公共品供给与囚徒两难博弈
囚徒困境的均衡辨析

囚徒困境的均衡辨析郭洪伟【摘要】传统的《博弈论》分析最终结果是两个囚徒均会坦白,但这并不是两个囚徒的最好结局,如何才能达到最好结局?本文从《博弈论》动中“理性人”的假设出发,对传统的(坦白,坦白)均衡提出质疑.本文指出理性人不会满足于传统的均衡,理性人会积极寻找双方利益最大化的均衡,并达到此均衡.本文给出了新的均衡:广义均衡,并给出广义均衡的求解过程.通过对引入公共支付函数的概念,公共支付函数表达了两个人的共同利益.通过公共支付函数的最大化,使两个囚徒公共利益最大化,以求得囚徒困境的新的均衡,让两个囚徒的结果达到最好——即两人均抵赖.本文还将公共支付函数运用于其他《博弈论》案例,并指出广义均衡比纳什均衡更具有社会意义,因为前者体现了公共利益.文中还对囚徒困境的机制设计问题做了分析,指出囚徒困境中机制的设计会诱导囚徒作出不正确的选择,从而没有达到双方利益的最大化.【期刊名称】《技术经济与管理研究》【年(卷),期】2011(000)002【总页数】4页(P22-25)【关键词】囚徒困境;公共支付;纳什均衡;广义均衡:支付函数【作者】郭洪伟【作者单位】首都经济贸易大学统计学院,北京100070【正文语种】中文【中图分类】F224博弈论研究的是存在相互影响关系下的个人选择问题。
这里的参与人都是理性人。
按照文献[1]的定义:理性人是在面临给定的约束条件下,能最大化自己偏好的那些人。
这里理性的人与自私的人不同。
理性人可能是利己主义者,也可能是利他主义者。
理性人假设是博弈论的分析前提。
基于这个前提,所有的参与人都尽量使自己的偏好(利益)最大化,如果存在某种行动会使参与人变的更好,参与人会积极努力达成更好的结果。
理性人在最大化偏好时,需要相互合作,而合作中又存在着冲突。
下面分析博弈论中经典的案例——囚徒困境,如表1所示。
假设有两名嫌疑人作案后被警察抓住,分别被关在不同的屋子里接受审讯(关在不同的屋子里是怕他们串供,这也是影响他们博弈的关键因素之一)。
公共危机管理体系博弈模型分析_略论政府的囚徒困境模型应对策略

公共危机管理体系博弈模型分析
———略论政府的囚徒困境模型应对策略
斯亚平
[摘 要 ] 我国正处于社会转型时期 ,政府在公共危机管理过程中面对着极为复杂的局面 。本文运用博弈模型分 析方法 ,从政府在公共危机管理过程中针对面临公共危机的相关个人 、组织等不同利益群体所采取的姿 态 、行为着手 ,研究讨论政府破解“囚徒困境 ”博弈模型中的应对策略 。
三 、我国公共危机管理中的囚徒困境模型分析 我国是处于转型期的超大型社会 ,社会关系复杂 ,各种 矛盾交织在一起 ,公共危机频发 。我们以“安徽阜阳 : 怪病 背后的政府怪状 ”为案例 ,可以分析得出政府破解囚徒困境 模型的应对策略 。
案例材料 2008年 3月上旬 , 阜阳市人民医院接收 5 例 患病儿童 ,症状一样 。3月 27日至 29日 , 5例患儿 全部死亡 ! 面对不明疾病 , 恐慌迅速蔓延 。但迟 至 4月 15日 ,当地政府才公开此病信息 :确有几名 婴幼儿因患春季呼吸道疾病相继夭折 , 且这几例 病人没有相互传染联系 。 又过了 10天 ,官方确诊的权威信息才姗姗来 迟 。此时 ,距发病初期已经一月有余 。 尽管阜阳政府极力辩解 , 但期间仍有多数人 认为 ,政府在试图通过“危机公关 ”,用极个别孩子 的生命消亡 , 弥补行政渎职和决策荒唐 。民意一 时汹汹 。 官方在 4月 15日前没有公布任何病情进展 。 但在 28日的新闻发布会上 , 媒体却被告知 :医院 其实已于 3月 31 日将情况上报 , 省里也很快派出 专家组赶赴阜阳 。此举 , 被当地政府艺术地形容 为“外松内紧 ”。 与官方 的 沉 默 不 一 样 , 民 间 自 救 自 发 启 动 。 有人上街戴口罩 ,有人把小孩从幼儿园接回家 , 还 有人把小孩送到乡下 。消毒液热销 , 非典期间被 人倚重的“板蓝根冲剂 ”也热销 , 价格从每盒 7 元 涨至 10元 。
公共物品供给与市场失灵

公共物品供给与市场失灵公共物品是指那些不具有排他性和竞争性的商品或服务,它们一旦提供给一部分人就会同时惠及所有人。
然而,公共物品的供给往往存在一些问题,而市场失灵则是其中最常见的原因之一。
本文将探讨公共物品供给中的市场失灵现象,并分析其中的原因和影响。
一、公共物品供给的重要性公共物品的供给对于社会的发展和公众的福利至关重要。
公共物品包括但不限于桥梁、公园、道路、基本教育和卫生保健等,它们提供了社会基础设施和公共服务,推动了经济增长和社会进步。
公共物品的供给不仅仅是政府责任的体现,也是社会公平和民生福祉的保障。
二、公共物品供给中的市场失灵现象然而,市场在提供公共物品方面存在着固有的局限性,导致了市场失灵的现象。
主要表现在以下几个方面:1. 非排他性公共物品的非排他性使得市场无法对其进行有效定价和收费,这给私人企业提供公共物品带来了困难。
由于公共物品无法追求个人利益最大化,私人企业在供给公共物品方面缺乏动力,从而导致市场失灵。
2. 非竞争性公共物品的非竞争性使得供给者无法通过竞争来获取利润,从而也无法形成有效的市场供求关系。
在缺乏市场竞争机制的情况下,对于公共物品的供给容易出现不足和低效的问题,市场失灵现象愈发显著。
三、公共物品供给中的市场失灵原因市场失灵在公共物品供给中常常涉及以下几个原因:1. 公共物品的外部性公共物品的供给往往带来正面的外部效应,使得社会收益大于个体收益。
然而,私人企业无法从外部效应中获得经济利益,从而对于公共物品的供给缺乏积极性,导致市场失灵。
2. 公共物品的囚徒困境由于公共物品无法排他性地供给给所有人,个体有动机不支付费用,在以集体行动为基础的市场上,出现自由魔法的问题,导致公共物品供给不足,市场失灵。
3. 公共物品的自由载益问题公共物品的非竞争性和非排他性导致个体可以在不支付费用的情况下享受公共物品所带来的好处,这引发了市场供给的自由载益问题。
在这种情况下,私人企业或其他市场参与者缺乏供给公共物品的动力,出现市场失灵的现象。
走出困境_公共品供给的博弈分析

2003年7月辽宁大学学报(哲学社会科学版) J ul.2003第31卷 第4期Journal of L iaoning U niversity(Philosophy and Social Sciences Edition)V ol.31 No.4走出困境:公共品供给的博弈分析Ξ宋维佳(东北财经大学金广建设管理学院,辽宁大连116025) 摘要:公共品的提供是不同利益主体对一部分社会资源配置的策略选择的结果,在选择过程中,由于公共品的特殊性质,不同主体的供给有可能陷入囚徒、智猪和斗鸡三种困境。
本文运用博弈论来分析这些困境,并试图寻找一条走出困境之路。
关键词:困境;公共品;供给;博弈中图分类号:F01915 文献标识码:A 文章编号:1002-3291(2003)04-0107-04 一、分析框架根据萨缪尔森的定义,公共品是这样一种产品,“每个人对这种产品的消费,都不会导致其他人对该产品消费的减少。
”公共品明显地具有非排他性和消费的非竞争性,公共品独享在技术上或经济上的不可行产生了非排他性,这一特征决定其是被社会公众共同享用,不能排斥他人享用;增加一个人消费公共品的边际成本为0产生了消费的非竞争性,这一特征使公共品提供的福利为社会大众所共享,消费者不会自愿向提供者支付价格。
公共品的供给,简单地划分,可以由公共部门来完成,可以由私人部门来完成,还可以是两者的组合。
公共部门供给公共品是出于其职能实现的考虑,由于公共品有相当大的外在性,这些外在性的存在影响着生产者与消费者的决定,从而使得资源配置远优于不存在外在性,完全竞争时产生的配置结果,这恰恰是公共部门配置,调节和稳定职能所要实现的目标[1];私人部门的供给则出于私人效用最大化的考虑,这涉及到私人运营的目的、财务状况及对该公共品的享受程度等等。
公共品的非排他性使得私人无法排除他人对该产品的消费,而交易成本的存在使得私人难以收费,因此私人会倾向于成为“免费搭车者”。
博弈论视角下准公共物品供给困境及对策研究

博弈论视角下准公共物品供给困境及对策研究作者:曲舒萌来源:《西部学刊》2021年第15期摘要:通过运用公共物品理论,明确老旧小区加装的电梯是一种接近私人物品性质的且公共性较低的准公共物品。
在此基础上,基于博弈论视角推演高层与低层住户、高层与高层住户间的利益博弈,指出在加梯供给中存在“零和博弈”和“囚徒困境”两种模型。
要想解决老旧小区加装电梯的供给困境,应适当放宽业主同意规则、创新财政补贴机制、建立科学有效的利益补偿机制、完善加梯模式和技术。
关键词:博弈论;老旧小区加装电梯;准公共物品中图分类号:F062.6文献标识码:A文章编号:2095-6916(2021)15-0146-03一、引言随着我国老龄化进程加快,近年来越来越多居住在无电梯多层住宅的人群开始进入老年阶段。
他们上下楼越来越不方便,甚至严重影响生活质量。
再加上新型城镇化的推进,原社区内老旧的功能型设施难以适应城市的现代化建设要求,阻碍城市经济的发展和城市肌理的延续。
老旧小区加装电梯逐步成为大众普遍关注、反应强烈的民生问题。
自2018年起,国务院《政府工作报告》已连续三年将老旧小区加装电梯工作列为城市更新的重点任务。
全国各地政府积极响应,先后出台一系列加装电梯的支持性政策。
然而相比政策在各地的加速扩散,加装电梯项目在实践中却频遭梗阻。
截至2019年5月,全国加装电梯总量约3万台左右,远远小于与实际需求量250万台,甚至北京市政策出台7年后才成功加装首部电梯。
目前,加装电梯供给数量不足、推进速度缓慢等已经成为制约我国城市社区发展的重要问题。
本文从公共物品理论视角,以博弈论为研究方法,探讨老旧小区加装电梯的供给困境及解决对策。
二、公共物品理论视角下的老旧小区加装电梯在公共物品理论视角下探讨老旧小区加装电梯,核心与首要命题就是辨析老旧小区加装的电梯是否属于公共物品。
现阶段,老旧小区加装电梯按运行模式可分为三类:第一类是经过楼栋业主协商后,由业主集体出资加装,产权归业主集体所有,乘坐免费;第二类是“代建租用”,即引进企业出资加装且由该企业拥有电梯产权,楼栋业主则为电梯的“租户”;第三类是由集体或产权单位负责电梯加装的审批、安装、验收等流程及费用。
西方经济学中的公共物品与市场失灵

西方经济学中的公共物品与市场失灵在西方经济学中,公共物品与市场失灵是一个重要的研究领域。
公共物品是指非竞争性的、无排他性的物品或服务,它们的使用对其他人不会造成排挤,并且一旦提供给一个人,就可以供给其他人使用。
然而,在市场经济中,由于公共物品的特殊性质,存在着市场失灵的问题。
首先,理性选择模型是研究市场失灵的重要工具之一。
根据理性选择模型,在市场经济中,个体追求自身利益,通过评估成本和效益来进行决策。
然而,对于公共物品来说,个体的行为会受到“囚徒困境”和“自由骑乘”问题的影响。
囚徒困境是指在多人博弈中,个体追求自身利益最大化,但整体利益最小化的问题。
对于公共物品来说,如果每个个体都选择不支付成本来获得公共物品,那么最终可能导致公共物品无法提供,从而造成整体利益的损失。
自由骑乘问题指的是当公共物品提供后,无法排除那些没有为其支付成本的人使用公共物品。
由于公共物品的非排他性,个体可以免费享受其他人为其提供的公共物品,这会导致一些人免费搭便车,从而减少了为公共物品支付成本的动力。
当一部分个体选择不支付成本时,其他人将面临支付成本的不公平问题,从而减少了为公共物品支付成本的意愿。
为了解决公共物品的供给问题,政府在市场经济中扮演着重要的角色。
政府可以通过征税和提供公共物品来解决市场失灵的问题。
通过征税,政府可以强制个体为公共物品支付成本,从而避免了自由骑乘问题的出现。
同时,政府可以直接提供公共物品,确保公共物品的供给。
然而,政府在提供公共物品时也面临着一些困难。
首先,政府需要确定公共物品的供给数量和质量,这需要一定的行政能力和信息收集能力。
其次,政府在提供公共物品时需要考虑资源的有限性,避免浪费和滥用公共资源。
最后,政府在提供公共物品时也需要考虑公众的利益和意愿,确保公共物品的提供符合社会的期望和需求。
除了政府的角色,市场机制在解决公共物品供给问题中也发挥着重要作用。
市场机制可以通过创新和竞争来提高公共物品的供给效率。
“囚徒困境”与农村社区公共产品的合作供给

囚 徒困 境”与农村社区 公共产品的 合作供给
龚 冬 生 ,丁 欣2
(.西 安工程大学 管理学院 , 1 西安 704 ; .陕西青年职业学院 ,西安 706 ) 1 8 2 0 108
摘
要 :在现 实的农村社 区公共产品合作供 给过 程 中,村 民从个体理性 出发而 导致不合作 ,陷入 “ 囚徒
困境” 。如何 来规避该 问题?基 于村庄权威而建立的惩 罚机 制则是一 个有效的方式 ,在现 实中也是可行的 。
关键词 :囚徒 困境 ;农村社 区公共产品 ;舍作供 给 中图分 类号 :F30 3 2 . 文献标志码 :A 文章编 号:17 -4 9 2 0 )60 0 - 6250 ( 0 8 0 -0 80 2
维普资讯
20 0 8年 第 6期 ( 第5 总 4期 )
ห้องสมุดไป่ตู้
边疆 经 济与文 化
T HE BORDER CONOMY E AND C TURE UL
N 620 m .08 G n r1Nm 5 e ea. 4
【 民・ 农 农村 ・ 农业】
、
一
收 稿 日期 :20 .21 0 71 .8
作 者简介 :龚冬生( 9 0 ) 18 一 ,男 ,湖北钟祥人 ,助教 ,从 事城 乡公共经济与农村发展研究 。
田 B 州 …N / A G H
‘
维普资讯
当前 ,国 家所 提 倡 的在 农 村 社 区实 行 的 “ 一 事一议” 就公共产品提供而言 ,本质上就是一种 , 合 作供 给 的思路 。然 而 ,在 现 实 的农 村社 区公共 产 品合作供给过程 中,常常会因为农村社区居 民基于 个体理性 出发导致不合作 的局面 ,从而陷入 “ 囚 徒 困境 ” ,不 利 于农 村公 共产 品提供 。
区域公共物品政府供给的博弈分析

区域公共物品政府供给的博弈分析作者:徐君君来源:《价值工程》2010年第14期摘要: 区域公共物品是一种特殊的公共物品,不仅具有公共物品的一般属性,还具有其自身特殊属性。
正是由于区域公共物品的这些特性,区域内地方政府在供给区域公共物品时容易陷入“囚徒困境”,导致区域公共物品供给不足,阻碍区域经济一体化的发展。
本文运用博弈分析原理,对区域公共物品供给不足进行了分析,认为区域公共物品供给不足除了区域公共物品的特性以外,政府的有限理性和信息不对称也是导致区域公共物品供给不足的重要因素,并就区域公共物品供给不足提出一些政策建议。
Abstract: Regional public goods is a special kind of public goods. It not only has the general properties of public goods, but also has its own special properties. Just because of these characteristics of regional public goods, l ocal governments in the region are easy to fall into” prisoner’ dilemma” when they supply regional public goods. This leads to inadequate supply of regional public goods and inhibits the development of regional economic integration. This article analyzes the inadequate supply of regional public goods by the tool of the game theory and concludes that in addition to the characteristics of regional public goods, the government's limited rationality and asymmetric information are also important factors to contribute to the inadequate supply of regional public goods. At last, the article makes some policy recommendations to resolve the inadequate supply.关键词: 区域公共物品;区域性;囚徒困境;博弈Key words: regional public goods;regional;prisoner’s dilemma;game中图分类号:F224.32 文献标识码:A文章编号:1006-4311(2010)14-0115-020引言区域公共物品是一个区域经济发展的重要推动力,完善的区域公共物品供给体系可以有效地节约交易成本,提高区域经济运行效率。
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
Public Goods and the Prisoners Dilemma: Experimental Evidence Liam Delaney – Junior SophisterDetective Curran: You like playing Games, don’t you?Catherine Tramell: I have a degree in psychology, it goes with the turf…Games are fun. (Basic Instinct, 1992) Like Ms. Tramell, Liam Delaney is interested in games. In this essay he discusses game theory, experimental economics and what an understanding of psychology can bring to this area. In particular the ”free rider” problem is interpreted in terms of established theory. He then examines how his own experimental findings support these views.In this essay I examine the topic of public goods and demonstrate how the use of experimentation can shed light on many crucial issues, which have, in the past, been the domain of introspection, philosophy and economic theory.The free rider problem results from the fact that public goods are both non-exclusive and non-rivalrous in consumption. Thus, once provided, there are no dividing lines about how the benefits from consumption should be allocated. This leads, in a competitive market, to under-provision, as the rational agent will under-contribute to the costs of provision and free ride off the contribution of others, thus enjoying the benefits of consumption but not accruing the costs. If strict rationality assumptions are imposed and traditional assumptions about agents' utility functions are valid, then pure public goods will not, except by nature, be provided at all in a market system.The notion of the Prisoner’s Dilemma has been employed as a useful analogy to explain the free rider problem. First introduced into the literature by Melvin Dresher and Merrill Flood in 1950, the layout of the Prisoners Dilemma is as follows: Two suspects are charged with a crime. They are placed in separate interview rooms for questioning. Communication between the two is not possible. Each suspect has two choices, either confess or claim innocence. If both confess then both go to prison. If both claim innocence, then both get a lesser jail sentence. However, if one confesses and the other claims innocence then the confessor is rewarded with an even lesser sentence while the unrepentant is given a greater sentence than he would have got had both of them confessed. We are left with a situation where, although the best result for the two comes from them both claiming innocence, the nature of the dilemma makes it optimal for each individual to confess.S TUDENT E CONOMIC R EVIEW 15P UBLIC G OODS AND THE P RISONERS D ILEMMA : E XPERIMENTAL E VIDENCES TUDENT E CONOMIC R EVIEW16Johansson 1 gives an introduction as to how this can be applied to explain market failures. The example he gives takes two individuals that can take up production of a pure public good, which yields to each a benefit of six pounds but costs a total of eight pounds to produce. If the two individuals co-operate, they both earn two pounds, which is the Pareto-efficient outcome. However, if we look at Table 1,keeping the following points in mind1. Communication does not occur2. It is not possible to make binding contracts Table 1:Net benefit Player 1Player 2Both co-operate Player 1 but not Player 2 co-operates Player 2 but not Player 1 co-operates Non-co-operation2-26026-20We see that the dominant strategy for each individual is to not co-operate. Non co-operation is a dominant strategy in that no matter what the other individual does,non co-operation will yield a higher payoff than co-operation. Thus, if each player plays rationally, non co-operation results in gain for neither party.However useful an analogy the Prisoner’s Dilemma may be, we are still a long way from understanding the processes which lead to non co-operation in such situations.Indeed we have yet to establish that non co-operation actually results in practice.The importance of understanding such phenomena cannot be understated. Ledyard gives a particularly eloquent account of the importance of such research:“Some of the most fundamental questions about the organisation ofsociety center around issues raised by the presence of public goods.Can markets provide optimal allocations of public goods such as airpollution or health? How well do current political institutions performin the production and funding of public goods such as spaceexploration and national defence? How far can volunteerism take us in1 Johansson (1991)L IAM D ELANEY attempts to solve world environmental problems? If existinginstitutions, thrown up in the natural evolutionary processes of history,do not produce desirable results, can we discover other organisationalarrangements that would better serve the interests of society? At aneven more fundamental level public goods raise questions about thevery nature of humans. Are we co-operative or selfish?” 2While traditionally such topics would have been subjected to a philosophical or introspective analysis, from the 1950s onwards economists began to make use of experimental methods in order to glean some insight into questions posed by the existence of public goods. Experimental research differs from the traditional non-experimental work in economics in that the scientist has direct influence over the independent variables. This allows for a greater degree of control and increases the confidence with which one can make causal, rather than co-relational inferences. Economics has not generally been viewed as a science which leant itself to experimental methods. As Samuelson and Nordhaus put it:“One possible way of figuring out economic laws is by controlledexperiments. Economists [unfortunately] cannot perform thecontrolled experiments of chemists and biologists because they cannoteasily control other factors. Like astronomers or meteorologists, theygenerally must be content largely to observe.” 3This view has certainly not gone unchallenged and as the pages of modern day journal articles will testify, economics is becoming an increasingly experimental science. The experimental research in to public goods, in particular, now spans volumes. Rather than trying to summarise it all here, the remainder of the essay will be devoted to some excellent examples of how experimental economics continues to shed light on the questions outlined above.We begin by considering the layout of a typical public goods experiment. The basic game runs as follows: A group of students are brought in to a room and given an amount of money to invest. They are told that they may keep the money and not invest it or that they may place a proportion of the money to the group fund. Whatever is in the group fund at the end, the subjects are told, will be doubled up and divided evenly among the group. Thus each participant benefits equally from2 Ledyard (1995)3 Samuelson & Nordhaus (1985)S TUDENT E CONOMIC R EVIEW17P UBLIC G OODS AND THE P RISONERS D ILEMMA : E XPERIMENTAL E VIDENCES TUDENT E CONOMIC R EVIEW18the group contribution, regardless of his/her individual contribution. Furthermore contributions are made simultaneously and the entire process is anonymous and without overt inter-personal communication. At the end of the game, subjects are paid in cash the amount they have earned.We can see that this situation is very similar to the Prisoner’s Dilemma and, like the Prisoner’s Dilemma, the dominant strategy for each individual is to contribute nothing while the Pareto-efficient outcome is for each group member to contribute everything. Thus, in this example, the outcome predicted by individual rationality will lead to the group earning half what it could have earned had co-operation occurred. In practice, however this result seldom occurs.Ledyard gives the following review of what actually occurs in practice in such studies, a review, which is consistent with other reviews of the field.41. In one-shot trials and in the initial stages of finitely repeated trials, subjectsgenerally provide contributions halfway between the Pareto-efficient and the free riding level.2. Contribution declines with repetition, and3. Face to face communication improves the rate of contribution.Thus people are neither completely self-serving nor completely co-operative but begin to converge on to Nash equilibrium towards the end of finitely repeated trials.We can now begin to go beyond the economic theory and ask some questions as to what is actually going on in Prisoner’s Dilemma situations. James Andreoni, a university of Texas professor, is a name synonymous with this type of research. In one of his early experiments 5, Andreoni tested two competing hypotheses, which had been offered to explain the decay effect in public goods experiments. The first is known as the learning hypothesis . This maintains that, in the initial stages of these experiments, subjects are unclear as to the nature of the payoffs involved. With each repetition subjects become gradually more conscious of the fact that it is to their advantage to be non-co-operative and, in this way, behaviour gradually converges on to rational Nash equilibrium strategies.4See, for example, Kim & Walker (1984), pp. 113-49.5 Andreoni (1988)L IAM D ELANEY An equally plausible hypothesis was offered by Nash himself and is known as the strategies hypothesis. For Nash, finitely repeated games are misleadingly named and are, in actuality, just one big game rather than a finite number of separate and distinct games. Thus the subjects are affected not only by information about what the other subjects will do in current rounds. They are also influenced by what they believe will be the effects of their own actions on the behaviour of the other subjects in future rounds. The basic claim of the strategies hypothesis is that subjects contribute relatively generously in earlier rounds in order to promote such behaviour among the other subjects. Once the strategic motivation for doing so is gone i.e. towards the end where it is no longer possible to influence future behaviour, the rate of contribution decreases concomitantly.To test this, Andreoni first devised a standard prisoner’s dilemma game, which took the following format. Subjects were placed in groups of five and given fifty tokens to invest. The choice was to invest tokens privately or publicly. Each token invested privately yielded a return of 5% to the individual. Each token invested publicly yielded a return of 2.5% to each member of the group. Thus with complete co-operation the total group yield will amount to 12.5%. However with completely selfish behaviour the total group yield will only amount to 5%. Using undergraduates as his subject pool, Andreoni replicated the basic result that contributions are initially halfway between free-riding and Pareto-efficient levels and decline with repetition.However, the main purpose of the study was to test the strategies and learning hypotheses. To test the strategies hypothesis he removed the postulated strategic motivation for contribution. He did this by randomly assigning subjects to two groups Partners and Strangers. Subjects assigned to the Partners condition were informed that they would be in the same group for each repetition of the trial. Subjects in the Strangers condition were told that they would be reassigned to different groups with each repetition of the trial and that the likelihood that any two given subjects would be in the same group in different rounds was extremely small. Thus, with the strategic motivation for contribution removed, one would expect initial rates of contribution to be significantly lower in the Strangers condition than in the Partners condition.To test the learning hypothesis Andreoni unexpectedly announced a restart at the end of the tenth (supposedly the last) trial. Subjects were told that the experiment would be repeated under the exact same conditions. Now, if the learning hypothesis is correct then the restart should not significantly affect the rate of contribution in S TUDENT E CONOMIC R EVIEW19P UBLIC G OODS AND THE P RISONERS D ILEMMA : E XPERIMENTAL E VIDENCES TUDENT E CONOMIC R EVIEW20either the Partners or the Strangers condition. Thus contribution rates in Round 1 of the restarted trial should not be significantly different from those in Round 10 of the original game. The restarted game, instead of running for the full ten rounds, was then unexpectedly stopped after three rounds.Andreoni’s results beg many interesting questions as to what is actually going on in these experiments. The strategies hypothesis was found to be unable to account for the decay effect. There was a significant difference in inter-round contribution rates between the Partners and the Strangers, however, in the opposite direction to what the strategies hypothesis would predict. Strangers , who had no strategic motivation to do so, actually contributed more in every round of the trial? Likewise, the “learning” hypothesis could not account for the data. The restart did significantly increase the rate of contribution in both the Partners and the Strangers condition.Had learning been responsible for the decay observed in the first ten rounds, then there is no reason to suppose that subjects would not continue to act selfishly in what was, in effect, the 11th round.One explanation for the results may be that Andreoni focused on the wrong forms of strategy and learning. Perhaps, subjects learn the single-shot equilibrium, hence the low contribution rate on round 10 but do not understand either the backwards induction necessary to understand the full game equilibrium or the nature of the strategies involved. This would explain why contribution rates jump back up in Round 11. Selten and Stocker 6 tested this by running a series of super-games using the same subjects. They found the same restart phenomena even after 25 runs of the super-game listed above. As Andreoni points out, once free-rider effects are given close experimental study, the results defy the neat categories of economic theory. A large body of experimental research exists which attempts to explain the free rider phenomenon in terms of non-standard behaviour. Some of this research is beginning to yield both theoretical and practical significance.Experimental work on the provision of public goods has yielded valuable information about the conditions under which voluntary co-operative behaviour will occur. Andreoni 7 showed that in standard dictator games i.e. where one person has a choice to maximise his/her benefit at the expense of others, there were significant interaction effects between the degree of selfishness and the gender of the dictator.Thus while there was no linear relation, it was found that males were more likely to6Selten & Stoeker (1986)7 Andreoni (1999)L IAM D ELANEYS TUDENT E CONOMIC R EVIEW 21be either completely selfish or completely selfless whereas females were generally found to be egalitarian, distributing the effects of the wealth evenly. The significance of such results for, as Andreoni puts it ‘those who broker in altruism ’i.e. charity organisations, is clear. Practical understanding of co-operative and charitable behaviour can greatly facilitate an increase in its rate of its occurrence.It is through this type of channel that experimental economics is developing in to a flourishing sub-discipline and incorporating many methods and facets of human behaviour that have long been neglected by traditional economic theory. In this regard economics has become closely inter-related with academic sub-disciplines within psychology such as Social Psychology 8 and Learning Theory. Again the increasing volumes of work testify to a union between the two disciplines. As this essay has tried to show this union is essential if we are to understand vital issues such as free rider affects which, although they are made more understandable by economic theory, cannot be explained by resorting to standard rational economic assumptions.As a brief endnote, my own attempt to shed some light on public goods phenomena looked at individual differences in certain personality traits. My aim was to reduce some of the noise in these simulations by trying to establish, a priori, who would be likely to show a high rate of contribution and who would be likely to show a low rate of contribution? The questionnaire measured the personality traits of altruism and concern for money , the questions being taken from a popular test used for recruitment and selection purposes by many firms.9 As it turned out these personality traits did not predict mean contribution rates. The usual decline effect was evident but mean contribution rates were higher in eight of the ten rounds than the subject pool in the Partners condition of Andreoni’s experiment, this probably being due to the greater degree of anonymity in the Andreoni study.8See, for example, Akerlof & Dickens (1982), pp. 307-19 for an excellent example of how “psychological variables ” can be rigorously incorporated into inter-temporal models whilst still guaranteeing the existence of the resulting equilibrium.9 Hunter & Roberts (1989)P UBLIC G OODS AND THE P RISONERS D ILEMMA : E XPERIMENTAL E VIDENCE S TUDENT E CONOMIC R EVIEW 22BibliographyAkerlof, G. & W. T. Dickens (1982) “The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance” in American Economic Review, 3, June.Andreoni, J. (1988) “Why Free Ride? Strategies and Learning in Public Goods Experiments” in Journal of Public Economics , 37, pp. 291-304.Andreoni, J. (1999) “Which is the Fair Sex?” “Gender Differences in Altruism”.Available from James Andreoni official website.Johansson, P.O. (1991) An Introduction to Modern Welfare Economics . Cambridge University Press: London.Kim, O. & M. Walker (1984) “The Free Rider Problem: Experimental Evidence”in Public Choice , 43.Ledyard, John (1995) “Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research” in Kagel, J. and A.E. Roth (eds.) Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton University Press: New York.Samuelson & Nordhaus (1985) in Friedman, D. & S. Sunder (eds.) (1994)Experimental Methods: A Primer for Economists. Cambridge University Press:London.Selten, R & R. Stoeker (1986) “ End Behaviour in Sequences of Finite Prisoner’s Dilemma Supergames: A Learning Theory Approach” in Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization.。