Transaction cost economics and its uses in marketing
战略管理英文版最新版教学课件第8章

LO 8-4 Identify and evaluate benefits and risks of vertical integration. LO 8-5 Describe and examine alternatives to vertical integration. LO 8-6 Describe and evaluate different types of corporate diversification. LO 8-7 Apply the core competence – market matrix to derive different
• Economies of scope
➢ Savings that come from producing more outputs or providing different services at less cost
❖ Ex: Amazon range of products & services
➢ Explains and predicts the scope of the firm ➢ "Market vs. firms" have differential costs
• Transaction costs
➢ Costs associated with economic exchanges
➢ Competitive bidding process ➢ Less than one-year term ➢ Lower prices cost advantages
交易成本理论(Transaction Cost Theory)

章节导览:壹、交易成本理论(Transaction Cost Theory)…………………………一、交易成本理论概述二、产生交易成本的原因三、交易的三项特征四、交易成本分析壹、交易成本理论(Transaction Cost Theory)一、交易成本理论概述交易成本理论(Transaction Cost Theory)是用比较制度分析方法研究经济组织制度的理论。
它是英国经济学家罗纳德·哈里·科斯(R·H·Coase)1937年在其重要论文“论企业的性质”中提出来的。
它的基本思路是:围绕交易费用节约这一中心,把交易作为分析单位,找出区分不同交易的特征因素,然后分析什么样的交易应该用什么样的体制组织来协调。
科斯认为,交易成本是获得准确市场信息所需要的费用,以及谈判和经常性契约的费用。
也就是说,交易成本由信息搜寻成本、谈判成本、缔约成本、监督履约情况的成本、可能发生的处理违约行为的成本所构成。
科斯在尝试解释企业何以存在时为经济理论“发现”的就是这种反复发生的交易成本。
他的结论是,通过建立一种无限期的、半永久性的层级性关系,或者说通过将资源结合起来形成像企业那样的组织,可以减少在市场中转包某些投入的成本。
一种多少具有持久性的组织关系,如一个雇员与企业的关系,对企业来说,能节省每天去市场上招聘雇员的成本;对于雇员来说,能减少每天去市场应聘的成本和失业风险成本。
这种“持久性的组织关系”就是制度,包括契约,也包括政策等。
因此,依靠体制组织、契约以及其上的政策等制度,采纳和利用标准化的度量衡,能降低交易成本的水平。
交易成本理论中的制度在经济分析中的重要性,使许多经济学者重构了制度经济学,并把它19世纪末20世纪初德国“历史学派”和美国制度主义理论家的那种注重对制度作描述性分析的研究区分开来,冠之以“新制度经济学”(New Institutional Economics),但我们仍然习惯地称之为制度经济学或制度分析学派。
Williamson(1979)transaction-cost-economics交易费用经济学-合同关系的治理(中英文)

TRANSACTION-COST ECONOMICS: THE GOVERNANCE OFCONTRACTUAL RELATIONS交易费用经济学:合约关系的治理The new institutional economics is preoccupied with the origins, incidence, and ramifications of transaction costs. 新制度经济学都已经先研究了交易费用的起源、发生、和分支。
Indeed, if transaction costs are negligible, the organization of economic activity is irrelevant, since any advantages one mode of organization appears to hold over another will simply be eliminated by costless contracting. 事实上,如果交易费用是可以忽略的,经济活动的组织就是不相关的,因为一种组织模型对于另一种的优势将仅被低成本的合约所消除。
But despite the growing realization that transaction costs are central to the study of economics,1 skeptics remain. 但是怀疑主义说坚持说,尽管日益增长的事实,交易成本仍是经济研究的中心。
Stanley Fischer's complaint is typical: "Transaction costs have a well-deserved bad name as a theoretical device... [partly] because there is a suspicion that almost anything can be rationalized by invoking suitably specified transaction costs."2 Stanley Fischer的抱怨是典型的:交易成本作为理论设计拥有一个罪有应得的恶名。
财政专业英语名词解释

Gini Coefficient●The Gini coefficient is a measure of the inequality of a distribution, a value of 0expressing total equality and a value of 1 expressing maximal inequality.Pareto Optimality●Given an initial allocation of goods among a set of individuals, a change to a differentallocation that makes at least one individual better off without making any other individual worse off is called a Pareto improvement. An allocation is defined as "Pareto efficient" or "Pareto optimal" when no further Pareto improvements can be made. transaction cost●In economics and related disciplines, a transaction cost is a cost incurred in making aneconomic exchange. Such as search and information costs, bargaining costs, policing and enforcement costs.natural monopoly●A natural monopoly arises where the largest supplier in an industry, often the first supplierin a market, has an overwhelming cost advantage over other actual and potential competitors. Examples include public utilities such as water services and electricity. externality●An externality is a cost or benefit, not transmitted through prices, incurred by a party whodid not agree to the action causing the cost or benefit. A benefit in this case is called a positive externality or external benefit, while a cost is called a negative externality or external cost.welfare economics●Welfare economics is a branch of economics that uses microeconomic techniques toevaluate economic well-being, especially relative to competitive general equilibrium within an economy as to economic efficiency and the resulting income distribution associated with it. It analyzes social welfare, however measured, in terms of economic activities of the individuals that comprise the theoretical society considered. Fundamental Theorem of W elfare Economics●There are two fundamental theorems of welfare economics. The first states that anycompetitive equilibrium leads to a Pareto efficient allocation of resources. The second states the converse, that any efficient allocation can be sustainable by a competitive equilibrium.social welfare function●A social welfare function is a real-valued function that ranks conceivable social statesfrom lowest to highest. Inputs of the function include any variables considered to affect welfare of the society.government failure●Government failure is the public sector analogy to market failure and occurs when agovernment intervention causes a more inefficient allocation of goods and resources than would occur without that intervention.voting paradox●The voting paradox is a situation in which collective preferences can be cyclic, even if thepreferences of individual voters are not. This is paradoxical, because it means that majority wishes can be in conflict with each other.Arrow’s impossibility theorem●Arrow’s impossibility theorem states that, when voters have three or more discretealternatives, no voting system can convert the ranked preferences of individuals into a community-wide ranking while also meeting a certain set of criteria.logrolling●Logrolling is the trading of favors, such as vote trading by legislative members to obtainpassage of actions of interest to each legislative member.median voter●The median voter theory posits that in a majority election, if voter policy preferences canbe represented as a point along a single dimension, if all voters vote deterministically for the politician who commits to a policy position closest to their own preference, and if there are only two politicians, then a politician maximizes their number of votes by committing to the policy position preferred by the median voter.Wagner’s Law●The Wagner's law predicts that the development of an industrial economy will beaccompanied by an increased share of public expenditure in gross national product: “The advent of modern industrial society will result in increasing political pressure for social progress and increased allowance for social consideration by industry.”public goods●A public good is a good that is non-rival and non-excludable. Non-rivalry means thatconsumption of the good by one individual does not reduce availability of the good for consumption by others; and non-excludability that no one can be effectively excluded from using the good.Collective goods●Collective goods are defined public goods that could be delivered as private goods, butare usually delivered by the government for various reasons, including social policy, and finances from like taxes.Free rider problem●Free riders are those who consume more than their fair share of a public resource, orshoulder less than a fair share of the costs of its production. Free riding is usually considered to be an economic "problem" only when it leads to the non-production or under-production of a public good, or when it leads to the excessive use of a common property resource. The free rider problem is the question of how to limit free riding in these situations.Lindahl Equilibrium●A Lindahl tax is a form of taxation in which individuals pay for the provision of a publicgood according to their marginal benefits. Lindahl taxes are sometimes known as benefit taxes. A Lindahl equilibrium is a state of economic equilibrium under such a tax.merit goods●The concept of a merit good is a commodity which is judged that an individual or societyshould have on the basis of some concept of need, rather than ability and willingness to pay. A merit good may be described as a good that has positive externalities associated with it.Pigovian T ax●A Pigovian tax is a tax levied on a market activity that generates negative externalities.The tax is intended to correct the market outcome. In the presence of negative externalities, the social cost of a market activity is not covered by the private cost of the activity. In such a case, the market outcome is not efficient and may lead to over-consumption of the product. A Pigovian tax equal to the negative externality is thought to correct the market outcome back to efficiency.Coase Theorem●The Coase theorem states that if trade in an externality is possible and there are notransaction costs, bargaining will lead to an efficient outcome regardless of the initial allocation of property rights.experimental economics●Experimental economics is the application of experimental methods to study economicquestions. Experiments, including data, are used to test the validity of economic theories and test-bed new market mechanisms.behavioral economics●Behavioral economics and its related area of study, behavioral finance, use social,cognitive and emotional factors in understanding the economic decisions of individuals and institutions performing economic functions, including consumers, borrowers and investors, and their effects on market prices, returns and the resource allocation.K-12 education●K–12 is a designation for the sum of primary and secondary education. It is used in theUnited States, Canada, and some parts of Australia.school voucher●A school voucher, also called an education voucher, is a certificate issued by thegovernment which parents can apply toward tuition at a private school, rather than at the public school to which their child is assigned.user fees and user charge●User fees:●Derived from government sale of licenses to engage in otherwise restricted of forbiddenactivities. Example: motor vehicle user fee●User charge:●Prices charged for voluntarily purchased, public provided service, although benefitingspecific individual or businesses, are closely associated with basic government responsibilities. Example: University tuitionmeans test●A means test is a determination of whether an individual or family is eligible for helpfrom the government.cost-benefit analysis●Cost–benefit analysis is often used by governments to evaluate the desirability of a givenintervention. It is an analysis of the cost effectiveness of different alternatives in order to see whether the benefits outweigh the costs.shadow price●The shadow price is the change in the objective value of the optimal solution of anoptimization problem obtained by relaxing the constraint by one unit – it is the marginal utility of relaxing the constraint, or equivalently the marginal cost of strengthening the constraint.government procurement●Government procurement, also called public tendering or public procurement, is theprocurement of goods and services on behalf of a public authority, such as a government agency.。
交易成本经济学

Purchasing standard material
Other Applications
• • • •
Investment Characteristics
Nonspecific Mixed Idiosyncratic
Occasional
Market governance (classical contracting)
Trilateral Governance (neoclassical contracting) Purchasing customized Equipment
Some Contracting Background
• Relational Contract
The pressures to sustain ongoing relations "have led to the spin-off of many subject areas from the classical, and later the neoclassical, contract law system, e.g., much of corporate law and collective bargaining."
Framework
Contract
Economic Behavior
Transaction
Some Contracting Background
• Classical Contract
What is distinctive about classical contract law is that it attempts to do this by enhancing discreteness and intensifying " presentiation," where presentiation has reference to efforts to "make or render present in place or time; to cause to be perceived or realized at present." The emphasis, thus, is on legal rules, formal documents, and self-liquidating transactions.
交易成本理论

交易成本理论外文名Transaction Costs一定的社会关一般的生产成本目录1.1成本简介2.2成本分类3.3成本原因4.4成本特性成本简介编辑交易成本理论是由诺贝尔经济学得奖主科斯(Coase, ., 1937)所提出,交易成本理论的根本论点在于对企业的本质加以解释。
由于经济体系中企业的专业分工与市场价格机能之运作,产生了专业分工的现象;但是使用市场的价格机能的成本相对偏高,而形成企业机制,它是人类追求经济效率所形成的组织体。
成本分类编辑由于交易成本泛指所有为促成交易发生而形成的成本,因此很难进行明确的界定与列举,不同的交易往往就涉及不同种类的交易成本。
总体而言,简单的分类可将交易成本区分为以下几项(Williamson, 1975):搜寻成本:商品信息与交易对象信息的搜集。
信息成本:取得交易对象信息与和交易对象进行信息交换所需的成本。
议价成本:针对契约、价格、品质讨价还价的成本。
决策成本:进行相关决策与签订契约所需的内部成本。
监督成本:监督交易对象是否依照契约内容进行交易的成本,例如追踪产品、监督、验货等。
违约成本:违约时所需付出的事后成本。
Williamson(1985)进一步将交易成本加以整理区分为事前与事后两大类。
事前的交易成本:签约、谈判、保障契约等成本。
事后的交易成本:契约不能适应所导致的成本;讨价还价的成本─指两方调整适应不良的谈判成本;建构及营运的成本;为解决双方的纠纷与争执而必须设置的相关成本;约束成本─为取信于对方所需之成本。
Dahlman(1979)则将交易活动的内容加以类别化处理,认为交易成本包含:搜寻信息的成本、协商与决策成本、契约成本、监督成本、执行成本与转换成本,说明了交易成本的型态及基本内涵。
简言之,所谓交易成本就是指当交易行为发生时,所随同产生的信息搜寻、条件谈判与交易实施等的各项成本。
成本原因编辑交易成本发生的原因,来自于人性因素与交易环境因素交互影响下所产生的市场失灵现象,造成交易困难所致(Williamson, 1975)。
交易成本理论

交易成本理论一、概念理论建构于概念之上。
对于交易费用为何,学界众说纷纭。
交易成本为英文“transaction cost”汉译,亦有学者将之译为“交易费用”。
一般认为,交易成本这一概念首先由科斯于《企业的性质》中提出。
这篇文章主要探讨了“企业何以存在”这一核心议题。
科斯[①]认为,企业与市场的边界有市场交易成本和企业组织成本共同决定。
前者主要为“使用价格价值的成本”。
在这篇文章中,科斯并未对交易费用这一概念作出清晰界定,而是采用列举法,认为交易费用包含了“发现相对价格的成本、谈判和签约的费用以及由于经济生活的不确定性和风险所导致的成本等”。
20世纪60年代后,伴随着科斯论文《社会成本问题》引起广泛和深入的讨论,交易成本的内涵得到拓展,其外延也进一步被细化。
威廉姆森把交易费用分为合同签订前和合同签订后,前者而包括草拟合同、就合同内容谈判和确保合同履行所付出的成本;后者则包括了不适应成本、讨价还价成本、建立及运转成本和保证成本等。
威廉姆森认为,交易成本产生的主要原因是人的性与机会主义行为;客观原因则包括了交易所具有的三个基本维度:交易发生的频率、交易的不确定性程度和资产专用性条件[②][③]。
张五常在《新玻尔格雷夫经济学大词典》“经济制度与交易费用”条目中将交易费用定义为“那些在鲁宾逊·克鲁梭(一人世界的) 经济中不能想象的一切成本, 在一人世界里,没有产权,也没有交易,没有任何形式的经济组织”。
从数学角度,汪丁丁[④]将交易费用定义为给定的不完备的知识集合上对可供选择的制度做选择的机会成本。
综合来看,交易费用有别于生产费用。
生产费用可以认为是生产过程中生产者必然要支付消耗的生产资料并支付劳工的劳动报酬的总。
交易费用则是交换过程中的讨价还价、签订合约、监督合约履行产生的费用。
二、交易成本理论交易成本理论围绕核心概念“交易成本”展开。
交易成本理论以交易为分析单位,是研究经济组织的比较制度理论。
《交易成本理论》PPT课件

契約確定後一方未遵守承諾,造成對方負擔
A
9
交易氛圍(atmosphere)
滿意、信任,避免不必要交易成本 不信任、猜忌,環境懷疑、不確定,增加搜尋與協議
監督等交易成本
交易頻率(frequency)
經常性交易(recurrent transactions)
事前少數交易
特殊知識(idiosyncratic knowledge)交易時未完全流通 +投機主義人性自利市場交易由少數人操縱
事後少數交易
第一次得標者取得經驗技能容易續約,可討價還價, 其他競爭者優勢相對低不完全競爭的少數交易,無 效率
A
8
資訊不對稱(information impactedness)
A
24
上網訂花、書 > 鞋子、牙膏、微波爐
電子商務搜尋成本低,檢驗、付費與售後服務成本 提高
鞋:檢驗成本 微波爐:售後服務成本
網購經驗影響
有網購經驗,受不確定性影響,但受資產特殊性影 響小
無網購經驗,受兩者影響皆大
網購受交易成本影響,交易成本受不確定性和 資產特殊性影響
A
25
資產專屬性造成交易雙方依賴關係,增加承包風險
A
13
古典契約與市場治理(market Governance)
古典契約法則(classical contract law)假設的理想 市場
理性、無投機主義、資訊對稱、確定 即有效率的交易情況 成員沒有相互依存關係
經常性:依過去經驗
偶發性:購買商品標準化(不具專屬性),他人購買經 驗可參考
預期交易完成後之利益 > 預期交易成本 交易成本=事前成本+事後成本
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
Transaction cost economics and its uses in marketingOliver Williamson &Tarek GhaniReceived:6June 2011/Accepted:10June 2011/Published online:15July 2011#Academy of Marketing Science 2011Abstract Scholarship at the intersection of transaction cost economics (TCE)and marketing has enjoyed an impressive record of growth over the past three decades,and the future promises more of the same.Following Erin Anderson ’s perceptive uses of TCE in her 1982dissertation,the field of marketing has made many constructive uses of and contributions to TCE,where the latter include broadening the reach of TCE,posing important challenges,and identifying opportunities still to be addressed.Given this history,we advance the proposition that the relation between TCE and marketing has been and should be a two-way street.In considering the scope for future research,we give special attention to issues of asymmetric costs,the dynamics of governance,and disequilibrium contracting.We also discuss the four precepts of pragmatic methodol-ogy,with special emphasis on prediction and empirical testing.The Appendix provides added perspective on the evolving “science of organization ”of which TCE is a part.Keywords Marketing .Transaction cost .Empirical testing .Economizing .Microanalytics .Public policy toward businessWe responded to the invitation to contribute a “thought piece ”to the 40th anniversary issue of the Journal ofAcademy of Marketing Science (hereafter JAMS)with alacrity.After all,transaction cost economics and JAMS have grown up together.Although the concept of transaction cost and the effort to operationalize it (transaction cost economics)are closely related,they should nevertheless be distinguished.The concept of transaction cost was advanced by Ronald Coase in his pathbreaking paper on “The Nature of the Firm ”(1937)to repair a serious lapse in microeconomics —namely,the distribution of economic activity as between firm and market was taken as given,when instead such a fundamental condition should be derived.This lapse was mainly ignored by the economics profession until Coase (1960)and Kenneth Arrow (1969)pushed the logic of zero transaction costs to completion to reveal that both market failures and vertical integration would vanish —because the parties to such trans-actions would always costlessly bargain to an efficient result.That was preposterous,yet it takes a theory to beat a theory (Kuhn 1970).Williamson ’s 1971paper on “The Vertical Integration of Production:Market Failure Consid-erations ”was an effort to breathe operational content into positive transaction costs in the context of vertical integration and,as such,was an early effort to implement transaction cost economics (TCE).The first issue of JAMS would appear 2years later in 1973.By the early 1980s,these two would be working together —with the under-standing that within marketing it was more appropriate and/or judicious to refer to TCE as transaction cost analysis,or TCA.1Forty years later a constructive relation between the two is alive and well.1We see merit in this distinction but refer to TCE throughout.In fact,although TCA is mainly based on TCE reasoning,it also appeals to agency theory.For some purposes,TCE and agency theory are complementary constructions.O.Williamson :T.GhaniHaas School of Business,University of California,Berkeley,Berkeley,CA 94720–1900,USA T.Ghanie-mail:tarek_ghani@ O.Williamson (*)Business,Economics and Law,Berkeley,CA,USAe-mail:owilliam@J.of the Acad.Mark.Sci.(2012)40:74–85DOI 10.1007/s11747-011-0268-zThis thought piece is organized in four parts.We begin with a digression in which Williamson recalls early uses of TCE by Erin Anderson to examine issues of central importance to marketing.The second section discusses the uses of TCE reasoning and analysis in the years since and advances the proposition that the relation between TCE and marketing should be a two-way street.The third section discusses pragmatic methodology and related issues.The final section and an appendix on the progression of TCE conclude the paper.A digressionThis section briefly discusses Erin Anderson’s early recognition that TCE had ramifications for marketing research in the1980s and beyond.I first met Erin when she joined the faculty of the Marketing Department at the Wharton School in the fall of 1981.2Erin had been a student of both Barton Weiss(in marketing)and William Ouchi(in organization theory) when she did her PhD work at UCLA.Bill was an organization theorist with an early interest in transaction cost economics3and urged Erin to include TCE within her toolkit.Weiss even more strongly encouraged her to bring transaction cost economics to bear on marketing issues(A. Gatignon and H.Gatignon2010,p.232)in her dissertation.I never asked Erin if either Bill or Bart encouraged her to participate in the Industrial Organization Workshop at Penn, but she showed up at the first IO Workshop in the fall of 1981.She immediately caught my attention and that of other workshop participants(including Sanford Grossman, Henry Hansmann,Pablo Spiller,and Michael Riordan)by “asking good questions.”4I made a point of introducing myself to Erin after her third consecutive week of attendance.Not only did Erin become a regular attendee with many perceptive good questions,but Erin also made workshop presentations and began publishing articles that featured TCE.Her article on“The Salesperson as Outside Agent or Employee:A Transaction Cost Analysis”(1985)is the first marketing article to put TCE to work.I moved to Yale in1983and Erin joined the INSEAD faculty in1994,but we had professional and holiday correspondence in the interim.Then another lucky thing happened:a European conference on“Transaction Cost Economics and Beyond”was being organized,and I was asked to participate.I inquired about the other participants and ascertained that many were skeptics of transaction cost economics.I therefore recommended that additional schol-ars be invited—to include Erin Anderson,Keith Crocker, Paul Joskow,Scott Masten,Claude Menard,and Margherita Turvani.The conference organizers agreed,and the confer-ence was held in1994.The conference featured spirited discussions between the skeptics and the supporters of TCE.Indeed,during much of the conference we were often at a“he says/she says”impasse.Yet there was a difference.The difference was not that one side was more eloquent or made more clever oral arguments than the other.To the contrary,a neutral observer would have concluded that it was a draw in oral argument respects. The difference was that,in addition to the oral argument, one side had a predictive theory for which the data were corroborative,whereas the other side was empty handed in this respect.As will be discussed in the third section, the cutting edge for separating the sheep from the goats resides in the fourth precept of pragmatic methodology: derive refutable implications and submit these to empir-ical testing.It is undisputed that TCE made headway within economics,the contiguous social sciences,and the business schools because it had ramifications for such a broad range of phenomena to which the data are corroborative.5I was especially gratified when Erin informed me when I visited INSEAD a decade later that the timing of the1994 conference could not have been better:it inspired her to re-engage TCE in her teaching and research with even greater confidence and energy.History records that hers was an exceptionally successful career.6Everyone who knew her—family,friends,students,colleagues—mourned her untime-ly death from cancer in2007.2Because Tarek Ghani did not have the pleasure of meeting Erin Anderson,the use of the first person singular pronoun in this section refers to Williamson.3Ouchi wrote a very favorable book review of Markets and Hierarchies(1975)for the Administrative Science Quarterly(1977). He and I had many occasions to share ideas in the years since.4Kenneth Arrow related to me that the reason he remembered me as one of his students is that I“asked good questions”in a course that I took from him when I was an MBA student at Stanford.Arrow further observed that asking good questions is how he came to the attention of his teachers when he was a PhD student at Columbia.5Empirical tests of transactions cost economics numbered over900in 2006and have been broadly corroborative(Macher and Richman 2008).Indeed,“despite what almost30years ago may have appeared to be insurmountable obstacles to acquiring the relevant data[which are often primary data of a microanalytic kind],today transaction cost economics stands on a remarkably broad empirical foundation”(Geyskens et al.2006,p.531).There is no gainsaying that transaction cost economics has been much more influential because of the empirical work that it has engendered(Whinston2001).6Erin Anderson“published43scholarly articles as well as six book chapters on transaction costs in action,and was nominated in ISI’s top 0.5%most cited scholars in business and economics in2003”(A. Gatignon and H.Gatignon2010,p.232).Constructive usesScholarship at the intersection of transaction cost economics and marketing has enjoyed an impressive record of growth in the three decades following the completion of Erin Anderson’s dissertation(1982).As Macher and Richman(2008)observe in their review of approximately900articles testing TCE theory,marketing places second only to industrial organization economics in generating new business-related empirical TCE research. Among the uses of TCE in marketing are vertical integration, foreign market entry,industrial purchasing,distribution channel management,and sales force control and compensa-tion.7Marketing has also been at the forefront of efforts to test TCE’s antecedents and implications.The main value of TCE theory to marketing scholars has been in providing a constructive framework for analyzing contractual exchange,with testable implications that have proven empirically robust across a wide range of applica-tions.More generally,the field of marketing has broadened the reach of TCE,posed important challenges,and identified opportunities still to be addressed.Indeed, marketing and TCE scholars have much to gain from a more regular,two-way research dialogue.In this spirit of interdisciplinary exchange,we briefly review in this section the principal means by which TCE has informed marketing and the major themes through which marketing has in turn informed TCE.Given that several excellent overviews of the marketing-TCE literature already exist(e.g., A. Gatignon and H.Gatignon2010;John and Reve2010; Rindfleisch and Heide1997),our intention is not to provide a comprehensive survey of past and current research,but rather to draw out recurrent themes,highlight novel insights,and clarify ambiguities.TCE informs marketingTCE differs from the neoclassical lens of choice,which places its primary emphasis on prices and output,supply and demand,by examining economic organization through the lens of contract/governance and taking the transaction to be the basic unit of analysis.TCE joins Coase(1937, 1960),in his insistence that the standard assumption of zero transaction costs needs to give way to express provision for positive transaction costs,and John mons,in his pronouncement that“The ultimate unit of activity…must contain in itself the three principles of conflict,mutuality and order.This unit is a transaction”(1932,p.4).Not only does TCE take the transaction to be the unit of analysis,but TCE also interprets governance as the means by which to infuse order,thereby to mitigate conflict and realize mutual gains from trade(both interfirm and intrafirm).Transaction cost economics took shape by progressively operationaliz-ing this agenda.8As described by Williamson(2010),the key moves in TCE are:(1)to examine economic organization through the lens of contract/governance;(2)to identify the key attributes of human actors(bounded rationality and oppor-tunism)that bear on the efficacy of contracting;(3)to name the key attributes of transactions to which contractual complications accrue,especially asset specificity(which gives rise to bilateral dependency)and disturbances (especially outliers,for which the stakes are great);(4)to take adaptation to be the main problem of economic organization,of which autonomous and coordinated types of adaptation are distinguished;(5)to name the key attributes that describe alternative modes of governance (with special emphasis on the syndromes of attributes that define markets and hierarchies);and(6)to advance the discriminating alignment hypothesis—wherein transactions, which differ in their attributes,are aligned with governance structures,which differ in their cost and competence,so as to effect a transaction cost economizing outcome.The basic regularities are these:if asset specificity is low,autonomous adaptation to changes in relative prices in the market (simple market exchange)will be efficient.As,however, asset specificity builds up and a condition of bilateral dependency develops,consequential disturbances pose interfirm contracting hazards for which hierarchy affords relief.As John and Reve(2010)observe,TCE has come to occupy a significant place in mainstream marketing strategy.As a variant upon TCE,the authors note that S-A-M governance structures—whereby parties to a transac-tion devise Safeguards thereby to promote Adaptations to changing circumstances for activities that lack verifiable outcome Measures—“constitute the workhorse model of channel mode choice in contemporary textbooks”(p.250).9 This consensus builds upon the work of Anderson’s dissertation(1982),which provided compelling early evidence for the role of behavioral uncertainty and specific investments in sales force management by electronics firms, and the related marketing research that followed(e.g. Anderson1985,1988a;Carson2000;Heide1987;John7See Rindfleisch and Heide(1997,p.30)for a detailed list of references corresponding to each of these five categories.8Other early contributors include Victor Goldberg(1976);Klein et al.(1978);Klein and Leffler(1981);Monteverde and Teece(1982); Scott Masten(1984);Masten and Crocker(1985);Anderson and Schmittlein(1984);Paul Joskow(1985,1987);and Grossman and Hart(1986)9It is noteworthy how closely S-A-M processes replicate the “Commons Triple”of conflict,mutuality,and order.For one example of a marketing textbook that makes productive use of TCE,see Coughlan et al.(2006),particularly chapters8,9,and13.and Weitz1988;Noordweier1986).10This branch of the marketing literature is focused mainly on the human capital dimensions of asset specificity and as such makes a distinctive contribution to the empirical study of TCE.While the most widely known applications of TCE in marketing deal with the classic question of governance mode and related issues of vertical integration,a number of sub-literatures have also developed that apply TCE to interpret other novel marketing phenomena,test the robustness of TCE’s predictions,or examine TCE’s bound-ary conditions.John and Reve(2010)review novel applications of TCE to marketing puzzles,such as incentivizing sales staff to focus on house brands over national brands(Anderson and Robertson1995),the co-branding of component-provider logos with certain prod-ucts and services(Ghosh and John2009),and the granting of royalty-free licenses for so-called“clone products”in the electronics industry(Dutta1990).A recurrent theme in all of these cases is that the action resides in the microanalytics of transactions and governance structures.Numerous other studies have subjected TCE’s predictions to empirical scrutiny in the marketing context.Rindfleisch and Heide’s detailed survey(Rindfleisch and Heide1997)finds broad support across45empirical studies for TCE’s conceptual emphasis on safeguarding specific assets,adapting to environmental uncertainty,and the firm’s decision to invest in performance measurement technologies.11The last point concerning performance measures receives attention both within firms,in the case of employee monitoring costs where human capital is a specific asset,and between firms, when trading partners seek independent qualifications of each other’s capabilities(e.g.,Heide and John1990).These authors also propose extensions to or improvements upon TCE,some of which are addressed below.Among other marketing issues to which TCE speaks but, evidently,has not been fully persuasive are the issue of “trust”and the explication of hybrid modes of contracting (where these two are related).TCE expressly takes exception with the propensity among sociologists and some economists to treat calculated risk as a manifestation of “trust”in commercial transactions.Calculated risks are precisely what the term implies:take the risk if the expected net gains are positive but not ing trust and calculated risk interchangeably introduces avoidable confu-sion by introducing problems of two kinds.First,use of the word trust serves often to suspend hard-headed analysis by inviting ex post rationalizations(as discussed in Williamson (1996a,pp.256–267)).Second,expansive use of the word trust commonly obfuscates the mutual gains from trade that are often realized by introducing credible commitments, thereby mitigating contractual hazards.Specifically,TCE interprets the hybrid mode of gover-nance as a means to mitigate the contractual hazards that would accrue to market exchange(by reason of asset specificity and uncertainty)without incurring the added bureaucratic costs and loss of incentive intensity that arise under hierarchy.The mechanisms through which hybrid contracting works include penalties for breach of contract, better information disclosure and verification,and private ordering dispute settlement mechanisms that promote continuity rather than rely on the adversarial process to award financial damages in the courts(Williamson1983, 1991).To repeat,such hazards are mitigated(but not eliminated)in a cost-effective way.Hybrids,so construed, are vital to effective marketing relationships(especially in intermediate product markets,but they have application to final goods and services as well).Appealing to trust draws attention away from hard-headed contracting—with the result that our understanding of efficient trade is sacrificed in the process.Marketing informs TCEAs A.Gatignon and H.Gatignon(2010,p.241)observe, Erin Anderson’s academic career began shortly after TCE’s development,and she played an instrumental role in providing the theory with empirical grounding.Crucially, Anderson also provided a roadmap for how other scholars could apply TCE in new research areas:look for novel applications,take testable hypotheses to the data,and extend the robustness of results.As a result of her disciplined research and that of many scholars who followed,the research frontiers in marketing—and TCE more generally—rest on a stronger and more diversified foundation.Marketing scholars have not only advanced several new research themes which warrant attention from TCE economists,including asymmetric costs and dynamic governance,but they are also well positioned to contribute to nascent efforts to develop and estimate structural TCE models.What,for example,is the cost to firm performance associated with making the“wrong”choice in the make-or-buy decision,and how does it relate to the underlying conditions of asset specificity and uncertainty in the contractual exchange?John and Reve(2010,pp.250–251)address this question,citing the findings of Rao (2009)that firms that mistakenly choose high-powered incentives for compensating their sales force suffer a larger penalty than firms that mistakenly choose low-powered10Interestingly,many of the early uses of TCE in marketing weredone by PhD students working on their dissertations.Some have been heard to say(with a wink)that TCE is“young people’s economics.”11The performance evaluation problem,as framed by Rindfleisch andHeide(1997,p.45),“arises when a firm whose decision-makers are limited by bounded rationality has difficulty assessing the contractual compliance of its exchange partners.”incentives.Also,Anderson(1988b)shows that wrong choices in high uncertainty regimes carry a significant penalty,while wrong choices in low uncertainty regimes may not.Rao’s(2009)conjecture that hierarchies provide insurance against costly mistakes is intriguing and warrants further research.Marketing scholars have also been active in expanding TCE’s theory horizons.The dynamics of governance is one area where marketing scholars have sought to push the envelope.A.Gatignon and H.Gatignon(2010,pp.240–241)provide a rich discussion of switching costs facing managers converting from one mode of governance to another,as well as a life-cycle approach to market relationships in which principal-agent relationships evolve over time.Switching costs offer one possible mechanism by which a governance decision becomes locked-in(Anderson and Gatignon1986;Guiltinan1974;Weiss and Anderson 1992),despite the possibility that changes in contracting conditions or the principal-agent relationship may lead alternative governance arrangements to be preferred(e.g., Jap and Anderson2007).Quantifying these switching costs, and exploring the gap between perceptions and realities,is worthy of more attention.Also,as TCE is further formalized(Tadelis and Williamson2011),dynamic gover-nance choices may provide a setting in which marketing scholars and TCE economists can collaborate,drawing upon a growing stable of dynamic contracting models(e.g., Bolton and Dewatripont2005,chap.9–10).Closely related to the questions of dynamic governance are the“disequilibrium contracting”issues that are posed by high velocity events,especially in conjunction with organizational and technological innovations.Real time responsiveness often trumps steady-state equilibrium con-siderations in such circumstances(Williamson1991).The simultaneous provision of high-powered incentives to the parties while avoiding the burdens of bureaucracy(Wil-liamson1985,chap.6)come to the fore,of which specialized financial structures(such as venture capital firms and leveraged buyouts)are examples(Williamson 2009).Marketing exigencies doubtless also arise for which disequilibrium contracting and organizational issues trump those that are pertinent to efficient alignment in more mature markets.These likewise warrant scrutiny.Familiar-ity with the equilibrium TCE setup nevertheless provides a baseline to inform the when and why and how of disequilibrium contracting—although not to the exclusion of other frameworks.As for future TCE empirical applications,Rindfleisch and Heide(1997)argue that“marketing’s rich tradition in construct measurement and survey research techniques have contributed to the operationalization and testing[of TCE]”(p.30).Interim developments in and uses of TCE notwithstanding,Rindfleisch et al.(2010)do not in the least regard this as a finished project and encourage motivated scholars to pursue challenging research opportunities. Perhaps,as John and Reve(2010)suggest,TCE marketing scholars will be among those next to address the empirical challenges of bounded rationality,or take the lead in formalizing and structurally estimating TCE models.If so, we hope they will find many willing research collaborators among our colleagues in the economics field.Indeed,as the marketing and strategy literatures make clear, still additional TCE challenges arise when issues are not posed de novo but as between pre-existing firms that have heterogeneous backgrounds.In that event,questions such as the following should be posed:“How should firm A—which has pre-existing strengths and weaknesses,core competencies and disabilities—organize X?”(Williamson1999,p.1103). TCE not only can be but has been and should be pushed to examine such circumstances by marketing research(John and Reve2010,p.283).Pragmatic methodologyBoth transaction cost economists and marketing specialists who have brought transaction cost analysis to bear on marketing issues(1)are interested in applied issues,(2) recognize that much of the relevant action resides in the microanalytics,(3)regard economizing on transaction costs to be important,and(4)believe that understanding complexity is a pluralist enterprise in which several focused lenses are usefully brought to bear.12Also,implicitly if not explicitly,many transaction cost economists and marketing scholars subscribe to the four precepts of pragmatic methodology.A sketchPragmatic methodology is herein discussed in a two-part way.The four precepts of pragmatic methodology are set out first.The transaction cost economics ramifications of the four precepts are then examined.13Describing himself as a native informant rather than as a certified methodologist,Robert Solow offers a“terse description of what one economist thinks he is doing”(2001,p.111)in the form of three precepts:keep it simple; get it right;make it plausible.Keeping it simple is accomplished by stripping away inessentials,thereby to 12Some marketing scholars are keen to move beyond the baseline setup and address new challenges.Others appear to believe that the basic model is unduly simple and/or over constraining.Although we applaud efforts to move beyond the basic setup,we believe that TCE is foundational and take the occasion here to set out the rudiments.13This discussion of pragmatic methodology is based on Williamson (2009,pp.145–157).focus on first order effects—the main case,as it were—after which qualifications,refinements,and extensions can be introduced.Getting it right entails working out the logic. And making it plausible means preserving contact with the phenomena and eschewing fanciful constructions.Solow observes with reference to the simplicity precept that“the very complexity of real life…[is what]makes simple models so necessary”(2001,p.111).Keeping it simple requires the student of complexity to prioritize:“Most phenomena are driven by a very few central forces. What a good theory does is to simplify,it pulls out the central forces and gets rid of the rest”(Friedman1997,p. 196).Central features and key regularities are uncovered by the application of a focused lens.Getting it right“includes translating economic concepts into accurate mathematics(or diagrams,or words)and making sure that further logical operations are correctly performed and verified”(Solow2001,p.112);plausible simple models of complex phenomena are expected to “make sense for reasonable or plausible values of the important parameters”(Solow2001,p.112).Also,because “not everything that is logically consistent is credulous”(Kreps1999,p.125),fanciful constructions that lose contact with the phenomena are suspect—especially if alternative and more realistic models yield refutable implications that are congruent with the data.This last brings us to a fourth precept:derive refutable implications to which the relevant(often microanalytic) data are brought to bear.Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen had a felicitous way of putting it:“The purpose of science in general is not prediction,but knowledge for its own sake,”yet prediction is“the touchstone of scientific knowledge”(1971,p.37).Indeed,most economists know in their bones that theories that are congruent with the data are more ton Friedman’s reflections on a lifetime of work are pertinent:“I believe in every area where I feel that I have had some influence it has occurred less because of the pure analysis than it has because of the empirical evidence that I have been able to organize.”14Inasmuch as the social sciences deal with exceptionally complex phenomena(Simon1957,p.89;Wilson1999,p. 183),“any direction you proceed in has a very high a priori probability of being wrong;so it is good if other people are exploring in other directions”(Simon1992,p.21). Accordingly,we are concerned with theories(plural)rather than a theory(singular).Also pertinent in this connection is that theories rarely appear full blown but undergo a natural progression—from informal to pre-formal,semi-formal, and fully formal stages of development—over which interval the relation between the theory and the evidence is interactive(Newell1990,p.14).Successive refinements and reformulations of a theory do not,however,go on indefinitely.Sooner or later the time comes for a reckoning when each would-be theory needs to stand up and be counted—by which we mean that each candidate theory should be examined with reference to the four precepts of pragmatic methodology,with special emphasis on the last.TCE’s responses to the four preceptsTransaction cost economics subscribes to this framework and advises other would-be theories of firm and market organization to do the same.The TCE response to the first precept—keep it simple—is to take economizing on transaction costs to be the main case.As discussed earlier, this is implemented by taking adaptation to be the main problem of organization,of which autonomous and coordi-nated adaptations are distinguished—where autonomous adaptations are accomplished in the market in response to changes in relative prices(and constitute the“marvel of the market”to which Hayek(1945)gave prominence),whereas coordinated adaptations are accomplished in a“conscious, deliberate,purposeful”way with the support of hierarchy (and constitute the“marvel of hierarchy”to which Barnard (1938)gave prominence).The transaction cost economics response to the precept “get it right”is to examine the economizing purposes of economic organization through the lens of contract,rather than rely entirely on the neoclassical lens of choice.As applied to the economics of organization,the lens of contract divides into two parts:ex ante incentive alignment and ex post governance.Of these two,transaction cost economics focuses predominantly on the ex post gover-nance of contractual relations,with emphasis on the mutual gains to be realized by looking ahead,identifying hazards, and crafting cost effective credible commitments—which, in the limit,entail taking transactions out of the market and organizing them hierarchically under unified owner-ship.The move from the lens of choice to the lens of contract is consequential.Whereas textbook economic theory treats the firm as a black box for transforming inputs into outputs according to the laws of technology, as a consequence of which organization is unimportant, TCE expressly holds otherwise.Not only is organization important,but operationalization is undertaken with the object of making organization susceptible to analysis.The governance of contractual relations prominently makes its appearance.Making it plausible poses unexamined tensions with both of the first two precepts.When plausibility collides with simplicity and mathematical tractability,what to do?14Personal communications from Milton Friedman to Oliver Williamson,February6,2006.。