究问题。

要简明扼要地总结研究的主要发现和贡献,并指出研究结果对相关领域的影响和意义。

在展望方面,可以提出研究的局限性并提出未来进一步研究的建议,以推动该领域的发展。

以上是一篇学术论文写作的范例,希望能够为读者提供一些有关论文结构和内容安排的指导。

在实际写作中,需要根据具体的研究主题和要求进行调整。

论文范文(4篇)

论文范文(4篇)

论文范文(4篇)在学术领域写论文是一项重要的任务,研究生甚至本科生都需要撰写一定数量的论文才能毕业。

对于许多人来说,写论文是一项挑战,因为需要具备良好的研究技能、写作能力和时间管理技能。

因此,在这篇文章中,我将提供四篇不同类型的论文范文,以便读者获得写好论文所需的基础知识和灵感。

一. 实验报告范文实验报告通常由四个主要部分组成:引言、方法、结果和讨论。

以下是一份关于“水的沸点实验”的实验报告范文:引言本次实验的目标是确定水的沸点。

沸点指的是液体从液相向气相转化所需的温度,在大气压力下,水沸点约为100°C(212°F)。

确定水的沸点非常重要,因为它是许多日常生活及工业过程中必需的参数。

因此,本实验将探讨如何通过简单的实验来确定水的沸点。

方法为了测量水的沸点,我们利用了一台实验室专用的销售式口炉,该口炉可以提供均匀且高效的加热作用。

我们采用了以下方法来测量水的沸点:1. 把100毫升纯净水倒入烧杯中。

2. 把温度计插入水中,确保水的表面和温度计测量的是同一温度。

3. 放置水的烧杯和温度计在口炉上。

4. 打开口炉,并把口炉调到最高温度设置,等待水沸腾。

5. 当水开始沸腾并呈现大气压下最高温度时,记录温度计示数,并记录时间。

6. 重复三次实验并计算平均沸点。

结果我们进行了三次实验并记录了以下结果:第一次实验:100.2°C第二次实验:100.1°C第三次实验:99.9°C平均沸点为100.1°C。

我们还计算出了每次实验的偏差,结果偏差很小,可接受。

讨论通过此次实验,我们成功测量了纯净水的沸点,并得出了100.1°C 的平均值。

尽管我们采取了一些措施降低实验误差,如三次重复实验并计算均值,但我们无法排除实验偏差的可能性。

我们在实验过程中使用的烧杯可能不够精确,或者在读取温度时存在误差。

这需要在未来的实验中获得更为精确的数据。

二. 综述论文范文综述论文旨在评估过去几十年来某一特定领域的研究与发展情况,并总结对该领域未来的影响。

学术期刊的论文格式

学术期刊的论文格式

学术期刊的论文格式篇一:学术论文标准格式学术论文标准格式一、作者简介顺序:姓名(出生年- ),性别,籍贯,单位,职称,学位,主要研究方向。

二、摘要:100-150字,应具有独立性和自含性,直接提出主要观点,概括主要内容,不加评论和补充解释。

三、关键词:3-5个,名词性术语。

四、正文各级标题层次为:一、(二)3. (4)五、凡引文出处一律列入文末“参考文献”,编排格式如下:(一)著作:[序号]作者.书名[M].出版地:出版者,出版年.起止页码(任选).(二)期刊:[序号]作者.篇名[J].刊名,年,卷(期):起止页码.(三)报纸:[序号]作者.篇名[N].报纸名,出版日期(版次).(四)文中引文序号与文末“参考文献”序号相对应,用上标方括号[ ] 。

(五)同一文献只能用一个序号,不同页码用括号标在文中序号后,如[1](P3)。

[1]著作类格式一,示例:W. 施太格缪勒. 当代哲学主流(下卷)[M]. 北京:商务印书馆,2000.著作类格式二(不必标明著作者),示例:马克思恩格斯全集(第1卷)[M]. 北京:人民出版社,1972.[2]期刊类格式一,示例:章培恒. 关于中国现代文学的开端——兼及“近代文学”问题[J]. 复旦学报(社会科学版),2001(2).期刊类格式二(两个以上作者),示例:曹凤岐、姜华东. 中国发展股指期货研究[J]. 北京大学学报(哲学社会科学版),2003(6).[3]文集类格式一,示例:邓小平文选(第二卷)[C]. 北京:人民出版社,1994. 文集类格式二(析出文献),示例:[美]哈耶克. 建构主义的错误[A]. 经济、科学与政治[C]. 南京:江苏人民出版社,2000.[4]报纸类格式,示例:谢希德. 创造学习的新思路[N]. 人民日报,1998-12-25(10).[5]电子文献类格式――[序号]主要责任人.电子文献题名[电子文献及载体类型标识]。

示例:王明亮.关于中国学术期刊标准化数据库系统工程的进展[EB/0L].1)中文部分①学术论文题目采用小二号黑体加粗字,章节标题采用小三号黑体加粗字;②作者姓名、通讯地址、摘要、关键词、正文(除章节标题外)均使用小四号宋体字,其中“摘要”、“关键词”两个词加方括号加粗;③“参考文献”采用小四号黑体加粗字,参考文献的具体内容用小四号仿宋字。

  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIESTHE REAL EXCHANGE RATE, MERCANTILISM AND THE LEARNING BY DOINGEXTERNALITYJoshua AizenmanJaewoo LeeWorking Paper 13853/papers/w13853NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH1050 Massachusetts AvenueCambridge, MA 02138March 2008Any views expressed herein are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications.© 2008 by Joshua Aizenman and Jaewoo Lee. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.The Real Exchange Rate, Mercantilism and the Learning by Doing ExternalityJoshua Aizenman and Jaewoo LeeNBER Working Paper No. 13853March 2008JEL No. F13,F15,F31,F43ABSTRACTThis paper examines the degree to which the learning by doing externality [LBD] calls for an undervalued exchange rate, a policy suggested by recent empirical studies which concluded that mildly undervalued real exchange rate may enhance growth. We obtain mixed results. For an economy where LBD externality operates in the traded sector, real exchange rate undervaluation may be used in order to internalize this externality, if the LBD calls for subsidizing employment in the traded sector. Yet, we also find that these results are not robust to changes in the nature of the LBD externality. If the LBD externality is embodied in aggregate investment, the optimal policy calls for subsidizing the cost of capital in the traded sector, and there is no room for undervalued exchange rate policy. In addition, a deliberate undervaluation by means of hoarding reserves may backfire if the needed sterilization would increase the cost of investment in the traded sector.Joshua AizenmanDepartment of Economics; E21156 High St.University of California, Santa CruzSanta Cruz, CA 95064and NBERjaizen@Jaewoo LeeResearch DepartmentInternational Monetary FundWashington DC, 20431jlee3@The remarkable takeoff in the hoarding of international reserves by developing countries has been the focus of growing attention and controversies. A casual inspection of the International reserves/GDP ratio trends depicted in Figure 1, and the pattern of hoarding reserves by China in Figure 2, reveals that the hoarding trend from 2001 has been driven mostly by China. Chinese international reserves were stable in the aftermath of the East Asian 1997-8 crisis, but took off at an accelerated speed after 2001, more than quadrupled in five years [2001-2006], reaching by now about 1500 billion dollar. Within this time frame, Chinese international reserves/GDP almost tripled from a relatively high initial level of 15%. Noting the decline in the growth rate of China in the late 1990s, followed by a substantially higher growth rate in the 2000s, some observers attribute the accelerated hoarding of reserves after 2001 to an export led growth policy supported by mercantilist hoarding of reserves. According to this view, hoarding reserves encourages exports by mitigating or preventing the real exchange rate appreciation that would have occurred under a fully flexible exchange rate system. Indeed, hoarding international reserves has been advocated by Dooley et al. (2004) as a key ingredient of the export-led growth strategy of China. Yet, Aizenman and Lee (2006) noted that such a policy may also reflect competitive hoarding among emerging markets, attempting to preserve their market share in the US and other OECD countries. Modeling this situation in a version of Johnson’s tariff game suggests that a country with the lowest cost of sterilization (arguably China), may be the winner of such a game, resulting with “beggar thy neighbor” outcome. The losers on such a game [arguably Korea, Japan, etc.] would keep hoarding reserves to minimize their losses, and will invest directly in China to mitigate their competitive losses. These results are consistent with Figure 3, indicating the acceleration of FDI from Japan and Korea to China from 2001, coinciding with the takeoff of Chinese hoarding of international reserves.Econometric support for the negative effects of overvaluation on growth have been found by Dollar (1992), Razin and Collins (1999) and others. More recently, Aguirre and Calderón (2005) found that RER misalignments hinder growth but the effect is non-linear: growth declines are larger, the larger the size of the misalignments. Although large undervaluations hurt growth, small to moderate undervaluations enhance growth. [See also Johnson and others (2007).] Overviewing this literature, Prasad et al.(2007) point out that overvaluation is frequently the outcome of real factors, like demographic aspects determining the supply of labor, the domestic supply of capital and the inflow of foreign capital, fiscal policy, etc.A drawback of the above literature is that it presumed that export led growth strategy requires a policy of undervalued exchange rate, without explaining the potential market failure that is addressed by undervaluation or the hoarding of international reserves. This issue is of obvious relevance for understanding East Asia – Aizenman and Lee (2006) pointed out that mercantilist hoarding of reserves is a relatively new phenomenon in East Asia, and that, during the fast growth phases, Japan (prior to 1992) and Korea (prior to 1997) refrained from an aggressive hoarding of reserves. Instead, Japan and Korea frequently encouraged export-led growth by subsidizing selectively the cost of capital in outward oriented activities, at a cost of reducing the quality of banks’ balance sheet. Consequently, there may be various ways of achieving the objective of export-led growth, and one needs to understand the conditions underpinning the desire to subsidize export led growth in order to better understand the policy choices confronting East Asian countries. While the presumption of Dooley et al. (2005) has been that hoarding international reserves by China is a win-win strategy, our approach is more agnostic, viewing it as the outcome of non cooperative interaction among countries, where some may be adversely affected.The purpose of the present paper is to model the circumstances that would lead to the export led growth drive, and to study the challenges associated with implementing such a policy. We model an economy populated by agents consuming non traded and traded goods. The non traded is the “traditional” good, produced only by labor, whereas the traded, dubbed manufacturing, is produced by labor and capital, also being subject to the learning by doing [dubbed LBD] externality. Specifically, the productivity of the atomistic firm in the traded sector is determined by the “stock” of experience gained from past aggregate production of the traded good.1 We focus on the implications of the LBD1See Krugman (1987), Young (1991), Ambler, Cardia and Farazli (1999) and Leahy and Neary (1999) for earlier studies dealing with the impact of policies in the presence of learning by doing.externality on the conduct of policies, and the robustness of the results to the nature of the LBD externality.1. Basic Model :We consider a real model, where the periodic utility is(1) ()()1t Nt Xt U C C γγ−=where N C and X C are the consumption of the non traded and the traded goods at time t.The subjective discount factor is β. The traded sector, dubbed manufacturing, is produced by a large number of competitive firms, q , and is subject to the learning by doing externality. Aggregate manufacturing output is(2)()()1,,,t t r x t r t X q A L K αα−= ;where index r refers to the reprehensive firm in manufacturing, employing ,,r x t L ,,r t K labor and capital at time t, respectively. To simplify exposition, we assume that capital is subject to full depreciation within a period, and that the traded good invested at time t provides the stock of capital stock at time t+1. The non traded good is the tradition sector, produced using a Ricardian technology .,.n t r x t L L qL =− , where the aggregate supply of labor is L .The productivity index A is affected by learning by doing: today’s aggregateproduction increases future productivity by the experience and the know-how learned today. We assume that this effect is subject to depreciation overtime. Specifically, we assume that A increases with the lagged aggregate discounted output:(3) 12;...;0t t t t t A c X X εφδε−−=ΩΩ=+++≥,and 01δ<≤ is the depreciation rate of the LBD stock, t Ω. The number of firms, q , is large enough such that the learning by doing is external to each firm.The main effects of the LBD externality are illustrated clearly in a two period example (t = 1, 2), where the stock of capital in period 1 is given by history, and productivity is normalized to ()1211;1A A X ε==+. Consider the planner’s problem for the case where the investment is self financed, i.e. where we assume first a balanced current account. Since the consumption and the production are identical for both traded and nontraded goods (Xt t C X = and Nt t C N =), the planner’s problem is:(4) 11,,1,,1,1,211,,1,,2,2,,21,,2,2(){()()}1;;(){([1])()}1r x r x r r r x r x r r x r x r L qL q L K qK MAX L L K L qL q X L K γααγγεααγβ−−−−⎡⎤−−+⎢⎥⎢⎥−+⎢⎥+⎣⎦.The first order conditions can be reduced to(5a)1112,1,,1,,11,21:(1)11x r x r x r U X U U L qL qL X qK X γεααγβ⎡⎤=−+⎢⎥−−++⎢⎥⎣⎦; (5b)1221,2,2(1)(1)(1):1r r U U K X qK qK γγαβ−−−=−+; (5c)22,2,2,2,2(1):(1);[(1)]x x x x U U L L hence L qL qL q γαγαγγαγ−=−=−+−.From which we infer that(6) ,,1,2|0|00;0r x r dL dK d d εεεε==>>The following table summarizes a simulation, tracing the optimal employment for the case where 16,10,0.4,0.02,0.7,0.05L q K γβα======.,,1,,2,2,1,1,1;;;/r x r x r n n x L L K p P P =ε = 00.35 0.31 0.05 0.34ε = 0.2 0.38 0.31 0.065 0.316ε = 0.40.415 0.31 0.082 0.29Table 1 LBD externality and optimal employment and investment, a two period exampleThe LBD externality increases the total marginal product of labor, increasing thereby the optimal first period employment. The resultant higher second period productivityincreases the optimal capital. As the second period is the end of the planning horizon, the LBD externality is not impacting the second period employment patterns. This is an artifact of the two-period horizon, and will be shown not to hold if one extends the model’s horizon.Despite its effects on the level of employment and production, however, the LBD externality has no direct effect on the socially optimal level of trade surplus. Trade imbalance, or foreign lending and borrowing, can be introduced by variable t F which denotes the stock of net foreign assets at the beginning (end) of period t (t-1). *1(1)()()t t t Xt Nt t Nt t F r F X C P N C I +=++−+−−where t I is the investment. In the two-period case, the net foreign assets at the end of period 2 would be optimally zero, and we assume the initial net foreign assets (at the beginning of period 1) to be zero. We can then write consumer’s problem as follows.11,,1,,1,1,221*1,,1,,2,2,,21,,2,22(){()()}1;;(){([1])()(1)}1r x r x r r r x r x r r x r x r L qL q L K qK F MAX L L K L qL q X L K r F γααγγεααγβ−−−−⎡⎤−−−+⎢⎥⎢⎥−+++⎢⎥+⎣⎦We can see that the LBD externality has no effect of increasing trade surplus. The first-order condition is: 1211U r U β∗+=⎛⎞⎜⎟+⎝⎠.This is the condition that is familiar from the standard intertemporal model of current account, according to which an economy borrows or lends to equate the intertemporal rate of substitution to the international rate of interest.The strength of LBD externality thus has no direct effect on the level of tradesurplus or deficit, and has an indirect effect by changing the incentive for intertemporal trade. The effect can be in the direction that a strong LBD externality would increase the incentive to borrow in the earlier period before the LBD externality has not materialized in the form of a high productivity. A strong LBD externality implies that, ceteris paribus, the output in later periods are higher because of a higher productivity. The economy in the initial periods is therefore looking forward to later periods of higher output, and thus would like to borrow to fund a higher consumption.In the rest of the paper, we flash out the policy implications of the LBDexternality on the basis of the balanced-trade assumption. We have seen that a strong LBD externality does not sway one way or the other, the trade surplus in the early phase of economic growth. This implication is broadly consistent with the growth experience of Japan and Korea, neither of which had particularly large current account or tradesurpluses during their early years of economic growth (except in years of macroeconomic crises). In both countries, massive reserve accumulation had come around in later stages of growth, following crisis-driven economic slowdown [Aizenman and Lee (2006)].2. Policy Implications :To explore the implication of the LBD externality on the real exchange rate, we write the consumer’s FOCs as:(7) 1,1,1,,1N n r x U MU p qL γ==−; 1,,11,2(1)1r X r U MU X qK γ−==−; 2,,22(1)1r X U MU X γ−== where ,1n p is the real exchange rate, defined by the relative price of non traded to traded goods [hence, our numeraire is the traded good]. Applying (7) to (5a), and the observation that firm’s marginal product of labor is 11,1,1,1()x L r r dX dX MP d qL qL α==, we infer that the FOC, (5a-c) can be rewritten as(8a)22,1,1,112[1][1]x x n L L dX X p MP MP dX αε=+=+Ω. (8b) 21K MP β+=.(8c),2,2x n L p MP =.The FOC condition for the socially optimal first period employment equates the value of the marginal produce of labor in the non traded sector [= the real exchange rate] with the value of the social marginal product of labor in the traded sector [the RHS of (8a)]. The employment under a competitive equilibrium corresponds to a similar FOC, where the learning by doing externality is ignored (corresponding to ε = 0). Hence, optimality calls for subsidizing employment in the traded sector, and is consistent with an undervalued real exchange rate. The subsidy internalizes LBD externality, and applies as long as the learning by doing is external to the firm.In a short digression, note that if there were uncertainty about the degree to which the authorities would adopt the policies called by the LBD externalities, the earlyinvestors would enjoy a windfall gains following the adaptation of these policies. This follows from the observation that gross rent per unit of capital in the first period increases with the labor/capital ratio [note that 11,1,,1,1,,1(1)()()/(1)(/)r x r r x r K L K L K ααααα−−=− ]. Hence, a policy that would reduce the cost of labor in period one would increase the rent of installed capital -- the prospect of adopting the policy that would internalize theexternality in period 1 has the effect of increasing the rent to the capital invested in period zero, 1K . Our discussion can be extended to the case where capital depreciates overtime. In these circumstances, anticipation of the gains associated with adopting future polices that would internalize the LBD externality may induce potentially large inflows of FDI at early stages of the development process, even if the present fundamentals are mixed.The above example provides a strong case for real exchange undervaluation. Yet, this result hinges on the nature of the LBD externality. To gain further insight, we review now several extensions dealing with the planning horizon and the nature of the LBD externality.We first extend the model to a three period horizon, focusing on the planner’s problem in period one, setting the investment determining the stock of capital in period two, and the optimal first period employment:(9)1,,1,1,21,,112,,2,2,32,,2,,1,,2,,2,2,313,333,22()()1{()()};;;;11{()()}(1)r x r r r x r x r r r x r x r x r x r r x x q L K qK w qL MAX q A L K qK w qL L L L K K q A L K w qL ααααααββ−−−⎡⎤⎢⎥−−+⎢⎥⎢⎥−−+⎢⎥+⎢⎥⎢⎥−⎢⎥+⎢⎥⎣⎦.The FOC characterizing the first period decisions are:(10) 23321,121213,22111[1(1)11(1)11[1]1x L K X X X w MP X X X X MP X βββββ∂∂∂=++++∂+∂+∂∂+=++∂; Alternatively,(10’) 23321,122333,231[1(1)]11(1)1[1]1x L K X X X w MP X MP αεαεδαεβββαεββ=++++Ω+Ω+Ω+=++Ω.The firm’s FOC is a special case of (10’), where ε = 0. Hence, optimality calls for subsidizing both employment and investment in the traded sector, at a rate that increases with the LBD externality. Note that extending the planning horizon implies that, with the exception of the terminal employment and capital levels, the LBD externality increases the social marginal product of both labor and capital due to the impact of the present output on future productivity.Our discussion can be extended to the case of infinite horizon, where the problem is: (11) 1,,1,1,21,,1,,1,20()();(1)0,1,2...r x j r j r j j r x j r x t r t j j MAX q L K qK w qL L K t ααβ−∞+++++++=⎡⎤⎧⎫−−⎪⎪⎢⎥⎨⎬+⎪⎪⎢⎥⎩⎭⎣⎦=∑Similar FOC applies: the social marginal product of each input is inclusive of the NPV of the marginal impact of firms MP on future productivity:(12)11,1112,11111[1](1)11[1](1)x t j t L t j j t t j K t j j t X w MP X X MP X βββ∞++++=+∞++++=+∂=++∂∂+=++∂∑∑. Note that the LBD externality calls for subsidizing the inputs used in the production of manufacturing, at a rate that increases with the externality, as is reflected by ε. The magnitude of the subsidy to labor and capital differs due to timing issues, as the capital used at time t was invested at t – 1, whereas labor used in time t is hired in the spotmarket. The gap between the optimal subsidy to labor and capital depend negatively on the LBD deprecation rate, δ, and the discount factor, β. In the limiting case, where 0&0βδ→→ , the two subsidies rates are identical.In assessing these results, one should keep in mind the dependence of the optimal policy on the nature of the LBD externality. Suppose that the externality is embodied in the capital, as has been modeled frequently by the endogenous growth literature that followed Romer (1986).2 This would be the case when knowledge creation is a side product of investment, as is when productivity at time t increases with aggregate capital. In terms of our model, the LBD stock at time t would be:(13) ,,111;...;0q q t t t i t i t i i A c K K εφδε−===ΩΩ=+++≥∑∑,where ,1i i q ≤≤ is the index of firms. In these circumstances, optimal policy calls for subsidizing only the cost of capital, and that real exchange rate undervaluation would not deal with this type of LBD externality.3 In contrast, if the LBD externality is embodied in the aggregate employment [i.e., ,,,,111...q q t x i t x i t i i c L L δ−==Ω=+++∑∑], optimal policy callsfor real exchange rate undervaluation instead of subsidizing capital. The endogenous growth literature frequently assumed that the LBD externality is embodied in aggregate investment, apparently due to the more convenient modeling associated with it. Yet, there is no clear empirical evidence that provides support the “aggregate investment”externality instead of an “aggregate production” or “aggregate employment” externalities. We add now rudimentary monetary considerations. Suppose that we start with a configuration of a fixed exchange rate, where the nominal exchange rate is pegged to 1, and the law of one price under which the foreign currency price of the traded good is normalized at 1. We assume that individuals choose to hold domestic currency so as to economize on the transactions costs of exchange associated with producing the GDP, leading to a demand for money 2 This literature frequently assumed that productivity increases with the aggregate capital stock, ,()t i t iA K εφ=∑.3 This follows form the observation that when the LBD externality is given by (3’); the FOC for the optimal employment of capital and labor are:,11211111;1[1](1)x t t t j t L K j j t X w MP MP X ββ++∞++++=+∂=+=++∂∑.(14) ,[]1d t n t t t M k p N X =+ Let the initial supply of money s t M be set to accommodate a given path of production and expenditure, assuring zero balance of payment.Suppose that a shock induces monetary expansion of (1)t s F −, where t F is the original shock [reflecting inflow of capital, favorable trade shock; etc.], and s is the coefficient of sterilization. Hence, the new short run equilibrium at time t is:(15) ,(1)[]s t t n t t t M s F k p N X +−=+.Maintaining the assumption of price and wage flexibility, we infer that 4(16),,,,,0,,,,,///(/)|s n t n tn t t t t s t t n t t n t ts s n t n t n t t t t s t t n t t n t t dp p p N X M dF M kp N p N dp p p N X M ds F kp N p N =+==+=−=−.A monetary disturbance t F induces the real appreciation at a rate that depends inversely on the openness of the economy, as measured by the GDP share of the traded sector. Similarly, sterilization mitigates the real appreciation at a rate that depends inversely on the openness of the economy. This in turn suggests that keeping the real exchange rate at a level that internalizes the LBD externality calls for the sterilization of financial inflows. The sterilization has to be of a real variety, which can keep the real exchange rate at the optimal level and maintain the nominal exchange rate at its peg (assumed to equal 1 in equation (14)). The combination of BOP inflows and offsetting stabilizations can result in the pattern that was or has been observed in several emerging markets. In an effort to sterilize the effect of large BOP inflows—via current or financial account—the4 Note that the envelope theorem implies that ,,[]/0n t t t x t d p N X dL +=, hence we ignore second order GDP effects associated with employment changes induced by the real appreciation.government accumulates large external assets in the form of international reserves. While this sterilization by pumping out BOP inflows continues, the real exchange rate can be maintained at a level that stimulates production and consequent improvement in productivity via the LBD channel.3. DiscussionOur analysis suggests circumstances under which policies promoting sectors characterized by the LBD externality may be desirable. Yet, the details of these policies hinge on the exact nature of this externality, and the quality of the governance which ultimately determines the efficacy of policy intervention. It would be too simplistic to view the successful growth of China as stemming from any deliberate undervalued exchange rate by means of large reserves hoardings. First, similar success stories in East Asia have happened without active hoarding policies. Second, depending on the nature of the LBD externality, it may call for subsidizing the cost of capital, subsidizing the cost of labor, or both. Real exchange rate undervaluation would be the suggested policy only if the LBD externality calls for subsidizing employment in the traded sector, and if this end can’t be accomplished by more effective means. After all, hoarding international reserves is a policy that impacts the stance of monetary policy and the domestic interest rates. Such a policy may backfire if the needed sterilization would lead to markedly higher interest rate, reducing thereby capital accumulation in the traded sector. The adverse financing effects of hoarding reserves are more likely to be larger in countries characterized with shallow financial system, low saving rates, and more costly sterilization; conditions that on balance apply to LATAM. Finally, the adaptation of similar hoarding policies by countries competing in the same third market may lead to competitive hoarding, dissipating the competitive gains of most involved countries [see Aizenman and Lee (2006)]. Yet, hoarding reserves may be an effective short-intermediate run policy dealing with balance of payment effects of shocks whose permanency is not known, like TOT improvements and capital inflows [see Aizenman and Riera-Crichton (2006)].ReferencesAguirre A. and C. Calderón (2005), “Real exchange rate misalignments and economic performance” Working paper 315, Chilean Central Bank.Aizenman J. and J. Lee (2006), "Financial versus Monetary Mercantilism-Long-run View of Large International Reserves Hoarding", forthcoming, The World Economy.Aizenman J. and D. Riera-Crichton (2006), "Real exchange rate and international reserves in the era of growing financial and trade integration," forthcoming, Review of Economics andStatistics.Ambler S., E. Cardia and J. Farazli (1999), “Export promotion, learning by doing and growth,”Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 23, pp. 747-772.Dooley P. M., D. Folkerts-Landau, and P. Garber (2005), “International Financial Stability,”Deutsche Bank, October [at /~mpd/Int%20Fin%20Stab.pdf ]. Dollar, D. (1992), Outward-Oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-1985. Economic Development and Cultural Change40(3), 523-544.Johnson, Simon, Jonathan D. Ostry and Arvind Subramanian (2007), “The Prospects for Sustained Growth in Africa: Benchmarking the Constraints,” IMF Working Paper No.07/52.Krugman, P. (1987), “The narrow moving band, the Dutch disease, and the competitive consequences of Mrs. Thatcher : Notes on trade in the presence of dynamic scaleeconomies” Journal of Development Economics, 27, 1-2, pp. 41-55.Leahy Dermot and Peter Neary, (1999), “Learning by Doing, Precommitment and Infant-Industry Promotion,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 12:3, pp. 435-40.Prasad, E. S., R. G. Rajan, and A. Subramanian (2007), “Foreign Capital and Economic Growth”Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, pp. 153-209.Razin, O., Collins, S.M., 1999. Real Exchange Rate Misalignments and Growth. In: Razin, A.Sadka, E., eds., The Economics of Globalization: Policy Perspectives from PublicEconomics. Cambridge, New York and Melbourne: University Press, pp. 59-81 Romer, P., M. (1986), “Increasing returns and long-run growth,” Journal of Political Economy, 90, pp.1002-1037.Young, A. “Learning by Doing and the Dynamic Effects of International Trade,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1991, pp 369-405.Figure 1IR/GDP ratios, 1980-2006Figure 2IR hoarding in China, 1990-2006FDI into China500010000150002000025000199419951996199719981999200020012002200320042005USD millionFigure 3FDI inflows to China from Korea and Japan, 1994-2006。

相关文档
最新文档