Strategic Trade Policy with Endogenous Choice of Quality and Asymmetric Costs

合集下载

DepartmentofEconomicsUniversityofWisconsin…

DepartmentofEconomicsUniversityofWisconsin…

Amit Gandhi/~agandhiDepartment of Economics University of Wisconsin-Madison Phone: (608) 262-0488 Fax: (608) 262-20331180 Observatory DriveMadison, WI 53706-1393 ****************.eduEducationPh.D., Economics, University of Chicago, 2007M.B.A., University of Chicago, 2007B.S., Mathematics, University of Michigan at Ann-Arbor, 1999Thesis Title: Identifying Risk Preferences using Betting Markets (Chair: Philip Reny)EmploymentAssociate Professor (with tenure), University of Wisconsin-MadisonAssistant Professor, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 2007- 2013Visiting Assistant Professor, Yale University, Fall Semester 2010Visiting Assistant Professor, Northwestern University, Winter Quarter 2011TeachingPrinciples of Microeconomics, Graduate Industrial Organization, and Behavioral Economics.AwardsStuart W. McCroskey Fellow in Economics, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 2007-2009Graduate School Fellowship, University of ChicagoResearch SupportNational Science Foundation Grant for “Nonparametric Identification and Estimation of Distributions of Unobserved Heterogeneity in Economic Choice Models using Mixtures” (NSF-0922046), 09/23/2009Research PapersPublished and Forthcoming Papers“Does Belief Heterogeneity Explain Asset Prices” (with Ricardo Serrano-Padial), June 2013, Forthcoming at Review of Economic Studies“Connected Substitutes and the Invertibility of Demand” (with Steven Berry and Phil Haile), Econometrica, September 2013, 81(5), 2087-2111*“Identification and Inference in Ascending Auctions with Correlated Private Values” (with Andres Aradillas-Lopez and Daniel Quint), Econometrica, March 2013, 81(2), 489-534*“Identifying Preferences Under Risk from Discrete Choices” (with Pierre Andre Chiappori, Bernard Salanie, and Francois Salanie), American Economic Review (P&P), 2008, 98, 146-150“Post-Merger Product Repositioning” (with Luke Froeb, Steven Tschantz, and Greg Werden), Journal of Industrial Economics, March 2008, Volume 56 (1), 49-67*Papers Under Review and Revision“On the Identification of Production Functions: How Heterogeneous is Productivity” (with Salvador Navarro and David Rivers), Oct 2013, revised and resubmit (2nd round) at Journal of Political Economy“Nonparametric Identification and Estimation of Random Coefficients in Multinomial Choice Models” (with Jeremy Fox), Aug 2013, revised and resubmitted to RAND Journal of Economics“A Simple Test for Moment Inequality Models with an Application to English Auctions” (with Andres Aradillas-Lopez and Daniel Quint), September 2013, under review“From Aggregate Betting Data to Individual Risk Preferences” (with Pierre Andre Chiappori, Bernard Salanie, and Francois Salanie), October 2012, revise and resubmit at Econometrica“Identification and Estimation in Discrete Choice Demand Models when Endogenous Variables Interact with the Error” (with Kyoo-il Kim and Amil Petrin), Oct 2012, revise and resubmit at EconometricaWorking Papers“Robust Inference of Strategic Interactions in Static Games” (with Andres Aradillas-Lopez), January 2013“Estimating Demand for Differentiated Products with Error in Market Shares” (with Xiaoxia Shi and Zhentong Lu), January 2013“Identifying Demand with Multidimensional Unobservables: A Random Functions Approach (with Jeremy Fox), October 2011“Negative Advertising and Political Competition” (with Daniela Iorio and Carly Urban), June 2012 “The Stochastic Response Dynamic: Computing Nash Equilibrium using MCMC”, 2006, (permanent working paper)Invited Seminar Presentations(2006-2007) University of Chicago, UCLA, Yale, Boston University, University of Southern California, University of Virginia, University of Pennsylvania (Wharton), Georgetown, University of Wisconsin-Madison(2007-2008) Columbia University(2008-2009) New York University (Economics Dept), University College London, Toulouse School of Economics, University of Minnesota(2009-1010) University of Michigan , MIT, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee, Duke, University of Chicago(2010-2011) Harvard Econometrics workshop, UCL, Yale, Northwestern(2011-2012) Chicago Booth, Carnegie Mellon, NYU-Stern, Caltech, UCLA, LSE(2012-2013) Princeton, Michigan, UVA, FTC(2013-2014) Toulouse University, Mannheim University, University of Zurich, Vanderbilt University, Pennsylvania State University, Harvard IO workshopInvited Conference PresentationsNSF/CEME Decentralization Conference, New Orleans, LA, April 2008World Congress on Economic Accounts and Economic Performance Measures, Washington DC, May 2008Cowles Foundation Conference on Identification of Economic Models, Yale University, June 2008 Cowles Foundation Conference on Structural Microeconomics, Yale University, June 20082nd Annual “Center on Auctions, Procurement, and Competition Policy” Conference, Penn State, March 2009Stanford Institute for Theoretical Economics (SITE), Stanford University, June 2009Cowles Foundation Conference on Nonseparable Models with Endogeneity, Yale University, June 2010Cowles Foundation Conference on Structural Microeconomics, Yale University, June 2010Econometrics of Demand Conference, MIT, May 2011Cowles Foundation Conference on Econometric Models of Strategic Interaction, Yale University, June 2011Consumer Behavior and Welfare Measurement, Insitute of Fiscal Studies, University College London, December 20112nd Workshop on Structural Approaches to Productivity and Industry Dynamics, Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance – Rome, Italy, April 2012Cowles Foundation Conference on Structural Empirical Microeconomic Models, Yale University, June 20121st Annual Hal White Antitrust Conference, Bates-White in Washington DC, June 20134th Annual Conference on Internet Search and Innovation, Northwestern University, June 2013Mini-Course on “Recent Developments in Industrial Organization” (3 Lectures), KU Leuven, (being scheduled)Invited Session on Empirical Analysis of Auctions for Asian Econometric Society Meetings, National University of Singapore, August 2013Organized session at 2014 Econometric Society Winter Meetings, “Identification and Estimation of Models of Nonseparable Models with Endogeneity”, Philadelphia, PA.Professional ServiceProgram Committee, 2013 North American Summer Meeting of the Econometric Society Refereeing for Journals: Econometrica, Journal of Political Economy, Review of Economic Studies, American Economic Review, RAND Journal of Economics, Journal of Econometrics, Quantiative Economics, AEJ Journal: Microeconomics Journal, Journal of Industrial Economics, Journal of Business Economics and Statistics, Journal of Applied Econometrics, International Economic Review, Review of Economics and Statistics, Economic Journal, Economic Letters, B.E. Journal of Economics. National Science FoundationDepartment and University ServiceJunior Faculty Recruiting (2007F-2008S), Library Representative (2007F-2010S), Faculty Senator-Alternative (2007F-2009S), Graduate Admissions and Aid (2009F-2013S), Coordinator of the Industrial Organization Workshop (2007F-2013S)。

战略性贸易政策

战略性贸易政策

贸易活动的依据。由于实行这种贸易政策的产业对
象和约束条件比“利润转移”理论要宽泛一些,因 此一般称其为“广义战略性贸易政策理论”。
13
战略性贸易政策的应用
政府大力支持战略产业的发展。技术、知识密集型产业,比 如计算机和信息产业等,产业关联极强,外部经济效益明显, 一旦成为主导产业,就能对社会经济发展起到巨大的推动作用。
8
(2)如果进口国决定开始实 施政府贸易政策干预战略,即 对从外国垄断厂商那里进口的 商品征收数量为CT的关税, 这就使外国垄断厂商的边际成 本提高到TT曲线,新的边际 成本曲线与边际收益曲线的交 点也由原来的A点移动到了B 点。 在此新的均衡中,外国垄 断厂商的出口产品在进口国市 场上的价格也由原来的P1上升 到P2,进口国的进口量下降。 在图6.1中,由于需求曲线 D比边际收益曲线MR更加平 坦,则进口国政府征收关税后 价格上升的幅度PlP2小于所征 收关税的幅度CT,从而改善 了进口国的贸易条件(注1)。 注释1:进口国对从外国垄断厂商进口的商品 征收关税后,贸易条件能否得到改善关键取决 于需求曲线和边际收益曲线的斜率。如果需求 曲线比边际收益曲线更加陡峭,则进口国征收 关税可能会导致价格更大幅度的提高,从而使 贸易条件会因关税而恶化。

政府协助企业争夺出口市场。在不完全竞争的条件下,政府 对本国出口企业的鼓励,能够增强企业的国际竞争优势,扩大 市场份额,获得规模经济效益,争得更多的出口利润。

政府限制进口以培育本国进口竞争产业的竞争能力。由于垄 断和规模经济的存在,贸易保护可以促使本国的进口竞争产业 成为出口产业。

14
7


根据图6.1所示,进口国面 对外国垄断出口厂商所供应商 品的需求曲线为D,与该需求 曲线相对应的边际收益曲线是 MR,CC为外国垄断厂商的边 际成本曲线(假定外国垄断厂 商的边际成本不变)。 那么,根据进口国是否实 施了政府干预,存在以下两种 不同的市场竞争态势: (I)在进口国没有实施政府 贸易政策干预的情况下,外国 垄断厂商在进口国市场上会拥 有一定的垄断力量。该垄断厂 商在追求利润最大化的目标下, 将销往进口国的产品价格定为 高于边际成本的Pl水平上,此 时其在进口国市场上的出口量 确定在其产品的边际收益等于 边际成本的水平上,均衡点为 A。

国经课后习题-精选

国经课后习题-精选
11
2. Unlike the mercantilists, Adam Smith maintained that:
• a. Trade benefits one nation only at the expense of another nation
• b. Government control of trade leads to maximum economic welfare
• Answer: d
4
• 5 Free traders maintain that an open economy is advantageous in that it provides all of the following except:
• a. Increased competition for world producers • b. A wider selection of products for consumers • c. The utilization of the most efficient production
• d. Consumer welfare in both countries, but not total production of both products
• Answer: b
16
7. International trade is based on
the notion that:
• a. Different currencies are an obstacle to international trade
• b. Goods are more mobile internationally than are resources

国际贸易策略英语作文

国际贸易策略英语作文

国际贸易策略英语作文Title: International Trade Strategies: Navigating Global Markets。

In today's interconnected world, international trade strategies play a pivotal role in shaping the economic landscape of nations. Effective trade policies not only stimulate economic growth but also foster diplomatic relations and promote global stability. This essay delves into the significance of international trade strategies and explores various approaches adopted by nations to navigate the complexities of global markets.Firstly, embracing free trade agreements (FTAs) is a common strategy employed by many nations to bolster their economic prospects. FTAs facilitate the exchange of goods and services between countries by reducing tariffs and other trade barriers. For instance, the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) paved the way for increased trade among the United States, Canada, and Mexico, leading toeconomic benefits for all parties involved. By enteringinto such agreements, countries can tap into new markets, attract foreign investment, and enhance competitiveness on a global scale.However, it's essential to strike a balance between the benefits of free trade and protecting domestic industries from unfair competition. This brings us to the second strategy: implementing trade barriers when necessary. Tariffs, quotas, and subsidies are tools that governments use to shield domestic industries from foreign competition or address trade imbalances. While these measures may provide short-term relief to domestic producers, overreliance on protectionism can hinder long-term economic growth and innovation. Therefore, a judicious approach to trade barriers is crucial to ensure a level playing field for both domestic and foreign businesses.Furthermore, fostering innovation and investing in human capital are integral components of a robust trade strategy. In today's knowledge-based economy, nations must focus on developing high-value-added goods and services tomaintain a competitive edge in global markets. Thisrequires investments in research and development, education, and skills training to nurture a talented workforce capable of driving innovation and adapting to evolving market trends. Singapore's success as a global trading hub can be attributed in part to its emphasis on innovation and human capital development, which have propelled the country tothe forefront of industries such as biotechnology, finance, and logistics.Another aspect of effective trade strategies is the promotion of sustainable development and environmental conservation. As the world grapples with climate change and resource depletion, there is growing recognition that trade policies must align with environmental goals. Embracing renewable energy, promoting sustainable agriculture, and adopting eco-friendly manufacturing practices are essential steps toward achieving both economic prosperity and environmental sustainability. The European Union'sstringent environmental regulations and green initiatives serve as a model for integrating environmental considerations into trade policies, thereby fosteringsustainable growth and mitigating the adverse impacts of globalization.In conclusion, international trade strategies are indispensable tools for navigating the complexities of global markets and fostering economic prosperity. By embracing free trade agreements, implementing judicious trade barriers, investing in innovation and human capital, and promoting sustainable development, nations can position themselves for success in the ever-evolving global economy. However, it is imperative to strike a balance between openness to trade and protection of domestic interests while ensuring that trade policies are aligned with broader societal goals such as environmental sustainability and social equity. Only through concerted efforts and strategic planning can countries harness the full potential of international trade to create a more prosperous and interconnected world.。

2014年对外经济贸易大学翻译硕士考研真题

2014年对外经济贸易大学翻译硕士考研真题

育明教育孙老师整理,来育明教于赠送资料,更多真题可咨询孙老师。

对外经济贸易大学2014年MTI考研真题I.Phrase Translation1.Anti-Dumping Duty Order反倾销税令2.counter trade对销贸易3.holding company控股公司4.working capital营运资本,流动资金5.contingency fund应急费用6.par value票面价值w of diminishing marginal utility边际效用递减/规律8.treasury bills(美国或英国的)短期国库券9.zero sum game零和博弈,又称零和游戏10.niche market利基市场11.即期汇票sight draft,demand draft12.资本流动性mobility of capital13.抵押贷款Mortgage Loan14.指令经济Command economy15.机会成本opportunity cost16.远期汇率forward rate17.最低限价floor price18.金融租赁公司Financial leasing company19.微信WeChat20.雾霾haze21.MOOC网络公开课(Massive Open Online Courses)22.TPP跨太平洋战略经济伙伴协议(Trans-Pacific Partnership)23.CAFTA东盟自由贸易区(China-ASEAN Free Trade Area)24.CFR成本加运费(Cost and Freight)25.GSP普及特惠税制度(Generalized System Of Preferences)26.ICC国际商会(International Chamber of Commerce)27.ITC国际贸易委员会(International Trade Commission)28.SBA小企业管理局(Small Business Administration)29.UNCTAD联合国贸易和发展会议(United Nations Conference on Trade and Development)AID美国国际开发署(United States Agency for International Development)ⅡPassage Translatron(120points)Section One:Translate the following English passage into Chinese. Write your answers on the ANSWER SHEET(60points).Global financial stability has improved over the past six months, bolstered by better macroeconomic performance and continued accommodative macroeconomic policies,but fragilities remain.Thetwo-speed recovery-modest in advanced economies and robust in emerging market economies-has posed different policy challenges for countries. In advanced economies hit hardest by the crisis,governments and households remain heavily indebted,to varying degrees,and the health of financial institutions has not recovered in tandem with the overall economy.Emerging market economies are facing new challenges associated with strong domestic demand,rapid credit growth,relatively accommodative macroeconomic policies,and large capital infl.ows. Geopolitical risks could also threaten the economic and financial outlook,with oil prices increasing sharply amid fears of supply disruptions in the Middle East and North Africa.The main task facing policymakers in advanced economies is to shift the balance of policies away from reliance on macroeconomic ar,d liquidity support to more structural policies-less“leaning”and more “cleaning of the financial system.This vnll entail reducing leverage and restoring market discipline,while avoiding financial or economic disruption during the transition.Thus,ongoing policy efforts to withdraw(implicit)public guarantees and ensure bondholder liability for future losses must build on more rapid progress toward stronger bank balance sheets,ensuring medium-term fiscal sustainability and addressing excessive debt burdens in the private sector.For policymakers in emerging market economies,the task is to limit overheating and a buildup of vulnerabilities-to avoid“cleaning”later.Emerging market economies have continued to benefit from strong growth relative to that in advanced economies,accompanied by increasing portfolio capital inflows.This is putting pressure on some financial markets,contributing to higher leverage,potential asset price bubbles,and inflationary pressures.Policymakers will have to pay increasing attention to containing the buildup of macro-financial risks to avoid future problems that could inhibit their growth and damage financial stability.In a number of cases,this will entail a tighter macroeconomic policy stance,and,when needed,the use of macro-prudential tools to ensure financial stability.Increasing the financial sector’s capacity to absorb higher flows through efforts to broaden and deepen local capital markets will also help.Section Two:Translate the following Chinese passage into English.Write your answers on the ANSWER SHEET(60 points).中意两国都是拥有悠久历史和灿烂文化的文明古国。

与贸易有关的投资措施协议(中英文对照)

与贸易有关的投资措施协议(中英文对照)

AGREEMENT ON TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURESMembers,Considering that Ministers agreed in the Punta del Este Declaration that "Following an examination of the operation of GATT Articles related to the trade restrictive and distorting effects of investment measures, negotiations should elaborate, as appropriate, further provisions that may be necessary to avoid such adverse effects on trade";Desiring to promote the expansion and progressive liberalisation of world trade and to facilitate investment across international frontiers so as to increase the economic growth of all trading partners, particularly developing country Members, while ensuring free competition;Taking into account the particular trade, development and financial needs of developing country Members, particularly those of the least-developed country Members;Recognizing that certain investment measures can cause trade-restrictive and distorting effects;Hereby agree as follows:与贸易有关的投资措施协定各成员,考虑到部长们在《埃斯特角城宣言》中同意“在审查与投资措施的贸易限制作用和扭曲作用有关的GATT条款的运用情况之后,谈判应酌情详述为避免此类对贸易的不利影响而可能需要的进一步规定”;期望促进世界贸易的扩大和逐步自由化,便利跨国投资,以便提高所有贸易伙伴、特别是发展中国家成员的经济增长,同时保证自由竞争;考虑到发展中国家成员、特别是最不发达国家成员特殊的贸易、发展和财政需要;认识到某些投资措施可能产生贸易限制作用和扭曲作用:特此协议如下:Article 1CoverageThis Agreement applies to investment measures related to trade in goods only (referred to in this Agreement as "TRIMs").第1条范围本协定仅适用于与货物贸易有关的投资措施(本协定中称“TRIMs”)。

国际贸易简答essay

CHAPTER 1—THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY AND GLOBALIZATION SHORT ANSWER1. What is the most important factor which contributes to competitiveness?ANS:Key to the concept of competitiveness is productivity, or output per worker hour.PTS: 12. What are the challenges of the international trading system?ANS:Among the challenges that the international trading system faces are dealing with fair laborstandards and concerns about the environment.PTS: 1ESSAY1. Does exposure to competition with the world leader in a particular industry improve a firm'sproductivity?ANS:The McKinsey institute found that higher productivity rested on the ability of mangers to invent new and ever more efficient ways of making products and on the ability of engineers to design products that are easy to make. The institute researchers observed that in the auto industry in Japan or the food industry in the United States, managers and engineers do not achieveinnovations because they are smarter work harder or are better educated than their peers. They do so because they are subjected to intense global competition, where improving laborproductivity is the key to success.PTS: 12. What are the essential arguments in favor of free trade?ANS:Proponents of an open trading system contend that international trade results in higher levels of consumption and investment, lower prices of commodities, and a wider range of productchoices for consumers. Trade also enables workers to become more productive, and wages of workers whose skills are more scarce internationally tend to rise.PTS: 1CHAPTER 2—FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGESHORT ANSWER1. Is it possible to add up the preferences of all consumers in an entire nation?ANS:No. It is impossible to make interpersonal comparisons of satisfaction, and thus it is notpossible to add up preferences.PTS: 12. Who gains more from trade, when nations are of unequal economic size?ANS:If one nation is significantly larger than the other, the larger nation attains fewer gains from trade, while the smaller nation captures most of the gains from trade.PTS: 13. Is it possible for comparative advantage to change, thus changing the direction of trade?ANS:Lagging productivity growth may cause a country to lose its comparative advantage. In a two-product, two-country model, this would change the direction of trade.PTS: 14. Do national security concerns lead to incomplete specialization?ANS:Yes. National security concerns may lead a country to produce some of the commodity in which it has comparative disadvantage, thus leading to incomplete specialization.PTS: 1ESSAY1. Will it be impossible to keep low-skilled jobs in the U.S.?ANS:If tax credits or other incentives are made available to U.S. companies, it would be possible for those companies to invest in training or technology for low-skilled workers. That wouldimprove the efficiency of the workers. Such improvements in productivity can more than outweigh the wage advantage that is enjoyed by low-skilled workers overseas. New Balance Athletic Shoe Co. Inc., headquartered in Boston, Massachusetts, has been successful inretaining low-skilled production in the United States by increasing worker productivity.PTS: 12. Is it possible to estimate the gains from trade?ANS:When a nation trades, it enjoys a larger income, owing to a wider range of goods available to consumers. Trade also has a positive influence on productivity levels. However, it is extremely difficult to measure these gains, since it requires knowledge of what a nation's imports would cost if it produced them itself, instead of purchasing them from a less expensive source abroad.PTS: 1CHAPTER 3—SOURCES OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGESHORT ANSWER1. Does factor price equalization occur in the real world?ANS:In the real world, differences in factor prices tend to exist. Different technologies, imperfect markets, transportation costs, and trade barriers may prevent factor prices from equalizingamong nations.PTS: 12. What is the focus of the product life cycle theory, and where is it applicable?ANS:The product life cycle theory focuses on the role of technological innovation as a keydeterminant of trade patterns. It applies to manufactured goods.PTS: 1ESSAY1. Explain how immigration and trade may worsen wage inequality, and how college educationmay mitigate against that.ANS:Trade tends to increase the demand for skilled workers relative to unskilled workers, thusworsening wage inequality. Immigration of unskilled workers decreases the supply of skilled workers relative to unskilled workers, thus worsening wage inequality. Alternatively, college education increases the supply of skilled workers relative to unskilled workers, thus reducing wage inequality.PTS: 12. How does Staffan Linder explain world trade patterns?ANS:Linder offers two explanations of world trade patterns. Trade in primary products conforms well to the factor-endowment theory. However, trade in manufactured goods is best explained by overlapping demand structures among nations. For manufactured goods, the basis for trade is stronger when the structure of demand in two nations is more similar, due to similarper-capita incomes.PTS: 1CHAPTER 4—TARIFFSSHORT ANSWER1. Can import duties have unintended side effects?ANS:Yes. Duties may discourage a company from importing goods in amounts large enough to take advantage of quantity discount pricing. Also, up-front payment of these duties may imposefinancial hardships on importers.PTS: 12. What happens to effective protection when the value added by the domestic producer declines?ANS:The degree of effective protection increases.PTS: 1ESSAY1. Is it possible for a low nominal tariff rate to understate the effective rate of protection? What istariff escalation?ANS:Yes. In some countries, the effective rate of protection is more than twice the nominal rate. The effective rate of protection takes into account the effects of tariffs levied on raw materials and intermediate goods. Tariff structures of industrialized nations have generally beencharacterized by rates that give greater protection to intermediate and finished products than to primary commodities. This is referred to as tariff escalation.PTS: 12. How can tariffs be justified?ANS:Tariffs are justified on the grounds that they protect domestic employment and wages, helpcreate a level playing filed for international trade, equate the cost of imported products with the cost of domestically produced goods, and allow domestic industries to be insulated temporarily from foreign competition until they can grow and develop or protect industries necessary for national security.PTS: 1CHAPTER 5—NONTARIFF TRADE BARRIERSSHORT ANSWER1. Is a tariff-rate quota a two-tier tariff? Why?ANS:Yes. It allows a specified number of goods to be imported at one tariff rate, whereas anyimports above this level face a higher tariff rate.PTS: 12. What is an OMA?ANS:An OMA involves limitations on export sales administered by one or more exporting nations.PTS: 1ESSAY1. Describe some of the differences between tariffs and quotas?ANS:Tariffs and quotas differ in their revenue effects and restrictive impacts on the volume of trade.While quotas are easier to administer and manage, they do not provide the government with revenue.PTS: 12. What are the intent and impact of domestic content requirements?ANS:Domestic content requirements try to limit the practice of job outsourcing and also encourage the development of domestic industry. They stipulate the minimum percentage of a product's value that must be produced in the home country for that product to be sold there. Domestic content protection tends to impose welfare losses on the domestic economy in the form ofhigher production costs and higher-priced goods.PTS: 1CHAPTER 6—TRADE REGULATIONS AND INDUSTRIAL POLICIES SHORT ANSWER1. What is the essential idea behind strategic trade policy?ANS:The essential notion underlying strategic trade policy is imperfect competition.PTS: 12.What is the basis for trade adjustment assistance?ANS:The rationale of trade adjustment assistance is that if society in general enjoys welfare gains from the increased efficiency stemming from trade liberalization, some sort of compensation should be provided for those who are temporarily injured by import competition.PTS: 1ESSAY1. Has industrial policy contributed significantly to Japan's economic growth?ANS:The extent to which industrial policy has contributed to Japan's economic growth is unclear.Japan has benefited from a high domestic savings rate, an educated and highly motivated labor force, good labor management relations, a shift of labor from low-productivity sectors tohigh-productivity manufacturing, entrepreneurs willing to assume risks, and the like. Thesefactors have enhanced Japan's transformation from a low-technology nation to ahigh-technology nation. It is debatable how rapidly this transformation would have occurred in the absence of an industrial policy. Although Japan has the most visible industrial policy of the industrial nations, the importance of that policy to Japan should not be exaggerated.PTS: 12. Explain how advocates of strategic trade policy differ from the classical free traders in theirtreatment of externalities?ANS:Advocates of strategic trade policy recognize that the classical argument for free trade considered externalities at length. The difference, they maintain, is that the classical theory was based on perfect competition and thus could not appreciate the most likely source of the externality, whereas modern theories based on imperfect competition can. The externality in question is the ability of companies to capture the fruits of expensive innovation. Classical theory based on perfect competition neglected this factor because large fixed costs are involved in innovation and research and development, and such costs ensure that the number of competitors in an industry will be small.PTS: 1CHAPTER 7—TRADE POLICIES FOR THE DEVELOPING NATIONS SHORT ANSWER1. What are some major trade problems faced by developing nations?ANS:Trade problems include lack of diversification of economies, unstable export markets,declining terms of trade over time, and lack of access to markets of advanced countries.PTS: 12. Are economic downturns helpful to cartels?ANS:No they are generally problematic for cartels. As market sales dwindle in a weakeningeconomy, profits fall. Cartel members may conclude that they can escape serious decreases in profits by reducing prices, in expectation of gaining sales at the expense of other cartelmembers.PTS: 1ESSAY1. What are some of the growth strategies that have been employed by the developing nations?How successful are these strategies?ANS:Besides attempting to stabilize commodity prices, developing nations have promoted internal industrialization through policies of import substitution and export promotion. Countriesemphasizing export promotion have tended to realize higher rates of economic growth thancountries emphasizing import-substitution policies.PTS: 12. Describe the flying-geese pattern of economic growth? What countries have pursued thisstrategy?ANS:It is widely recognized that East Asian economies have followed the flying-geese pattern of growth. This pattern of growth occurs when countries gradually move up in technologicaldevelopment by following in the pattern of countries ahead of them in the development process.For example, Malaysia and Taiwan take over leadership in apparel and textiles from Japan as Japan moves into higher-technology sectors of automotive and electronic products.PTS: 1CHAPTER 8—REGIONAL TRADING AGREEMENTSSHORT ANSWER1. What is meant by economic integration?ANS:The term refers to the process of eliminating restrictions on international trade, payments, and factor input mobility.PTS: 12. What factors influence the extent of trade creation and trade diversion?ANS:Trade creation and diversion are influenced by the degree of competitiveness thatmember-nation economies have prior to formation of the customs union, the number and size of its members, and the size of its external tariff against non-members.PTS: 1ESSAY1. Explain the theory of optimum currency areas.ANS:Much of the analysis of the benefits and costs of Europe's common currency is based on the theory of an optimum currency area. According to this theory, the gains to be had from sharinga currency across countries' boundaries include more uniform prices; lower transaction costs,greater certainty for investors, and enhanced competition. These gains must be comparedagainst the loss of an independent monetary policy and the option of changing the exchange rate.PTS: 12. Concerning transition economies, what do the advocates of shock therapy propose?ANS:Advocates of shock therapy maintain that economies in transition should proceed immediately on all fronts. That is, they should privatize, abandon price controls, liberalize trade, and develop market institutions, and so on as quickly as possible. Although the initial economic pain may be severe, it will subside as the transition to the market economy leads to rising living standards.PTS: 1CHAPTER 9—INTERNATIONAL FACTOR MOVEMENTS AND MULTINATIONAL ENTERPRISESSHORT ANSWER1. What are the typical ways in which multinational enterprises have diversified their operations?ANS:Multinational enterprises have diversified their operations along vertical, horizontal, andconglomerate lines.PTS: 12. What are Mexican maquiladoras?ANS:Maquiladoras are assemblages of foreign-owned companies that use foreign parts and Mexican assembly to produce goods that are exported to the United States.PTS: 1ESSAY1.Are there any differences between the theory of multinational enterprises and conventionaltrade theory?ANS:There are major differences. The conventional model assumes that commodities are tradedbetween independent, competitive businesses. However, multinational enterprises are oftenvertically integrated businesses with substantial intrafirm sales. Also, multinational enterprises may use transfer pricing to maximize overall company profits of any single subsidiary.PTS: 12. What are the disadvantages of forming joint ventures?ANS:A joint venture is a cumbersome organization compared with a single organization. Control isdivided, creating problems of "two masters." Success or failure depends on how wellcompanies work together despite having different objectives, corporate cultures and ways of doing things. The action of corporate chemistry is hard to predict, but it is critical becausejoint-venture agreements usually provide both partners an ongoing role in management. When joint-venture ownership is divided equally, as often occurs, deadlocks in decision making can take place. Even when negotiated balance is achieved, it can be upset by changing corporate goals or personnel.PTS: 1。

中国对外贸易政策的政治经济分析

中文摘要崇尚自由贸易政策的纯贸易理论与现实中的贸易干预和扭曲政策之间形成鲜明的反差,近年来发展起来的贸易的政治经济学理论将公共选择的分析范示引入传统贸易理论,从政策决策过程的角度去探求贸易扭曲政策存在的真正原因,这一贸易政策内生化的理论增强了人们对作为公共政策形式之一的贸易政策的“科学”认识。

本文利用国际贸易政治经济学的方法论和概念框架分析中国对外贸易政策制定的政府行为、决策过程和制度约束,考察的对象包括贸易发展战略、进口和出口贸易政策体制、贸易自由化进程以及中国的多边、地区和双边贸易关系,并以中国工业行业的保护结构为重点研究中央政府、利益团体、公众和世界贸易体系对贸易政策决策的影响。

本文的根本目的并非着重于提出中国贸易政策的最优方式,而是在于如何认识和理解其贸易政策的产生和实施过程。

本文共分为九章。

第一章为导言,阐述写作的背景、主题、目的和篇章结构。

第二章文献评述从贸易的政治经济学的问题的提出出发,对近十多年来该领域理论研究和实证研究发展的脉络进行了总结,并对不同分支研究的基本观点、基础模型、方法论、技术特点和结论进行了比较和综合性的学术评论。

第三章首先利用政治学理论中结构─功能论和系统论的方法勾画出中国经济政策决策的一般政府过程框架,并结合中国政治体制的特点对框架中的不同环节进行了剖析,从而描述了中国经济政策决策的宏观政治制度本质、特征以及中国经济改革的政治经济学,为分析贸易政策提供广阔的时空背景。

ass="MsoNormal" style="text-indent:21.75pt">第四、五、六章首先勾勒和描述了中国贸易政策决策的总体框架结构,然后分别从国家目标和权威、利益团体和外国政府及国际贸易制度约束三个层面对中国贸易的公共选择问题进行了详尽的阐述,分析了它们各自的行为动机、行为方式和行为绩效。

其中涉及了大量的部门、政策和机构的案例分析,力图从一个比较广阔的视角来展现中国贸易政策决策和执行的现实情况。

主要的贸易保护理论

01
03
02
Analysis
2、最优关税的说明
W
t
0
A
C
B
t*
tH
最优关税(t*)应该在零关税和禁止性关税(tH)之间。
当关税达到最优关税时,本国的福利水平达到最大化.此时,征税国因贸易条件改善而带来的边际收益正好等于征税而产生的生产扭曲和消费扭曲所带来的边际损失.
? A,B.C三点的含义
Appraisal
1、此观点在发展中国家比在发达国家更适用(因为其资本市场不成熟);在历史上具有较大贡献。 此理论可以说是发展中国家进口替代政策 (Import substitute policy)的理论基础。 2、很难确定哪些是幼稚工业,经验表明,一旦给予保护就很难取消; 3、发展幼稚产业不一定要关税或配额等贸易保护手段 ,事实上采用直接生产补贴和减免税更可取。 生产补贴只会导致生产扭曲,而不会造成消费扭曲,因此保护成本更低; 生产补贴和减免税是国内政策,较少受到本国参与的国际经贸条约的制约。
二战后主要国家贸易政策的演变(自学)
CH6:代表性的贸易保护观点
6.1 The Optimum Tariff and Retaliation
一、概念(Concept) 最优关税(Optimum tariff):使一国贸易条件改善相对于其贸易量减少的负面影响的净所得最大化的税率。 二、最优关税理论的主要观点(Main View) 大国征收进口关税可改善其贸易条件,这意味着大国可能通过征收最优关税来获得比自由贸易更高的福利水平。 三、分析(Analysis) 四、政策有效性的评价 (Appraisal) 五、案例:20世纪30年代的关税战。
Appraisal(1)
对战略性贸易与产业政策理论质疑与批评 信息不充分问题:极难选择赢家(战略性产业)并设计合适的政策去培育它们 从单一产业来看,无法估计准确的收益矩阵 产业不能隔离时,更难获得全面信息 政府政策可能使某一个产业获得战略优势,却使得其他产业处于战略劣势。 以对手不采取行动为前提; 当一国实施成功时,是以其他国家的损失为代价,因此易引起对方的报复;

西安交通大学国际贸易2005真题及答案(含国际金融)

西安交通大学2005年硕士研究生入学考试试题考试科目:国际贸易(含国际金融)科目编号:488考试时间:1月23日下午《国际贸易》(总计100分)一、名词解释(每小题3分,共6小题,合计18分)1.国际分工2.产业内贸易3.绿色壁垒4.战略性贸易政策5.区域经济一体化6.WTO二、简答题(每小题10分,共5小题,合计50分)1.二战后国际贸易迅速发展的原因及特点。

2.试用图示“国际贸易中产品生命周期的动态变化”。

3.国家竞争优势理论与比较优势理论的联系与区别。

4.对外贸易对一国经济发展影响的动态效应。

5.国际服务贸易的主要形式。

三、论述题(32分)非关税壁垒设置与演变对我国对外贸易发展影响的双重性分析。

《国际金融》(总计50分)一、名词解释(每小题2分,共5小题,合计10分)1.official Reserves 2.Absorption Approach 3.Capital Flight4.The Theory of International Indebtedness 5.Interdelivery Spread二、简答题(每小题10分,共2小题,合计20分)1.试析确定一国国际储备水平的理论和模型。

2.简述银行如何进行外汇风险管理。

三、计算分析(每小题10分,共2小题,合计20分)1.简述国际收支的弹性分析法和马歇尔-勒纳条件。

2.应用上述方法并结合J曲线分析下列情形:为了改善贸易收支,荷兰政府决定将其货币贬值10%,即由原来的1美元=2.0荷兰盾调整到1美元=2.2荷兰盾。

若荷兰的出口需求弹性和进口需求弹性分别为1.2和0.5:假定荷兰进出口供给弹性为无穷大,分析货币贬值可能对荷兰贸易收支的改善起多大的作用,其作用的过程将是如何展开的。

  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIESSTRATEGIC TRADE POLICY WITH ENDOGENOUSCHOICE OF QUALITY AND ASYMMETRIC COSTSDongsheng ZhouBarbara J. SpencerIlan VertinskyWorking Paper 7536http://papers/w7536NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH1050 Massachusetts AvenueCambridge Ma 02138February 2000We are grateful to Zhiqi Chen for very helpful ideas, discussions and comments. We would also like to acknowledge useful suggestions received from Professors James Brander and Shelby Brumelle. Financial support was provided by the SSHRC and NSERC. This paper is part of NBER's research program in International Trade and Investment. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research.© 2000 by Dongsheng Zhou, Barbara J. Spencer and Ilan Vertinsky. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.Strategic Trade Policy with Endogenous Choice of Quality and Asymmetric Costs. Dongsheng Zhou, Barbara J. Spencer and Ilan VertinskyNBER Working Paper No. 7536February 2000JEL No. F12, F13ABSTRACTThis paper examines the strategic trade policy incentives for investment policies towards quality improvements in a vertically differentiated exporting industry. Firms first compete in qualities and then export to a third country market based on Bertrand or Cournot competition. Optimal policies are asymmetric across the two producing countries. Under Bertrand competition, the low-quality country subsidizes investment to raise export quality, while the high-quality country imposes a tax so as to reduce the quality of its already high quality exports. Under Cournot competition, the results are reversed with a tax in the low-quality country and a subsidy in the high-quality country.Dongsheng Zhou Barbara J. SpencerFaculty of Business Faculty of CommerceCity University of Hong Kong University of British Columbia83 Tat Chee Avenue, Kowloon2053 Main Mall, VancouverHong Kong B.C. V6T1Z2, Canadamkdszhou@.hk and NBERbarbara.spencer@commerce.ubc.caIlan Vertinsky,Fepa Research Unit, Forest Science CentreUniversity of British Columbia2424 Main MallVancouver B.C. V6T 1Z4fepa@interchange.ubc.caStrategic Trade Policy with Endogenous Choice of Quality and Asymmetric Costs1. IntroductionThe availability of a greater variety of products with increasing levels of world trade has emphasised the importance of non-price competition for success in exporting. At one extreme, there is Japan with its demanding consumers and quality oriented production culture and, at the other, there is the emergence of lower quality, but cost competitive producers among the newly industrialized countries (NICs). Thus success for a company can often involve the careful positioning of products in the quality spectrum taking into account the qualities chosen by foreign rivals. The importance of this strategy is particularly evident in the rapidly expanding, knowledge intensive industries, such as pharmaceuticals and computer software. First, these industries often exhibit high up-front costs of product development with subsequent low variable costs of production. Also, firms tend to be oligopolistic because of limitations on entry due to this cost structure and an ability to patent. In such an environment, the particular features that differentiate products are the main determinants of success1 and a major focus of competition is at the product development stage.There are a number of possible motives for government policy targeted at product quality. In particular, regulations affecting quality, such as minimum quality standards, may simply be a response to the need for consumer protection due to asymmetric information about product quality. Such policies may also be a means to protect domestic industry from import competition2. Other motives, however, are needed to explain the existence of policies targeted at the quality of exports3.1These features can be broadly interpreted as any attributes, including attributes of the production process (e.g. impacts of production on the environment) that consumers care about (see Inglehart 1990).2For example, the U.S. has long complained that Japanese regulations specifying detailed characteristics that particular products must satisfy is discriminatory against imports.3Quality upgrading of exports could be an indirect consequence of growth policies that generally targetTaiwan, for example, has a long standing policy to influence the quality of exports through compulsory inspection of certain export items and the subsidization of quality control associations in some sectors [e.g., machine tools, heavy electrical machinery, umbrellas and toys] (Wade 1990:144]). Korea has also encouraged product quality improvement in some sectors, while, as part of the so called “Northern strategy”, it has also subsidized the marketing of certain low quality products, thus eliminating incentives to improve product quality (Ursacki and Vertinsky 1994). In Finland, the government subsidized product oriented R&D in paper production, offering incentives for climbing the product quality scale in an industry which was already a world leader in the production of high quality papers (Wilson et al. 1998). Subsidies for product quality improvement in the newsprint industry have also been recommended in Canada, despite Canadian leadership in quality (see Binkley 1993).There are various arguments as to why governments might want to raise the quality of exports when quality levels are low. For example, Taiwan may have imposed quality controls to avoid damage to the reputation of all its exports from the export of shoddy goods. There may also be a motive to improve the quality of exports so as to satisfy minimum quality standards in importing countries. However, these arguments do not explain why governments would subsidize quality improvements for firms that are already industry leaders in quality or even discourage the development of quality for their low quality exporters.This paper explores the implications of a “strategic-trade policy” or “rent-shifting” motive4 for subsidy or tax policy applied to investments in quality improvements for exported products. There are two countries, a developed country and an LDC (lesser developed country), each with one firm producing a quality differentiated good. To focus on strategic trade policy effects, we assume4 For the original work, see Spencer and Brander (1983) and Brander and Spencer (1985). Eaton and Grossman (1986) show the importance of Bertrand versus Cournot competition.that the entire production is exported to a third country market on the basis of either Bertrand or Cournot competition. A feature of the model is asymmetry of investment costs. Thus to reflect the disparity in investment opportunities between the LDC and developed country, we assume the LDC faces an equal or lower productivity of investment in quality than the developed country5. If this cost difference is sufficiently large, we are able to show that there exists a unique pure strategy equilibrium in which the LDC exports the low quality product and the developed country the high quality product. However, even if countries are identical as to investment costs, the two countries will produce different qualities of products and have an incentive to pursue asymmetric policies towards the quality of their exports. As we show, under Bertrand price competition, the low quality producer has an incentive to subsidize investment in quality, whereas optimal policy by the high-quality producer involves an investment tax. These policies are reversed under Cournot competition with optimal policy involving a tax by the low quality producer and a subsidy by the high-quality producer. Thus strategic-trade policy can explain why a country might intervene to raise the quality of low quality exports, but it also shows that there are circumstances in which there is a motive for less obvious policies, such as a subsidy to a high-quality producer or a tax on quality development by a low-quality producer.The model structure follows Spencer and Brander (1983), except that government policy affects positioning in product space, rather than levels of cost-reducing investment (in R&D) for products that are fixed in nature6. Thus there is a three stage (full information) game in which governments act first to maximize domestic welfare by committing to their subsidy or tax policy. If both countries intervene, there is a Nash equilibrium in subsidy and tax levels. Firms then commit5For the effects of asymmetric production costs see De Meza (1986) and Neary (1994).6Policy is very different since, for the basic model, it involves an R&D subsidy under both Bertrand and Cournot competition (see Bagwell and Staiger 1994).to their levels of investment in quality and subsequently compete (in quantities or prices). As in Spencer and Brander (1983), the advantages of unilateral tax or subsidy policy to the domestic country accrue from their ability to move the outcome from the Nash equilibrium in quality space to what would have been the Stackelberg equilibrium with the domestic firm as leader and foreign rival as the follower. Thus the policy works by influencing those actions of the rival firm that are taken as given by the domestic firm at the Nash equilibrium.We also explore the implications of coordinated policy choices by the two producing nations so as to maximize their joint welfare. With the elimination of the motive for rent-extraction from the rival firm, this focuses policy towards exploiting consumers in the third country market. Nevertheless, the implications of this for policies towards quality are not immediately obvious. For Bertrand competition, a move from the Nash policies to the jointly optimal policies causes a switch in policies for both countries, namely the LDC should tax rather than subsidize quality and the developed country should subsidize rather than tax quality. Under Cournot competition, the jointly optimal policy is a tax on investment in quality by both countries.Our assumption that the costs of quality development are sunk before the market determination of prices and output is well established in the literature (see for example, Gabszewicz and Thisse 1979, Shaked and Sutton 1982, 1983, Ronen 1991 and Motta 1993). However, international trade theory has mostly concentrated on an alternative model, in which quality is chosen simultaneously with price or output7 (see, for example, Krishna (1987) and Das and Donnenfield (1987, 1989), Ries (993) but Herguera, Kujal and Petrakis (1999) is an exception). Also, the focus of this international literature (including the above papers) differs from ours because of its main7Since quality affects marginal production costs, this simultaneous choice model is sometimes referred to as a “variable cost of quality model”. Similarly, since the cost of quality is fixed when prices and output are determined, the sunk cost model has been referred to as a “fixed cost of quality model”.concern with the effects of domestic import restrictions, particularly the implications with respect to quality upgrading or downgrading8.In addition to the strategic trade policy results, the paper also contributes to the technical development of the quality differentiation model. First, as previously mentioned, we introduce asymmetric costs of development of quality and show existence and uniqueness of equilibrium for a sufficiently large cost difference under both Bertrand and Cournot competition. We also provide analytical proofs of concavity of profit and welfare functions with respect to quality, both for asymmetric costs of investment and for a wider class of investment cost functions than has previously been considered in the literature. Particularly for the Cournot case, numerical equilibrium values have previously been used to help establish concavity (see Motta (1993) and Herguera, Kujal and Petrakis (1999)).The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 sets out the structure of the game and the basic consumer preferences and costs underlying the model of quality choice. Section 3 investigates investment policy and quality choice under Bertrand competition whereas Section 4 develops and contrasts the results for Cournot competition. Finally, section 5 contains concluding remarks. 2. The basic model: consumer demand and costsThere are two firms, firm 1 located in an LDC (lesser developed country) and firm 2, in a developed country. Each firm produces a quality differentiated product, all of which is exported to a third country market. The game between firms involves a sub-game perfect equilibrium with two stages of decision. In stage 1, the quality of each product is determined at a Nash equilibrium in which each firm chooses its investment in quality so as to maximize profit taking the quality of the other firm as given. In stage 2, the products are sold on the basis of a Bertrand-Nash equilibrium if8Feenstra (1988) discusses these two approaches and provides evidence on quality upgrading.9If F(q) = aq n for n 2, then F (q) = naq n-1 > 0 and F (q) = n(n-1)aq n-2 > 0 for q > 0 and F K (q) 0. If F(q)= q(e aq - 1), then F (q) = (1+aq)e aq - 1> 0, F (q) = a(2+aq)e aq > 0 and F K (q) = (a)2(3+aq)e aq > 0 for q > 0. In both cases, F(0) = 0 and F (0) = 0.price is the decision variable or a Cournot-Nash equilibrium if quantity is the decision variable. This two-stage structure reflects the idea that price (or quantity) can be changed more easily than product quality, which is a longer term decision. For simplicity we assume that marginal production costs are constant and, without loss of generality, we let these costs be zero. Governments commit to policy towards investment at stage 0, prior to the game played by firms.The asymmetry in investment costs across countries is reflected by the assumption that firm 2 in the developed country requires an investment F(q) to produce a product with quality q, whereas firm 1, in the LDC requires an investment of F(q) where 1. Otherwise, the two firms are identical for any given value of q. Following Ronnen (1991), we assume F(q) satisfiesF(0) = F (0) = 0; F (q) > 0, F (q) > 0 for q > 0 andF (q) = ; F K (q) 0. (1)lim q →∞Thus the investment cost, F(q), and marginal investment cost F (q) are strictly increasing in quality for all q (0, ]. Since F (q) > 0 and F K (q) 0, F(q) is strictly convex and F (q) is linear or convex. The assumptions F(0) and F (0) help ensure that both firms enter. Two classes of functions satisfying these restrictions 9 are F(q) = aq n for n 2 and F(q) = q(e aq - 1) where a > 0.We use a standard model of quality differentiation (see, for example, Gabszewicz and Thisse 1979, Bond 1988, Das and Donnenfeld 1987, 1989, Tirole 1988 and Motta 1993) in which consumers purchase at most one unit of the differentiated product. Other things being equal, all consumers prefer a higher quality product. Letting represent a taste parameter for quality, there is a continuum of consumers indexed by , which is uniformly distributed on [0,1]. Consumers obtain10 The results can be generalized to any concave utility function u(q), where u (q) > 0, u(q) 0. There are no income effects since, implicitly, utility is assumed to be separable in a second homogeneous good. This homogeneous good also acts behind the scenes to achieve trade balance.a (linear) utility 10, q, from consumption of a good with quality q and price P. Letting p P/q for q > 0, we also adjust the price P to reflect differences in quality. This implies a consumer surplus for taste given by:C s = C s (q,p; ) = q - P = q( - p) for q > 0.(2)Assuming a reservation surplus of zero, consumers purchase the product only if C s > 0, which requires q > 0. Also since [0,1], for any p > 0, there is a range of consumers who choose not to buy the good.The two firms are free to produce the same or different qualities. Referring to the low and high quality firms as firms L and H respectively, although we will subsequently identify firm L as located in the LDC and firm H as in the developed country (see Proposition 1 for the Bertrand case and Proposition 9 for the Cournot case), for the moment we do not specify which of the firms, L or H, is firm 1 or 2. Using the superscripts L and H to indicate variables associated with firms L and H respectively, then the quality-adjusted price is given by p L = P L /q L for the low quality product and p H = P H /q H for the high quality product where q L q H . We also define r q H /q L 1 to represent the ratio of high to low quality.If q L = q H , then both firms can remain in the market only if p L = p H . Since consumers would buy the product for (p, 1], letting x L and x H represent the quantities purchased of qualities q L and q H respectively, this implies an inverse demand,P i = (1 - (x L + x H ))q i for q L = q H and i = L,H.(3)However, similar to Motta (1993), we will show that in equilibrium, qualities differ across firms forCournot as well as Bertrand competition. For q L < q H , let = represent the value of the taste~θparameter at which a consumer would purchase the differentiated good but is indifferent betweenthe high and low quality. Then, setting C s (q L ,p L ; ) = C s (q H ,p H ;) from (2), it follows using r > 1,~θ~θthat:= (P H - P L )/(q H - q L ) = (rp H - p L )/(r - 1).(4)~θThe requirement C s (q H ,p H ;) > 0 implies > p H , and hence consumers with taste ( ,1] buy~θ~θ~θquality q H . Also, since C s (q L ,p L ; ) = q L ( - p L ) > 0 for > p L and since > p H implies > p H > p L~θ~θ(from (4)), there exists a range of taste parameters (p L ,] for which consumers will buy quality~θq L . Consumers for whom [0, p L ] do not purchase the quality differentiated good. Since each consumer buys one or no units of the good, the respective demand functions for the low and high quality products are given byx L = - p L = r(p H - p L )/(r - 1) and x H = 1 - = 1 - (rp H - p L )/(r - 1).(5)~θ~θ3. Investment policy and quality choice under Bertrand competitionAssuming Bertrand price competition at the second stage, the two-stage model of firm behavior involving choice of quality and then sale of the good is developed in subsection 3.1.Policies towards investment in quality are then investigated in 3.2 and 3.3 for the LDC and developed country respectively.3.1. The two-stage model of firm behavior: Bertrand competition.As is standard in these models, we start by examining price determination at the second stage Bertrand equilibrium before considering the first stage choice of quality. Since marginal production cost is assumed to be zero, firms L and H earn profits from production equal to their respective revenues, given by R L = P L x L and R H = P H x H . Thus at stage 2, each firm sets its price to maximize its revenue, taking the price of the other firm as given. Since the qualities q L and q H are committed at the first stage, this is equivalent to choosing quality-adjusted prices, p L = P L /q L for firm L and p H11We have 2R L /( p L )2 = -2q H /(r-1) < 0, 2R H /( p H )2 = -2rq H /(r-1) < 0 and using 2R i /( p L )( p H ) = q H /(r-1) >0 for i = L,H, we obtain 6 ( 2R L /( p L )2)( 2R H /( p H )2) - ( 2R i /( p L )( p H ))2 = (q H )2(4r-1)/(r-1)2 > 0.= P H /q H for firm H. Expressing R L = q L p L ( - p L ) and R H = q H p H (1- ) (from (4) and (5)) and using~θ~θ / p L = -1/(r-1) and / p H = r/(r-1), it follows that p L and p H satisfy the first order conditions:~θ~θ R L / p L = q H (p H - 2p L )/(r - 1) = 0; R H / p H = q H [1 - (2rp H - p L )/(r - 1)] = 0,(6)where the second order and stability conditions are also satisfied 11. As is typical for Bertrand competition, since R i / p i is increasing in p j for i,j = L,H and j C i, the products are strategic complements in price space.Solving the conditions (6), it follows, using (4), that in equilibrium, prices are given by:p L = (r-1)/(4r-1), p H = 2p L and = (2r-1)/(4r-1). (7)~θIt is notable that firm H enjoys a demand (as well as a quality-adjusted price) that is twice that offirm L: i.e. from (5) using 1- = 2( - p L ) = 2r/(4r-1) from (4) and (7),~θ~θx L = - p L = r/(4r-1) and x H = 1- = 2x L .(8)~θ~θLetting 1(r) = p L x L = p H x H /4, we can express the Bertrand equilibrium revenues of the two firms as R L (q L ,q H ) = 1(r)q L and R H (q L ,q H ) = 41(r)q H where from (7) and (8), 1(r) = r(r-1)/(4r-1)2 and hence1 (r) = (2r+1)/(4r-1)3 > 0 and 1 (r) = - 2(8r+7)/(4r-1)4 < 0.(9)It follows that higher quality products tend to command higher revenues, but also (as shown by1 (r)> 0) each firm ’s revenue is increased by a greater separation of products. Since in response to an increase in r, quality adjusted prices rise and outputs fall for both firms, this latter increase in revenue can be explained by a reduction in price competition: i.e. from (7) and (8),dp H /dr = 2(dp L /dr) = 6/(4r-1)2 > 0 and dx H /dr = 2(dx L /dr) = -2/(4r-1)2 < 0.(10)Using subscripts L and H to represent partial derivatives with respect to q L and q H respectively, since r is increasing in q H and decreasing in q L , this implies:R L= 1 (r) > 0 and R H L = - 4(r)21 (r) < 0.(11)HTurning to the stage 1 determination of quality, we continue to keep the analysis general by letting L F(q L) and H F(q H) represent the cost of investment in quality faced by firm L and firm H respectively. In addition to the cost disadvantage, , in the LDC, the parameters, L > 0 and H > 0 will subsequently be interpreted as including the effects of subsidies and taxes arising from investment policies in the two countries. Thus, the respective profits of firms L and H are given by: %L(q L,q H) = R L(q L,q H) - L F(q L) and %H(q L,q H) = R H(q L,q H) - H F(q H),(12) where R L(q L,q H) = 1(r)q L and R H(q L,q H ) = 41(r)q H. Setting q L to maximize %L taking q H as given and setting q H to maximize %H taking q L as given, it follows from (12) that, at the Nash equilibrium in quality, q L and q H satisfy the first order conditions:%L L = R L L- L F (q L) = 0 and %H H = R H H - H F (q H ) = 0,(13) where, using (9), we obtain:= 1(r) - r1 (r) = (r)2(4r-7)/(4r-1)3 > 0 for r > 7/4 andR LLR H= 4(1(r) + r1 (r)) = 4r(4(r)2 -3r + 2)/(4r-1)3 > 0. (14)HThe second order conditions are satisfied since, from (13), (14), (9) and F(q) > 0, we have %L LL = R L LL - L F(q L) < 0 and %H HH = R H HH - H F(q H ) < 0,(15) = (r)21(r)/q L < 0 and R H HH = 4(21 (r)+r1(r))/q L = - 8(5r+1)/q L(4r-1)4 < 0. Since R L LHwhere R LLL= -r1(r)/q L = - R L LL/r > 0 and R H HL = - rR H HH > 0, we also obtain R L LL R H HH - R L LH R H HL = 0 and henceD %L LL%H HH - %L LH%H HL = - H F(q H)R L LL - L F(q L)%H HH > 0.(16) It follows from (15) and (16) that conditional on a particular country producing the high or low quality, the equilibrium is unique and stable.In deciding on quality, the firms face two basic considerations. The first is the profitability of the location in quality space based on revenues and the cost of investment in quality for a given distance from the rival’s quality as measured by the quality ratio, r. The second is the effect of12Adapting Ronen (1991) for 1, since r > 7/4 as q L Ú 0 and F (0) = 0 (see (1)), it follows, using (14),that %L L = R L L - F (0) > 0 for any q H .lim q L →0lim q L →0induced changes in the quality ratio, which determines the degree of price competition. For firm L,since an increase in q L serves to reduce r (holding q H fixed), the associated increase in price competition, tends to reduce firm L ’s marginal revenue, R L L , from quality (i.e. the term r 1 (r) enters negatively). Indeed, as shown by (14), R L L is positive only if the products are sufficiently differentiated to make r 7/4. Nevertheless, for any q H , firm L has an incentive to set q L > 0, because its marginal profit from a very low quality is always strictly positive 12. Since there is no cost of investment at q L = 0 (i.e. F(0) = 0 from (1)), this ensures that entry as a low quality producer is always profitable and hence that both firms enter. For firm H, the prospect of reduced price competition as r is increased, taking q L as fixed, gives an incentive to increase quality. The tradeoff is that an increase in q H becomes increasingly costly because of the rising marginal cost of investment in quality.As illustrated in Figure 1, the reaction functions, denoted q H = 'H (q L ) and q L = 'L (q H ) for firms H and L respectively, have positive slopes, making the products strategic complements in quality space: i.e. from (14) and (15),dq H /dq L - R H HL /%H HH = rR H HH /%H HH > 0; dq L /dq H - R L LH /%L LL = R L LL /r %L LL > 0.(17)Thus in response to the greater price competition arising from an increase in q L , firm H eases this competition by also increasing q H . Correspondingly, the reduced competition associated with an increase in q H allows firm L to better position its product by raising q L . The second order and stability conditions (15) and (16) ensure that firm L ’s reaction function is steeper than for firm H and hence that the curves cross at a unique point (shown as N). Since r = q H /q L > 1, the reaction functions both lie above the (dotted) 45° line.Figure 1 Quality reaction functions: BertrandcompetitionTurning to the question as to which country produces which quality, for Bertrand competition, Ronnen (1991) has shown that if the firms are identical ( L = H in our setting) then there exists a global equilibrium in which the unique qualities (q L,q H) can be produced by either firm. Thus there are two pure-strategy equilibria depending on which firm produces which product. For asymmetric firms, we show in Proposition 1 that the second, “switched” equilibrium, in which firm 1 in the LDC produces q H and firm 2, in the developed country, produces q L can be ruled out by setting sufficiently large. For this result, it is important that investment costs increase sufficiently fast with quality (due to F(q) > 0 and F K(q) 0) that the LDC firm does not leapfrog its quality above the high quality produced by firm H.Proposition 1. Assume Bertrand price competition. Under conditions (1), if 1 is sufficiently large, there exists a unique pure strategy equilibrium in which the low quality product is produced in the LDC and the high quality product is produced in the developed country.Proof: See Appendix AFor the subsequent analysis, we assume that is sufficiently large for Proposition 1 to apply andhence that firm L (or firm 1) produces the low-quality product in the LDC and firm H (or firm 2) produces the high-quality product in the developed country, country H.3.2 LDC investment policy towards the low-quality productNow considering government policy committed at stage 0, this section concerns the effects of an LDC subsidy (or tax) applied to investment in quality by firm L. We also adjust firm H’s cost so as to include any subsidy (or tax) imposed by country H. Effects on quality levels and profits are first developed before examining the policy that maximizes LDC welfare taking the policy of country H as given.Letting s L and s H represent the proportion of the cost of investment in quality covered by the governments in the LDC and developed countries respectively, we assume13 s L < 1and s H < 1, with s L < 0 or s H < 0, corresponding to a tax. Thus the cost of investment for firm L is L F(q L) where L = (1-s L) > 0 and the cost of investment for firm H is H F(q H) where H = 1-s H > 0. Letting q L = q L( L, H) and q H = q H( L, H) represent the relationships between quality and costs, L and H, as defined by (13), it follows that s L and s H have an indirect effect on prices through quality changes. However, since investment costs are sunk at stage 2, there is no change in the second-stage price equilibrium for given levels of quality.As shown in Proposition 2(a), an investment subsidy by the LDC increases both q L and q H, enhancing the quality levels chosen by both firms, but since the quality ratio r q H/q L falls, overall the products become more similar. This follows since in response to an increase in q L (due to the subsidy), firm H eases price competition by also increasing its quality (q L and q H are strategic complements), but, the increase in q H is not sufficient to prevent a fall in r. From (10), quality-adjusted prices, p L and p H then fall and outputs, x L and x H rise. Not surprisingly, as shown in13 Countries have no incentive to set s L 1 or s H 1, since then quality would be increased indefinitely (this violates the first order conditions (13)).。

相关文档
最新文档