【视频】经济学:金融市场 06 市场有效性与过度波动性(Markets vs Volatility)
国际金融市场参考文献

国际金融市场参考文献引言:国际金融市场作为全球经济体系的重要组成部分,在全球化和经济发展的背景下,发挥着日益重要的作用。
为了更好地理解和分析国际金融市场,研究者们广泛运用了各种研究方法和理论框架。
本文将就国际金融市场的参考文献进行探讨,以帮助读者更好地了解和研究这一领域。
一、经典文献:1. Robert C. Merton (1973) - "The Theory of Rational Option Pricing"本文被公认为是金融衍生品定价理论的奠基之作,对金融市场的研究产生了深远的影响。
通过对期权定价的理论研究,Merton提出了一种基于风险中性概率的期权定价模型,为金融市场的理论研究和实践应用提供了重要的理论基础。
2. Eugene F. Fama (1970) - "Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work"本文系统地回顾了关于有效资本市场理论的研究成果,提出了信息效率市场假说。
该假说认为,在有效市场中,资产的价格会反映所有可获取的信息,投资者无法通过分析已有信息来获得超额利润。
这一假说对金融市场的理论研究和实践应用产生了重要的影响。
二、实证研究文献:1. John Y. Campbell, Andrew W. Lo, and Craig MacKinlay (1997) - "The Econometrics of Financial Markets"该书综合了金融市场中的实证研究成果,包括股票、债券和外汇市场等。
通过运用计量经济学的方法,作者们对金融市场的波动性、收益率预测和市场效率等问题进行了深入研究,为金融市场的实证分析提供了重要的参考。
2. Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny (1997) - "The Limits of Arbitrage"该文研究了市场的套利机会是否会被有效利用,以及套利行为对市场效率的影响。
有效市场假说与行为金融学

有效市场假说与行为金融学一般认为,现代金融理论产生于20世纪50年代,以1952年马柯维茨(H.Markowitz)发表《证券投资组合选择》一文为开端,随后关于公司财务的Modiglian-Miller理论,Sharpe的资本资产定价理论,Fama的有效市场理论,Black-Scholes-Merton的期权定价理论和Ross的套利定价理论的创立和发展,构建起了现代金融学的基本框架。
这些理论都假定行为主体是理性经济人,所用的分析框架为一般均衡理论或无套利定价理论。
其中有效市场假说(Efficient Market Hypothesis,EMH)是现代金融理论的基石,其对主流金融理论的主要贡献一是理性人假设,这是分析的起点;二是套利方程,为套利行为的分析提供了最有效的分析方法和思路。
正因为EMH在现代证券理论中的特殊地位,EMH得到了金融学家广泛的检验和讨论。
随著对金融市场理论研究、以及实证检验的不断深入,金融市场出现了很多不能被主流金融学所解释的异常现象,使EMH和主流金融学受到了人们的普遍质疑。
而正当主流金融学陷入理论困境的同时,一门以研究、解释这些异常现象发展起来的新兴金融学派--行为金融学派正在崛起,无论主流金融学派是否愿意承认,行为金融学派正受到越来越多的关注和讨论,EMH和主流金融学派正面临史无前例的挑战。
一、有效市场假说与Grossman-Stiglitz悖论有效市场假说是指如果一个市场的证券价格总能够"充分反映"所有可以得到的信息,则该市场就是"有效的"。
价格已经充分反映了所有可以得到的信息,这就是有效市场假说。
其逻辑推理简单地说就是,在由完美理性的投资者构成的完全竞争下的证券市场中,投资者根据最大效用原则,利用已有的私人信息和前期均衡价格所包含的公共信息,进行证券组合的选择,交易的结果是所形成的新均衡价格就会包括所有的私人信息和公共信息,即证券的均衡价格反映了所有可得的信息。
有效市场假说与行为金融PPT课件

竞争是市场效率的根源。这包含两层含义,一是 一旦市场偏离均衡,出现了某种获利机会,对收益 的竞争会使投资者在极短的时间内去填补这一空 隙,使市场恢复均衡;二是市场上存在着许多训练 有素、知识和技术能力、分析能力都很强的投资 者,这些投资者之间的竞争使得要战胜市场(其他 投资者)成为不可能,从而要预测证券价格的未来 变化,寻找获利机会是相当困难的。
化表述。
(二)市场有效性实证检验
1,股市收益可预测性的检验
有文献对纽约证交所上市股票的周收益考察证实
了:
短期内正序列相关的存在 长期(跨越数年)的收益存在明显的负长期序列 相关 理论解释:股价对相关信息存在过度反应。 – 过度反映会引致短期的正序列相关(势头) – 随后对过度反应的纠正又引市场假定——〉半强有效市场假定——〉弱 有效市场假定
二、有效市场理论的应用
(一)有效市场理论的推论
有效市场中的投资者不能战胜市场,但仍可得到 市场的公平回报;
只有当足够多的投资者相信市场无效时,它才有 可能在竞争压力下变得有效;
公开的投资策略不可能获得超额回报; 专业投资者在选股方面不应该比普通投资者表现 得更好; 投资者过往的业绩不代表其未来的业绩;
《金融学季刊》入选论文。
• 本文以机构投资者发展对市场质量的影响为研究 对象,选取2008年第一季度到2011年第四季度期 间170家上市公司的面板数据为样本,采用两阶 段最小二乘法(2SLS),并使用工具变量,就机 构投资者发展程度对包括市场流动性、波动性、 信息传递效率在内的市场质量的影响关系进行了 实证检验和分析。检验表明,机构投资者整体促 进了流动性和信息传递效率的提高,但加剧了证 券市场的波动性;不同机构投资者的发展对市场 的流动性、波动性和信息传递效率具有不同方向 和不同程度的影响。据此,论文提出了优化我国 机构投资者结构和提升证券市场质量的对策建议。
耶鲁公开课笔记2

美国耶鲁大学网络公开课《金融市场》视频笔记2耶鲁大学网络公开课《金融市场》由罗伯特.J.希勒(Robert J. Shiller)教授主讲。
共26课(集),每课时长均为一个多小时,配有字幕。
[第2课] 风险管理中的普遍原理:风险汇聚和对冲(时长1小时09分)本课主题是风险管理中的普遍原理----风险汇聚和对冲(Pooling and Hedging of Risk)。
希勒认为这是金融理论中最基本、最核心的概念。
本课先讲概率论(Probability Theory),再讲通过风险汇聚来分摊风险的概念。
概率论是极具智慧的构想,诞生于历史上的特定时期,并令人意想不到地获得广泛应用,金融是其应用领域之一。
对部分学生来说,本课相对所讲的其他课会显出更多的技术性,并且遗憾的是又安排在学期初。
对于学过概率和统计的学生而言,就不是新知识了。
这是从数学角度的看法。
概率论是新知识,但不要太畏惧。
课前有个学生告诉希勒,他的数学有些生疏了,是否还能选这门课?希勒说,如果你能听懂这堂课,那就不会有问题。
什么是概率?通过举例说明。
比如,今年股票市场会走高的概率是多少?例如认为概率是0.45,是因为对股市悲观,预测股市会走高的可能性是45%,而股市会走平或走低的可能性是55%。
这就是概率。
听了这个例子,人们就会觉得这个概念是熟悉的,如果有人提到概率是0.55或0.45,也就知道他说的意思了。
话锋一转,希勒强调,概率并非总是以这种方式来表述的。
概率论成形于十七世纪,此前没有人提出过。
撰写概率论历史的作者伊恩.哈金(Ian Hacking),查遍世界所有关于概率论的文献,没有发现在十七世纪之前有概率论的文献,也就是说,在十七世纪产生了一次智慧的飞跃,当时用概率词汇来表述非常时髦,引用概率进行表述的方式很快传遍世界。
但是,有意思的是,如此简单的概念此前从未使用过。
下面希勒详细介绍哈金的成果。
哈金研究表明,概率词汇早已存在于英语中,莎士比亚就用过,但其所代表的意思是什么呢?哈金举了一个年轻小姐的例子,这位小姐描述她喜欢的男子,说道,“我太喜欢他了,我觉得他有很大‘可能’”(probable)。
探究股票市场的有效性与波动性

标题:探究股票市场的有效性与波动性摘要:股票市场作为金融市场的重要组成部分,一直备受关注。
本文旨在探究股票市场的有效性和波动性,通过对现有文献和数据的分析,得出结论并提出相应建议。
研究结果表明,股票市场是有效的,但波动性较大。
因此,投资者应该根据自身的风险承受能力和投资目的,合理进行投资。
引言:股票市场是金融市场的重要组成部分,也是经济发展的重要指标之一。
股票市场的有效性和波动性是投资者和学者们一直关注的问题。
股票市场有效性指股票价格能够反映所有可获得信息,即市场价格是公正的、合理的。
而波动性则是指股票价格的波动幅度,包括短期波动和长期波动。
了解股票市场的有效性和波动性对于投资者进行投资决策和风险控制具有重要意义。
正文:一、股票市场有效性的理论基础股票市场有效性理论最早由美国经济学家菲舍尔(Fisher)提出。
他认为,股票价格是由市场上所有可获得信息共同决定的,因此股票市场是有效的。
此后,美国学者法玛(Fama)在20世纪60年代提出了股票市场有效性三种形式:弱式有效、半强式有效和强式有效。
弱式有效指股票市场价格已经包含了历史价格信息,但未包含其他公开信息。
半强式有效指市场价格已经包含了所有公开信息,但未包含内部信息。
而强式有效则指市场价格已经包含了所有可获得的信息,包括内部信息。
目前,学术界普遍认为股票市场是半强式有效的。
二、股票市场有效性的实证分析许多研究表明,股票市场是有效的。
例如,法玛(Fama)在1970年代通过对美国股票市场数据的分析发现,即使是具有信息优势的专业投资者也不能获得超过市场平均收益的投资回报。
此外,很多学者也对其他国家的股票市场进行了实证研究,结果也表明股票市场是有效的。
三、股票市场波动性的原因股票市场的波动性是由多种因素造成的。
首先,宏观经济因素是影响股票市场波动的重要因素之一。
例如,通货膨胀率、利率、经济增长率等因素都会影响股票市场的走势。
其次,公司内部因素也会影响股票价格的波动。
第9章 有效市场假说与行为金融学

• 这里所谓的额外利润,也即非正常收益率(abnormal 这里所谓的额外利润,也即非正常收益率( 所谓的额外利润 收益率 return),它是指在给定风险水平 ),它是指在给定风险水平下 rates of return),它是指在给定风险水平下,投 资者所获得的超过预期收益率以上的收益。 以上的收益 资者所获得的超过预期收益率以上的收益。我们可以 通过CAPM 单指数模型(SIM)或套利定价理论 APT) CAPM、 定价理论( 通过CAPM、单指数模型(SIM)或套利定价理论(APT) 来确定正常收益率。根据CAPM 证券(或组合) CAPM, 来确定正常收益率。根据CAPM,证券(或组合)i的 预期收益率为: 预期收益率为: E(r )=r +[E(r 9.6) E(ri)=rf+[E(rM)-rf]βi (9.6) 中的E( 即所谓正常收益率。这样, E(r 式中的E(ri)即所谓正常收益率。这样,非正常 收益率AR 即可定义为: 收益率ARi即可定义为: E(r ARi=ri-E(ri) +[E(r =ri-{rf+[E(rM)-rf]βi} (9.7)
第九章 有效市场假说与行为金融学
• 有效市场假说 • 行为金融学
第一 有效市场理论
要解决的问题
什么样的市场才是有效的? 什么样的市场才是有效的? 的市场才是有效的 市场有效性程度的划分及其相应特征是什么? 市场有效性程度的划分及其相应特征是什么? 有效性程度的划分及其相应特征是什么
是判断资本市场效率的理论依据,决定着 判断资本市场效率的理论依据,决定着 理论依据 实际投资中的投资策略 策略。 实际投资中的投资策略。 在运转良好的金融市场中, 在运转良好的金融市场中,价格反映了所 有相关信息, 有相关信息,这样的市场就被称为有效市 场或效率市场( market)。 场或效率市场(efficient market)。
091金融学习题(全)@北工大

第1章货币与货币制度1.在一个经济社会中,三个人分别生产三种产品:商品成产者苹果苹果园主香蕉香蕉种植者巧克力巧克力制造商如果苹果园主喜欢香蕉,香蕉种植者喜欢巧克力,而巧克力制造商喜欢苹果,在一个易货经济中,他们三人之间会发生交易吗?货币的引入会给三个生产者带来什么利益呢?There are three goods produced in an economy by three individuals:Good ProducerApples Orchard o wnerBananas Banana growerChocolate ChocolatierIf the orchard owner likes only bananas, the banana grower likes only chocolate, and the chocolatier likes only apples, will any trade between these three persons take place in a barter economy? How will introducing money into the economy benefit these three producers?2.将下列资产按照流动性从高到低排列:a:支票账户存款b:房屋c:通货d:洗衣机e:储蓄存款f:普通股Rank the following assets from most liquid to least liquid:a.checking account depositsb.housesc.currencyd.washing machinese.savings depositsmon stock3.为什么经济学家将恶性通货膨胀期间的货币比喻为在人们手里迅速传递的“烫手的山芋”?Why have some economists described money during a hyperinflation as a “hot potato” that is quickly passed from one person to another?第2章金融体系概览1.对以下说法作出评论:“因为企业并没有从二级市场实际获取资金,因此二级市场对经济而言的重要性不如一级市场。
金融工程讲义 第六讲 有效市场理论

第六讲有效市场理论第一节有效市场假设概述一.有效市场假设(Efficient Market Hypothesis,EMH)的理论渊源第一篇讨论市场有效问题的著述可追溯到1900年,即法国数学家巴切列尔(Bachelier)所发表的博士论文《投机理论》,他在其中写道:“过去的,现在的,甚至是将来可预期到的事情都反映在市场价格中,但是与未来的价格变化没有明显的联系。
”他认为股票期货价格是不能预测的,买卖双方的盈亏机会均等,在任何一个时刻价格升降的可能性同时存在,因此投机者的预期收益是零,但是却没有什么经验证明来支持他的假设。
可惜巴切列尔的观点在当时并没有引起人们的重视,直到20世纪50年代,保罗·萨缪尔森(Samuelson)才第一个认识到他的贡献。
1933年,经济学家考尔斯(Cowles)发表了论文《股市预测者能预测吗》,他通过大量的数据统计表明无法准确预测大市走势。
考尔斯发现:找不出任何证据来猜出市场的价格变化。
1944年,考尔斯在《计量经济学报》第12卷第3期及第4期合刊上发表了论文《股市预测》,他通过分析1929年至1944年15年内专家们所做的6 904次预测,统计出看好与看淡的比率为4:1,可是期内股市跌掉一半。
虽然这篇文章只是从投资专家的角度分析了他们测市的准确度,但也间接说明了市场的不可预测。
1934年,斯坦福大学统计学教授沃金·霍尔布鲁德(working Holbrood)在《美国统计学会学报》3月号发表了《供时间序列分析用的随机差系列》论文。
他用大量的统计数字,证明了股票和期货价格预测不准确。
沃金以每次成交的价位为基准,把股票及商品期货的价格变动绘成走势图。
通过这样的图表,他发现价位变化在很大程度上是随机走动的,这证明价格趋向是不可测的。
同时,他还通过以随机过程求出随机数目的方法,证明根据每手成交价位绘制的图表所显示的价格变化与随机数目生成的图表没有任何不同。
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
Lecture 6 - Efficient Markets vs. Excess VolatilityOverview:Several theories in finance relate to stock price analysis and prediction. The efficient markets hypothesis states that stock prices for publicly-traded companies reflect all available information. Prices adjust to new information instantaneously, so it is impossible to "beat the market." Furthermore, the random walk theory asserts that changes in stock prices arise only from unanticipated new information, and so it is impossible to predict the direction of stock prices. Using statistical tools, we can attempt to test the hypotheses and to predict future stock prices. These tests show that efficient markets theory is a half-truth: it is difficult but not impossible for some people to beat the market.Reading assignment:Robert Shiller, Irrational Exuberance, chapters 10 and 11David Swensen, Pioneering Portfolio Management, chapter 8Jeremy Siegel, Stocks for the Long Run, chapters 3, 4, 5, 16, 17, and 18Financial Markets: Lecture 6 TranscriptFebruary 01, 2008Professor Robert Shiller: I want to talk today about the efficient markets hypothesis. Let me just first say, last lecture was about insurance and I was telling you about the theory of insurance and how it has evolved over the years and how it has produced some real benefits. Is that better? It says, "Mike volume." I wanted to just tie this in--the advantages of insurance that we have to some big events that occurred and that will, I think, point out the strengths and weaknesses of our institutions. We had a terrible hurricane a couple of years ago in Los Angeles; Hurricane Katrina damaged the city of--I'm sorry did I say Los Angeles? Y ou have to stop me when I say things that are obviously wrong. My mind lapses sometimes--New Orleans--and Los Angeles doesn't have to worry about hurricanes as far as I know, unless there's some major change. In New Orleans there was a Hurricane Katrina; it broke the levies that were surrounding the city and caused the flooding of the city.What saved the people of the city, mostly? I would say it was actually the insurance institutions because the city was heavily damaged but homes were generally insured. There were some conflicts when this huge disaster came. Some people had wind insurance and some people hadflood insurance and it became difficult whether this was a wind or a flood problem, because the wind caused the flood. So, if you had only wind insurance are you covered? There was a lot bickering and arguments afterwards but I think it worked out well. There were surveys of customer satisfaction after the event and I think, generally, people were happy with their insurance companies. Of course, there were some that were not, who may have found out that they weren't covered; but on the whole, the experience worked well.The other thing I want to say about the last lecture is that as financial progress moves on, the distinction between insurance and other forms of risk management may get blurred. One very interesting thing that's been happening is that we are starting to see development of another institution called the catastrophe bond, which is another way that people have for protecting themselves against catastrophes and it's not insurance. A catastrophe bond is a bond that the issuer doesn't have to pay off if there's a catastrophe. Y ou could have hurricanes--the City of New Orleans could raise money with catastrophe bonds that they have to pay back if there's no hurricane but they don't have to pay back if there is a hurricane. Or it could be some mixture: they'd pay back part of it if there is a hurricane. That's like insurance, isn't it? But it doesn't operate through an insurance company, it operates through a securities market.A good example of that is a couple of years ago the Government of Mexico issued catastrophe bonds against earthquakes. Mexico City was hit by a terrible earthquake about twenty years ago and it's vulnerable to being hit again. So, what does Mexico do about this? Mexico could wait until there is a hurricane (sic) and hope that there's some international relief effort, but that's not a very good way to proceed. We want to arrange it in advance. What Mexico did was issue cat bonds that have to be repaid in the absence of a hurricane and have a lower repayment if there is--I'm sorry, I'm not on my best form today--earthquake. Mexico City does not have to worry about hurricanes either. Every area is different and they have their own individual characteristics.Right now, the insurance industry is a bit challenged because--in terms of some risks--because the risks seem to be changing through time and, notably, it looks like hurricane risk is increasing. So people who are insured in--it seems to be increasing because of global warming, although I don't know if all scientists are agreed on that. If you live in a coastal area of Florida it does appear that your risk is increasing through time. So insurance companies want to raise your rates and this is a huge issue down in Florida. Well, the government has kind of taken over for the time being--insurance in Florida--because we have problems. People are having problems paying the increased insurance premium. I don't think we've figured out finally how insurance will ultimately look in a matter of years. But, I think that the important thing is that it's protecting against us already, maybe imperfectly, but it's already protecting us against some of our worst fears, like hurricanes and earthquakes. I think the system is evolving and we're getting new developments like cat bonds that are changing the way we're doing things. In the future, I think these will develop more and make us even better able to handle catastrophe risks.Anyway, that's the last lecture. Today I wanted to talk about--back to securities markets or actually, more general, asset markets. I want to talk today about the efficient markets hypothesis, which is a very important intellectual construct that has guided a lot of theory in finance. I want to talk firstabout the history of the hypothesis--I haven't defined it yet for you but maybe you already have heard of this--but history of the hypothesis, the arguments for it, and then the arguments against it.I want to talk about technical analysis and empirical evidence in the literature--about technical analysis--and other schools of thought that doubt the market efficiency, talk somewhat about behavioral economics. Then, finally, we have a homework assignment; actually, it's coming up. I'll start talking about it now so you--it will be an assignment for you to try to forecast the stock market using statistical methods. Y ou don't have to look at the screen yet; I'll come back to that.What is the efficient markets hypothesis? The term actually is a fairly recent origin--that is, a few decades ago--but the idea goes back much further. The idea is that in asset markets that have good regulations and market makers and developed markets that have a lot of depth and liquidity--in these markets, the prices that you see are perfect indicators of true value. In other words, efficient market says that the market efficiently incorporates all information and the prices are like the best information about the value of something. In other words, efficient markets hypothesis tells you: trust markets, don't trust people, trust markets.I've been trying to find out who said that first. The earliest statement of the efficient markets hypothesis, although it doesn't call it the efficient markets hypothesis--the earliest statement that I could find comes from a book written in 1889 by George Gibson and it's called The Stock Exchanges of London, Paris, and New Y ork. I'll quote him, he said, "When shares become publicly-known in an open market, the value, which they acquire there, may be regarded as the judgment of the best intelligence concerning them." I was kind of interested to see this book. I found it in the Mudd Library, actually by accident, looking through old stock market books.The book had some interesting observations. One observation, which took my interest, was that he points out that in this modern electronic age information speeds around the globe at the speed of electricity--or the speed of light. When I first read that I thought for a minute, wait a minute, 1889? That sounds like 1989 or something. Just a moment. We found the microphone. Oh, it was right there? Now I am free from my tether. In 1889, they had already invented the telegraph. In fact, that goes back decades earlier. The telephone was starting to appear, so it really was true that information would speed around the globe. Information that became publicly-known would be entered into market price almost immediately. The conclusion that Gibson had was that there's no hope in trying to beat the price or beat the market because the price already has all of the information in it.Let me elaborate on that theme a little bit. Actually, it goes back before telegraph, there was a famous story of Mr. Reuters, who had an information service before the telegraph was invented. He wanted to help his clients get the information first so that they could trade on it and he had the idea of using what you call carrier pigeons. What you do is you get these birds and you raise them--you know what I'm talking about, right? Y ou raise them in one place and then they're going to want to go back there. Then you take them away in a cage to another city and when you need to get a message across, you tie the message to the pigeon's foot and release it. Then it will fly back and it will beat any other method of message transmission. Incidentally, Reuter's information service is still in business today and now they use computers the way everyone else does, but thewhole principle precedes the invention of computers.The idea is that the only way you can beat the market is to get information that nobody else has. The way it works today is that the--we can't actually improve on the speed from 1889 because they were already going at virtually the speed of light with their information; but, we can improve on our access to it. Now, many people have beepers or something like this in their pocket that wakes up and tells them when news is announced.What happens where there's news about a stock? Let's say it's a drug company that just makes an announcement that it has a new drug--let's say good news--or it has gotten FDA approval to market some new drug. Well, it would put that out over the network of information and some people would have their things beep on them and alert them immediately. There are analysts who try to keep up with news about stocks. So, these analysts then would jump to action when they hear news like that. That's because they know that markets move really fast to important new information and they've got to be there first. What happens when the drug company announces that they have some news--important news? Well, the guys who are with their beepers immediately spring to action and try to figure out what the news is. Within seconds they're trading because you know you've got to be there first; otherwise, you can't benefit from the news.What happens? They say they've announced--they've got approval for this new drug. Then maybe do a quick call to their drug company expert and say, quick how much should I change the valuation of this stock? The guy will give a quick guess--this is now twenty seconds after the announcement--and then immediately you place a big trade for a million shares or plus or minus. Then the guy calls back thirty seconds later and says, "Oh no, I wasn't exactly right on that. I've had thirty more seconds to think about this, so let me change it again." Over the next few minutes, the price--a lot of people are trading like that so the price is jumping around rapidly. Then, after maybe five minutes, these people have had time to assimilate it and think about it and check their thinking and the price starts to settle down. Maybe I'm exaggerating how fast it settles down. Maybe an hour later you have a committee meeting and the experts are arguing about what this really means and trying to assimilate other information and coordinate with it; but, after two hours it started to really settle down.Suppose you then, the next day, read in The Wall Street Journal about this new announcement. Do you think you have any chance of beating the market by trading on it? I mean, you're like twenty-four hours late, but I hear people tell me--I hear, "I read in Business Week that there was a new announcement, so I'm thinking of buying." I say, "Well, Business Week--that information is probably a week old." Even other people will talk about trading on information that's years old, so you kind of think that maybe these people are naïve. First of all, you're not a drug company expert or whatever it is that's needed. Secondly, you don't know the math--you don't know how to calculate present values, probably. Thirdly, you're a month late. Y ou get the impression that a lot of people shouldn't be trying to beat the market. Y ou might say, to a first approximation, the market has it all right so don't even try.The efficient markets hypothesis is a hypothesis that one should respect financial markets very much. Y our textbook by Fabozzi, et al. mentions--I looked it up in the index to see what they sayabout efficient markets hypothesis. They define it. I'm quoting the textbook Fabozzi, "Publicly-available, relevant information about the issuers will lead to correct pricing of freely-traded securities in properly-functioning markets." That's their definition of the efficient markets hypothesis. They didn't say it was right; they just said that's the hypothesis. What Fabozzi, et al. said is that the hypothesis has informed a lot of regulation. The Securities and Exchange Commission and other agencies that regulate financial markets have shown some faith in the efficient markets hypothesis. Therefore, they feel that their--maybe their primary mission is to regulate the flow of information to make sure that it's an even playing field so that everyone has access to information at the same time. For example, the Securities and Exchange Commission requires that when a corporation publishes information that's relevant to the value of their stock, they have to put it out to everyone at once or there's rules about what that means. Typically, they'll have a webcast or something like that and it's announced in advance, so everyone who is really interested can listen in. I don't find a whole lot of enthusiasm in the Fabozzi book for the efficient markets hypothesis and maybe that's because it's not exactly right, which is my view. It's a half truth; I'll come back to that.I want to quote another best-selling textbook, not your own, but there's another textbook, Brealey and Myers, which is a textbook of corporate finance. They are much more enthusiastic about efficient markets hypothesis. At the end of their textbook, they have a concluding chapter and the concluding chapter is built around what they call the "seven most important ideas in finance." One of those seven ideas to them is efficient markets. They don't call it a hypothesis, they just say "efficient markets," which they define as the theory that--I'm quoting them, "Security prices accurately reflect available information and respond rapidly to new information as soon as it becomes available." Then they have a little qualifier--I think this is interesting--they say, "Don't misunderstand the efficient market idea, it doesn't say that there are no taxes or costs. It doesn't say that there aren't some clever people and some stupid ones. It merely implies that competition in capital markets is very tough. There are no money machines and security prices reflect the true underlying value of assets." That's a pretty enthusiastic endorsement of efficient markets.I said I have some doubts about it. I guess I don't--I guess what I don't like is their concluding statement, "Security prices reflect the true underlying value of assets." I don't think that's really true but I guess I agree, it's tough to make money reliably and quickly in financial markets. So, if that's what efficient markets means, they're right. "Efficient markets" is not so easy to define. We can go back to--the term really goes back to 1967 and it was Professor Harry Roberts at University of Chicago who defined three different efficient markets hypotheses. There's the weak form, the semi-strong form, and then the strong form. The weak form--these differ only in terms of the amount of information that is assumed to be efficiently incorporated into prices. The weak form says that information of past prices is already in the--incorporated into price, but only past prices. What it means "only" is that you can't predict stock prices by noting that, say, if it goes up today, it'll probably go up tomorrow or it goes up today, it'll probably go down tomorrow. That would be relying only on past prices. Harry Roberts felt most confident that this form of the hypothesis was good, so he called it the weak form; it's the least criticizable form of efficient markets.Semi-strong form says that market prices incorporate all public information. Anything that'sknown to the public is already incorporated into price, so don't bother to trade on it. The strong form says all information, whether public or not, is incorporated into price. This is a really strong--it's the least likely to be true because every time you increase the information set--what strong form says is that no information is private, really, it all gets out into price. Companies keep secrets, so that's not public information. The Securities and Exchange Commission insists that companies keep secrets because they have to disseminate information in an orderly way. So, there has to be a secret until a certain hour in which it's announced to everybody. But the strong form efficient markets hypothesis is cynical about that and says, you know, nobody keeps secrets, it all leaks out.I think that when we refer to the efficient markets hypothesis, it's the semi-strong form that we're usually referring to because the strong form is a bit strong. The definitions of efficient markets that I gave you are intuitive but not very precise. Then you have to ask, well what does it mean to say that price incorporates all information? What does it mean to incorporate information? Unfortunately, there's not one answer to that question, so I'm going to give the simplest answer. What does efficient markets mean? I might--I'll have to--this is the simplest version but it's often the one that is referred to most. That is that price is the expected value--the expected present value--of future dividends paid on a stock.The efficient markets hypothesis says, the true value of a stock comes from the dividends that it pays--that's a cash flow that is valued by the market and the market values it as the present value of the optimally-forecasted future dividends. The theory that's most often referred to is the simple--I've already talked in the second lecture about present value formulas; we had a growing-perpetuity model. Remember that I said that the present value--the present discounted value of a growing perpetuity that pays an amount D--well, if it pays Degt or D0egt is the dividend, so it's growing at rate, g. Then, the formula we had for the present value was D/(r-g). Remember that? This assumes, of course, that the growth of dividends has to be less than the discount rate, r.The simplest version of the efficient markets hypothesis says, price is equal to the dividend all over the discount rate minus the growth rate of dividends, where g, the growth rate of dividends, is an optimally-forecasted growth rate of dividend. That gives us a value--a model for the price. Another way of writing, more generally--if I don't assume the constant growth rate of dividends--is to write just a present value formula. It's another less strong form of writing down the efficient markets hypothesis because it doesn't say how dividends are thought to grow. But you can write: price is equal to the summation of E(Dt+k)]/(1 + r)k; k = 1 to infinity. This is another--that's just the present value formula. I have the price--I'm sorry, this should be expectation at time, t--the price at t is the expectation of the dividend, at time t plus k, discounted by a discount factor r. That's just the present value formula where I've substituted an expectation for the future dividend. That's the efficient markets theory in this incarnation.There are other ways to envision the efficient markets--what it means--but let's consider this simple story. What this means then is that the price is a forecast of future dividends to be paid on the stock. This would be--of the present value of future dividends to be paid on the stock--and this means then that price, relative to dividend, is related to expected future growth rates of dividends.If you expect dividends to grow a lot, if g is high, then price will be h igh, relative to dividends, because this is subtracted off the denominator. It makes the denominator smaller and it makes the price higher. On the other hand, if you expect dividends to do poorly in the future, then price will be low relative to dividends; that's what the efficient markets hypothesis would say.I would give you an example of that. I talked last year about a company that I read in Business Week--that I read about in Business Week, so this is a year old story in Business Week. There was a company called First Federal Financial, which was a company that issues mortgages. This was in January of 2007, actually the Business Week story was in December of 2006, but I was still reacting to it a year ago, in January of 2007. The Business Week story--this is First Federal Financial--was referring to the fact that the price-dividend ratio--actually they talked about price-earnings ratio, but the price-earnings ratio for this company was very low. It was only 8.5 in December 2006. Typically, price-earnings ratios of the companies are very high, much higher than that--typically like fifteen. The price of First Federal Financial, relative to its earnings, was very low, so some people might be inclined to think well that looks cheap. I can buy--by buying First Federal Financial, I can buy the stock at a low price relative to its earnings. But, if you believe in efficient markets you wouldn't think that this is any reason to buy the company because efficient markets would say that if the price is low relative to either dividends or earnings, it must mean that people think that bad things are going to come to the dividends or earnings. In other words, the First Federal Financial has a low expected growth rate of dividends in the future. So, I was interested in this particular story because Business Week wrote an article about them and noted the low price-earnings ratio and said, what does this mean? What Business Week presented a year ago was an argument why g was likely to be low. Y es?Student: [inaudible]Professor Robert Shiller: If they don't pay dividends you can't use this formula. I'm not sure what the dividends were at First Federal Financial. I only know the price-earnings ratio at that time. Y ou're right, you cannot use this formula if they're not paying a dividend today because this formula--I erased it, but it was up here--assumes that dividends are following a growth path. If they're not paying a dividend, then we're very clearly--that's not an appropriate assumption.Student: So how would the efficient market theory explain prices of companies that do not pay dividends?Professor Robert Shiller: Right. So for–incidentally, if you know, Berkshire Hathaway is the company Warren Buffett owns and it's a very famous company because it's done extremely well. Warren Buffett is regarded as, by many people, as the financial genius. If Berkshire Hathaway is not paying a dividend, we have to revert to this formula. The efficient market theory would say, well they're going to pay a dividend eventually, so the price reflects these future terms. If you spell this out, this is the expected dividend next year plus the dividend in two years--this is divided by (1 + r)2--the expected dividend in three years divided by (1 + r)3, etc.This theory would say that the dividend--that Berkshire Hathaway has value only becausethey--investors expect them to pay dividends in the future. That sounds right because if Berkshire Hathaway is never going to pay dividends, why would you hold it? Y ou might say, I'll hold it because I could sell to someone else at a higher price. But then you say, well why would anyone else buy it? Look, if they're never going to pay a dividend, what good is it? It's just a piece of paper, unless I can sell to a greater fool. But anyone who buys it is either--would be buying it either on the assumption that there's some greater fool coming or they would be a fool themselves. This theory says that the value--if Warren Buffett--of course, he can't even say this, but let's somehow say the company could say, we will never pay a dividend. This company is going to give itself away to charity someday and you won't get a penny as a stockholder. Well, if that happened the price should be zero. It would convert into a non-profit, like Y ale University. So what's the price of a share in Y ale University? I mean, it's undefined--I its guess zero, right? Because Y ale is not paying--I'll write a piece of paper for you and say this is a share. On my authority, this is a share in Y ale University. It might just as well be that because it also says in my fine print, you will never get a dividend on this. So what's the point, right? Incidentally, Microsoft for many years never paid a dividend. It's often common for young companies not to pay dividends; but they did start paying a dividend.The whole theory--efficient markets theory--says that that's what people are looking for. That's why the value of a company is related to its activities; otherwise, if the company never paid a dividend, then what would you care what the company is doing? Y ou only care about it because someday they're going to give you money. A lot of investors forget that; that's a very naïve attitude. They think that somehow stocks generate capital gains--prices go up--but you have to realize and effic ient markets theory is saying this: prices only go up because there's new information about future dividends. First Financial anyway--this is an efficient markets story--First Financial had a low P/E, so people were wondering, is this a bargain? This is a cheap stock--P/E means price-earnings ratio. The Business Week article pointed out that 40% of First Federal had been sold short--40% of their stock had been sold short; this is a very high level of shortage. Y ou know what means? That means a lot of investors said, "I don't like First Federal Financial, I don't want to invest in it. Worse than that, I want to go and short them." That means you borrow shares and sell them and hope that the price goes down. When you have 40% of the shares sold short that means that there were a lot of people who didn't believe in First Federal Financial.Business Week, in its article, pointed out that this--First Federal Financial was a small mortgage lender--this is before the mortgage crisis that we have started--in Santa Monica, California. And it was particularly innovative, in a sense, in its lending. Notably, 80%, according to the Business Week article, 80% of the mortgages it's issued were no-doc mortgages. Do you know what a no-doc mortgage is? It's something that appeared recently in the housing frenzy. A no-doc mortgage is a mortgage where you walk in and say, "I want to borrow money to buy this house." The company says, "Fine we'll give you a mortgage. We won't even ask you to have your employer send a letter saying that you have a job. We won't even ask you to prove that you own anything or have--we'll just give you the mortgage." That's considered by many people risky behavior but it was done during the housing boom.。