投资学10版习题答案11

合集下载

投资学习题+答案

投资学习题+答案

投资学习题+答案一、单选题(共30题,每题1分,共30分)1、若提高一只债券的初始到期收益率,其他因素不变,该债券的久期( )。

A、变小B、无法判断C、变大D、不变正确答案:A2、以下说法不正确的是( )。

A、价格高开低收产生阴K线B、光头阳K线说明以当日最高价收盘C、价格低开高收产生阳K线D、今日价格高于前日价格必定是阳K线正确答案:D3、在周期天数少的移动平均线从下向上突破周期天数较多的移动平均线时,为股票的( )。

A、卖出信号B、买入信号C、等待信号D、持有信号正确答案:B4、合格的境内机构投资者的英文简称为( )。

A、QFIIB、QDIIC、RQFIID、RQDII正确答案:B5、有四种面值均为100元的债券,投资者预期未来市场利率会下降,应该买入( )。

债券名称到期期限票面利率甲 10年 6%乙 8年 5%丙 8年 6%丁 10年 5%A、乙B、丙C、甲D、丁正确答案:D6、投资与投机事实上在追求( )目标上是一致的。

A、风险B、处理风险的态度上C、投资收益D、组织结构上正确答案:C7、除权的原因不包括( )。

A、发放红股B、配股C、对外进行重大投资D、资本公积金转增股票正确答案:C8、一个股票看跌期权卖方承受的最大损失是( )。

A、执行价格减去看跌期权价格B、执行价格C、股价减去看跌期权价格D、看跌期权价格正确答案:A9、某项投资不融资时获得的收益率是20%,如果融资保证金比例为80%,则投资人融资时在该项投资上最高可以获得的收益率是( )。

A、28%B、40%C、58%D、45%正确答案:D10、股票看涨期权卖方承受的最大损失可能是( )。

A、无限大B、执行价格减去看涨期权价格C、看涨期权价格D、执行价格正确答案:A11、下面哪一种形态是股价反转向上的形态( )。

A、头肩顶B、三重顶C、双底D、双顶正确答案:C12、下列关于证券投资的风险与收益的描述中,错误的是( )。

A、在证券投资中,收益和风险形影相随,收益以风险为代价,风险用收益来补偿B、风险和收益的本质联系可以用公式表述为:预期收益率=无风险利率+风险补偿C、美国一般将联邦政府发行的短期国库券视为无风险证券,把短期国库券利率视为无风险利率D、在通货膨胀严重的情况下,债券的票面利率会提高或是会发行浮动利率债券,这种情况是对利率风险的补偿正确答案:D13、若提高一只债券的票面利率,其他因素不变,该债券的久期( )。

金德环《投资学》课后习题答案

金德环《投资学》课后习题答案

金德环《投资学》课后习题答案习题答案第一章习题答案第二章习题答案练习题1:答案:(1),公司股票的预期收益率与标准差为:Er,,,,,,,0.570.350.2206,,,,,,,,A1/2222,, ,0.5760.3560.22068.72,,,,,,,,,,,,,,A,,(2),公司和,公司股票的收益之间的协方差为:Covrr,0.5762510.50.3561010.5,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,AB ,,,,,,0.22062510.590.5,,,,(3),公司和,公司股票的收益之间的相关系数为:Covrr,,,,90.5AB ,,,,,0.55AB,8.7218.90,,AB练习题2:答案:如果,,,的投资投资于,公司,余下,,,投资于,公司的股票,这样得出的资产组合的概率分布如下:钢生产正常年份钢生产异常年份股市为牛市股市为熊市概率 0.5 0.3 0.2 资产组合收益率(,) ,, ,., -2.5 得出资产组合均值和标准差为:Er=0.516+0.32.5+0.2-2.5=8.25,,,,,,,,,,组合1/22222,, ,=0.516-8.25+0.32.5-8.25+0.2-2.5-8.25+0.2-2.5-8.25=7.94,,,,,,,,组合,,1/22222,=0.518.9+0.58.72+20.50.5-90.5=7.94,,,,,,,,,,,,,,,组合,,练习题3:答案:尽管黄金投资独立看来似有股市控制,黄金仍然可以在一个分散化的资产组合中起作用。

因为黄金与股市收益的相关性很小,股票投资者可以通过将其部分资金投资于黄金来分散其资产组合的风险。

练习题4:答案:通过计算两个项目的变异系数来进行比较:0.075 CV==1.88A0.040.09 CV==0.9B0.1考虑到相对离散程度,投资项目B更有利。

练习题5:答案:R(1)回归方程解释能力到底如何的一种测度方法式看的总方差中可被方程解释的方差所it2,占的比例。

博迪《投资学》(第10版)笔记和课后习题详解答案

博迪《投资学》(第10版)笔记和课后习题详解答案

博迪《投资学》(第10版)笔记和课后习题详解答案博迪《投资学》(第10版)笔记和课后习题详解完整版>精研学习?>无偿试用20%资料全国547所院校视频及题库全收集考研全套>视频资料>课后答案>往年真题>职称考试第一部分绪论第1章投资环境1.1复习笔记1.2课后习题详解第2章资产类别与金融工具2.1复习笔记2.2课后习题详解第3章证券是如何交易的3.1复习笔记3.2课后习题详解第4章共同基金与其他投资公司4.1复习笔记4.2课后习题详解第二部分资产组合理论与实践第5章风险与收益入门及历史回顾5.1复习笔记5.2课后习题详解第6章风险资产配置6.1复习笔记6.2课后习题详解第7章最优风险资产组合7.1复习笔记7.2课后习题详解第8章指数模型8.2课后习题详解第三部分资本市场均衡第9章资本资产定价模型9.1复习笔记9.2课后习题详解第10章套利定价理论与风险收益多因素模型10.1复习笔记10.2课后习题详解第11章有效市场假说11.1复习笔记11.2课后习题详解第12章行为金融与技术分析12.1复习笔记12.2课后习题详解第13章证券收益的实证证据13.1复习笔记13.2课后习题详解第四部分固定收益证券第14章债券的价格与收益14.1复习笔记14.2课后习题详解第15章利率的期限结构15.1复习笔记15.2课后习题详解第16章债券资产组合管理16.1复习笔记16.2课后习题详解第五部分证券分析第17章宏观经济分析与行业分析17.2课后习题详解第18章权益估值模型18.1复习笔记18.2课后习题详解第19章财务报表分析19.1复习笔记19.2课后习题详解第六部分期权、期货与其他衍生证券第20章期权市场介绍20.1复习笔记20.2课后习题详解第21章期权定价21.1复习笔记21.2课后习题详解第22章期货市场22.1复习笔记22.2课后习题详解第23章期货、互换与风险管理23.1复习笔记23.2课后习题详解第七部分应用投资组合管理第24章投资组合业绩评价24.1复习笔记24.2课后习题详解第25章投资的国际分散化25.1复习笔记25.2课后习题详解第26章对冲基金26.1复习笔记26.2课后习题详解第27章积极型投资组合管理理论27.1复习笔记27.2课后习题详解第28章投资政策与特许金融分析师协会结构28.1复习笔记28.2课后习题详解。

投资学第10版课后习题答案

投资学第10版课后习题答案

CHAPTER 4: MUTUAL FUNDS AND OTHER INVESTMENTCOMPANIESPROBLEM SETS1. The unit investment trust should have lower operating expenses.Because the investment trust portfolio is fixed once the trust isestablished, it does not have to pay portfolio managers toconstantly monitor and rebalance the portfolio as perceived needsor opportunities change. Because the portfolio is fixed, the unitinvestment trust also incurs virtually no trading costs.2. a. Unit investment trusts: Diversification from large-scaleinvesting, lower transaction costs associated with large-scaletrading, low management fees, predictable portfolio composition,guaranteed low portfolio turnover rate.b. Open-end mutual funds: Diversification from large-scaleinvesting, lower transaction costs associated with large-scaletrading, professional management that may be able to takeadvantage of buy or sell opportunities as they arise, recordkeeping.c. Individual stocks and bonds: No management fee; ability tocoordinate realization of capital gains or losses withinvestors’ personal tax situation s; capability of designingportfolio to investor’s specific risk and return profile.3. Open-end funds are obligated to redeem investor's shares at netasset value and thus must keep cash or cash-equivalent securitieson hand in order to meet potential redemptions. Closed-end funds do not need the cash reserves because there are no redemptions forclosed-end funds. Investors in closed-end funds sell their shareswhen they wish to cash out.4. Balanced funds keep relatively stable proportions of funds investedin each asset class. They are meant as convenient instruments toprovide participation in a range of asset classes. Life-cycle fundsare balanced funds whose asset mix generally depends on the age of the investor. Aggressive life-cycle funds, with larger investments in equities, are marketed to younger investors, while conservative life-cycle funds, with larger investments in fixed-income securities, are designed for older investors. Asset allocation funds, in contrast, may vary the proportions invested in each asset class by large amounts as predictions of relative performance across classes vary. Asset allocation funds therefore engage in more aggressive market timing.5. Unlike an open-end fund, in which underlying shares are redeemedwhen the fund is redeemed, a closed-end fund trades as a security in the market. Thus, their prices may differ from the NAV.6. Advantages of an ETF over a mutual fund:ETFs are continuously traded and can be sold or purchased on margin.There are no capital gains tax triggers when an ETF is sold(shares are just sold from one investor to another).Investors buy from brokers, thus eliminating the cost ofdirect marketing to individual small investors. This implieslower management fees.Disadvantages of an ETF over a mutual fund:Prices can depart from NAV (unlike an open-end fund).There is a broker fee when buying and selling (unlike a no-load fund).7. The offering price includes a 6% front-end load, or salescommission, meaning that every dollar paid results in only $ going toward purchase of shares. Therefore: Offering price =06.0170.10$Load 1NAV -=-= $8. NAV = Offering price (1 –Load) = $ .95 = $9. Stock Value Held by FundA $ 7,000,000B 12,000,000C 8,000,000D 15,000,000Total $42,000,000Net asset value =000,000,4000,30$000,000,42$-= $10. Value of stocks sold and replaced = $15,000,000 Turnover rate =000,000,42$000,000,15$= , or %11. a. 40.39$000,000,5000,000,3$000,000,200$NAV =-=b. Premium (or discount) = NAVNAV ice Pr - = 40.39$40.39$36$-= –, or % The fund sells at an % discount from NAV.12. 100NAV NAV Distributions $12.10$12.50$1.500.088, or 8.8%NAV $12.50-+-+==13. a. Start-of-year price: P 0 = $ × = $End-of-year price: P 1 = $ × = $Although NAV increased by $, the price of the fund decreased by $. Rate of return =100Distributions $11.25$12.24$1.500.042, or 4.2%$12.24P P P -+-+==b. An investor holding the same securities as the fund managerwould have earned a rate of return based on the increase in the NAV of the portfolio:100NAV NAV Distributions $12.10$12.00$1.500.133, or 13.3%NAV $12.00-+-+==14. a. Empirical research indicates that past performance of mutualfunds is not highly predictive of future performance,especially for better-performing funds. While there may be some tendency for the fund to be an above average performer nextyear, it is unlikely to once again be a top 10% performer.b. On the other hand, the evidence is more suggestive of atendency for poor performance to persist. This tendency isprobably related to fund costs and turnover rates. Thus if the fund is among the poorest performers, investors should beconcerned that the poor performance will persist.15. NAV 0 = $200,000,000/10,000,000 = $20Dividends per share = $2,000,000/10,000,000 = $NAV1 is based on the 8% price gain, less the 1% 12b-1 fee: NAV1 = $20 (1 – = $Rate of return =20$20 .0$20$384.21$+-= , or %16. The excess of purchases over sales must be due to new inflows intothe fund. Therefore, $400 million of stock previously held by the fund was replaced by new holdings. So turnover is: $400/$2,200 = , or %.17. Fees paid to investment managers were: $ billion = $ millionSince the total expense ratio was % and the management fee was %, we conclude that % must be for other expenses. Therefore, other administrative expenses were: $ billion = $ million.18. As an initial approximation, your return equals the return on the shares minus the total of the expense ratio and purchase costs: 12% % 4% = %.But the precise return is less than this because the 4% load is paid up front, not at the end of the year. To purchase the shares, you would have had to invest: $20,000/(1 = $20,833. The shares increase in value from $20,000 to: $20,000 = $22,160. The rate of return is: ($22,160 $20,833)/$20,833 = %.19. Assume $1,000 investmentLoaded-Up Fund Economy Fund Yearly growth (r is 6%) (1.01.0075)r +-- (.98)(1.0025)r ⨯+- t = 1 year$1, $1, t = 3 years$1, $1, t = 10 years$1, $1,20. a. $450,000,000$10,000000$1044,000,000-= b. The redemption of 1 million shares will most likely triggercapital gains taxes which will lower the remaining portfolio by an amount greater than $10,000,000 (implying a remaining total value less than $440,000,000). The outstanding shares fall to 43 million and the NAV drops to below $10.21. Suppose you have $1,000 to invest. The initial investment in ClassA shares is $940 net of the front-end load. After four years, yourportfolio will be worth:$940 4 = $1,Class B shares allow you to invest the full $1,000, but yourinvestment performance net of 12b-1 fees will be only %, and you will pay a 1% back-end load fee if you sell after four years. Your portfolio value after four years will be:$1,000 4 = $1,After paying the back-end load fee, your portfolio value will be:$1, .99 = $1,Class B shares are the better choice if your horizon is four years.With a 15-year horizon, the Class A shares will be worth:$940 15 = $3,For the Class B shares, there is no back-end load in this casesince the horizon is greater than five years. Therefore, the value of the Class B shares will be:$1,000 15 = $3,At this longer horizon, Class B shares are no longer the betterchoice. The effect of Class B's % 12b-1 fees accumulates over time and finally overwhelms the 6% load charged to Class A investors.22. a. After two years, each dollar invested in a fund with a 4% loadand a portfolio return equal to r will grow to: $ (1 + r–2.Each dollar invested in the bank CD will grow to: $1 .If the mutual fund is to be the better investment, then theportfolio return (r) must satisfy:(1 + r–2 >(1 + r–2 >(1 + r–2 >1 + r– >1 + r >Therefore: r > = %b. If you invest for six years, then the portfolio return mustsatisfy:(1 + r–6 > =(1 + r–6 >1 + r– >r > %The cutoff rate of return is lower for the six-year investment because the “fixed cost” (the one-time front-end load) is spread over a greater number of years.c. With a 12b-1 fee instead of a front-end load, the portfoliomust earn a rate of return (r ) that satisfies:1 + r – – >In this case, r must exceed % regardless of the investmenthorizon.23. The turnover rate is 50%. This means that, on average, 50% of theportfolio is sold and replaced with other securities each year. Trading costs on the sell orders are % and the buy orders toreplace those securities entail another % in trading costs. Total trading costs will reduce portfolio returns by: 2 % = %24. For the bond fund, the fraction of portfolio income given up tofees is: %0.4%6.0= , or % For the equity fund, the fraction of investment earnings given up to fees is:%0.12%6.0= , or % Fees are a much higher fraction of expected earnings for the bond fund and therefore may be a more important factor in selecting the bond fund.This may help to explain why unmanaged unit investment trusts are concentrated in the fixed income market. The advantages of unit investment trusts are low turnover, low trading costs, and low management fees. This is a more important concern to bond-market investors.25. Suppose that finishing in the top half of all portfolio managers ispurely luck, and that the probability of doing so in any year is exactly ½. Then the probability that any particular manager would finish in the top half of the sample five years in a row is (½)5 = 1/32. We would then expect to find that [350 (1/32)] = 11managers finish in the top half for each of the five consecutiveyears. This is precisely what we found. Thus, we should not conclude that the consistent performance after five years is proof of skill. We would expect to find 11 managers exhibiting precisely this level of "consistency" even if performance is due solely to luck.。

《投资学》课后习题参考答案

《投资学》课后习题参考答案

习题参考答案第2章答案:一、选择1、D2、C二、填空1、公众投资者、工商企业投资者、政府2、中国人民保险公司;中国国际信托投资公司3、威尼斯、英格兰4、信用合作社、合作银行;农村信用合作社、城市信用合作社;5、安全性、流动性、效益性三、名词解释:财务公司又称金融公司,是一种经营部分银行业务的非银行金融机构。

其最初是为产业集团内部各分公司筹资,便利集团内部资金融通,但现在经营领域不断扩大,种类不断增加,有的专门经营抵押放款业务,有的专门经营耐用消费品的租购和分期付款业务,大的财务公司还兼营外汇、联合贷款、包销证券、不动产抵押、财务及投资咨询服务等。

信托公司是指以代人理财为主要经营内容、以委托人身份经营现代信托业务的金融机构。

信托公司的业务一般包括货币信托(信托贷款、信托存款、养老金信托、有价证券投资信托等)和非货币信托(债权信托、不动产信托、动产信托等)两大类。

保险公司是一类经营保险业务的金融中介机构。

它以集合多数单位或个人的风险为前提,用其概率计算分摊金,以保险费的形式聚集资金建立保险基金,用于补偿因自然灾害或以外事故造成的经济损失,或对个人因死亡伤残给予物质补偿。

四、简答1、家庭个人是金融市场上的主要资金供应者,其呈现出的主要特点如下:(1)投资目标简单;(2)投资活动更具盲目性(3)投资规模较小,投资方向分散,投资形式灵活。

企业作为非金融投资机构,其行为呈现出了以下的显著特点:(1)资金需求者地位突现;(2)投资目标的多元化;(3)投资比较稳定;(4)短期投资交易量大。

2、商业银行在经济运行中主要的职能如下:(1)信用中介职能;(2)支付中介职能;(3)调节媒介职能;(4)金融服务职能;(5)信用创造职能;总的来说,商业银行业务可以归为以下三类:(1)负债业务:是指资金来源的业务;(2)资产业务:是商业银行运用资金的业务;(3)中间业务和表外业务:中间业务指银行不需要运用自己的资金而代客户承办支付和其他委托事项,并据以收取手续费的业务第3章答案:一、选择题1、D2、D3、B二、填空题1、会员制证券交易所和公司制证券交易所、会员制、公司制。

投资学第10版习题答案

投资学第10版习题答案

CHAPTER 8: INDEX MODELSPROBLEM SETS1. The advantage of the index model, compared to the Markowitz procedure, is thevastly reduced number of estimates required. In addition, the large number ofestimates required for the Markowitz procedure can result in large aggregateestimation errors when implementing the procedure. The disadvantage of the index model arises from the model’s assumption that return residuals are uncorrelated.This assumption will be incorrect if the index used omits a significant risk factor.2. The trade-off entailed in departing from pure indexing in favor of an activelymanaged portfolio is between the probability (or the possibility) of superiorperformance against the certainty of additional management fees.3. The answer to this question can be seen from the formulas for w0 (equation 8.20)and w* (equation 8.21). Other things held equal, w0 is smaller the greater theresidual variance of a candidate asset for inclusion in the portfolio. Further, we see that regardless of beta, when w0 decreases, so does w*. Therefore, other thingsequal, the greater the residual variance of an asset, the smaller its position in the optimal risky portfolio. That is, increased firm-specific risk reduces the extent to which an active investor will be willing to depart from an indexed portfolio.4. The total risk premium equals: ? + (? × Market risk premium). We call alpha anonmarket return premium because it is the portion of the return premium that is independent of market performance.The Sharpe ratio indicates that a higher alpha makes a security more desirable.Alpha, the numerator of the Sharpe ratio, is a fixed number that is not affected by the standard deviation of returns, the denominator of the Sharpe ratio. Hence, an increase in alpha increases the Sharpe ratio. Since the portfolio alpha is theportfolio-weighted average of the securities’ alphas, then, holding all otherparameters fixed, an increase in a security’s alpha results in an increase in theportfolio Sharpe ratio.5. a. To optimize this portfolio one would need:n = 60 estimates of means n = 60 estimates of variances770,122=-nn estimates of covariances Therefore, in total: 890,1232=+nn estimatesb.In a single index model: r i ? r f = α i + β i (r M – r f ) + e i Equivalently, using excess returns: R i = α i + β i R M + e iThe variance of the rate of return can be decomposed into the components: (l)The variance due to the common market factor: 22M i σβ(2) The variance due to firm specific unanticipated events: )(σ2i e In this model: σββ),(Cov j i j i r r = The number of parameter estimates is:n = 60 estimates of the mean E (r i )n = 60 estimates of the sensitivity coefficient β i n = 60 estimates of the firm-specific variance σ2(e i ) 1 estimate of the market mean E (r M )1 estimate of the market variance 2M σTherefore, in total, 182 estimates.The single index model reduces the total number of required estimates from 1,890 to 182. In general, the number of parameter estimates is reduced from:)23( to 232+⎪⎪⎭⎫ ⎝⎛+n n n6.a.The standard deviation of each individual stock is given by:2/1222)](β[σi M i i e σσ+=Since βA = 0.8, βB = 1.2, σ(e A ) = 30%, σ(e B ) = 40%, and σM = 22%, we get:σA = (0.82 × 222 + 302 )1/2 = 34.78% σB = (1.22 × 222 + 402 )1/2 = 47.93%b.The expected rate of return on a portfolio is the weighted average of the expected returns of the individual securities:E(r P ) = w A × E(r A ) + w B × E(r B ) + w f × r fE(r P ) = (0.30 × 13%) + (0.45 × 18%) + (0.25 × 8%) = 14% The beta of a portfolio is similarly a weighted average of the betas of the individual securities:βP = w A × βA + w B × βB + w f × β fβP = (0.30 × 0.8) + (0.45 × 1.2) + (0.25 × 0.0) = 0.78 The variance of this portfolio is:)(σβσ2222P M P P e +=σwhere 22σβM P is the systematic component and )(2P e σis the nonsystematic component. Since the residuals (e i ) are uncorrelated, the nonsystematic variance is:2222222()()()()P A A B B f f e w e w e w e σσσσ=⨯+⨯+⨯= (0.302 × 302 ) + (0.452 × 402 ) + (0.252 × 0) = 405where σ2(e A ) and σ2(e B ) are the firm-specific (nonsystematic) variances of Stocks A and B, and σ2(e f ), the nonsystematic variance of T-bills, is zero. The residual standard deviation of the portfolio is thus:σ(e P ) = (405)1/2 = 20.12% The total variance of the portfolio is then:47.699405)2278.0(σ222=+⨯=PThe total standard deviation is 26.45%.7.a.The two figures depict the stocks’ security characteri stic lines (SCL). Stock A has higher firm-specific risk because the deviations of the observations from the SCL are larger for Stock A than for Stock B. Deviations are measured by the vertical distance of each observation from the SCL.b. Beta is the slope of the SCL, which is the measure of systematic risk. The SCL for Stock B is st eeper; hence Stock B’s systematic risk is greater.c.The R 2 (or squared correlation coefficient) of the SCL is the ratio of the explained variance of the stock’s return to total variance, and the totalvariance is the sum of the explained variance plus the unexplained variance (the stock’s residual variance):)(σσβσβ222222i M i M i e R += Since the explained variance for Stock B is greater than for Stock A (theexplained variance is 22σβM B , which is greater since its beta is higher), and its residual variance 2()B e σ is smaller, its R 2 is higher than Stock A’s.d. Alpha is the intercept of the SCL with the expected return axis. Stock A has a small positive alpha whereas Stock B has a negative alpha; hence, Stock A’s alpha is larger.e. The correlation coefficient is simply the square root of R 2, so Stock B’s correlation with the market is higher.8. a.Firm-specific risk is measured by the residual standard deviation. Thus, stock A has more firm-specific risk: 10.3% > 9.1%b. Market risk is measured by beta, the slope coefficient of the regression. A has a larger beta coefficient: 1.2 > 0.8c. R 2 measures the fraction of total variance of return explained by the market return. A’s R 2 is larger than B’s: 0.576 > 0.436d.Rewriting the SCL equation in terms of total return (r ) rather than excess return (R ):()(1)A f M f A f Mr r r r r r r αβαββ-=+⨯-⇒=+⨯-+⨯The intercept is now equal to:(1)1%(1 1.2)f f r r αβ+⨯-=+⨯-Since r f = 6%, the intercept would be: 1%6%(1 1.2)1% 1.2%0.2%+-=-=-9.The standard deviation of each stock can be derived from the following equation for R 2:==2222σσβiMi iR Explained variance Total variance Therefore:%30.31σ98020.0207.0σβσ222222==⨯==A A MA AR For stock B:%28.69σ800,412.0202.1σ222==⨯=B B10. The systematic risk for A is:22220.7020196A M βσ⨯=⨯=The firm-specific risk of A (the residual variance) is the difference between A’s total risk and its systematic risk:980 – 196 = 784 The systematic risk for B is:22221.2020576B M βσ⨯=⨯=B’s firm -specific risk (residual variance) is:4,800 – 576 = 4,22411. The covariance between the returns of A and B is (since the residuals are assumedto be uncorrelated):33640020.170.0σββ)(Cov 2=⨯⨯==M B A B A ,r rThe correlation coefficient between the returns of A and B is:155.028.6930.31336σσ),(Cov ρ=⨯==B A B A AB r r12. Note that the correlation is the square root of R 2:2ρR =1/2,1/2,()0.2031.3020280()0.1269.2820480A M A MB M B M Cov r r Cov r r ρσσρσσ==⨯⨯===⨯⨯=13. For portfolio P we can compute:σP = [(0.62 × 980) + (0.42 × 4800) + (2 × 0.4 × 0.6 × 336)]1/2 = [1282.08]1/2 = 35.81% βP = (0.6 × 0.7) + (0.4 × 1.2) = 0.90958.08400)(0.901282.08σβσ)(σ22222=⨯-=-=M P P P eCov(r P ,r M ) = βP 2σM =0.90 ×400=360 This same result can also be attained using the covariances of the individual stocks with the market:Cov(r P ,r M ) = Cov(0.6r A + 0.4r B , r M ) = 0.6 × Cov(r A , r M ) + 0.4 × Cov(r B ,r M )= (0.6 × 280) + (0.4 × 480) = 36014. Note that the variance of T-bills is zero, and the covariance of T-bills with any assetis zero. Therefore, for portfolio Q:[][]%55.21)3603.05.02()4003.0()08.282,15.0(),(Cov 2σσσ2/1222/12222=⨯⨯⨯+⨯+⨯=⨯⨯⨯++=M P M P M M P P Q r r w w w w(0.50.90)(0.31)(0.200)0.75Q P P M M w w βββ=+=⨯+⨯+⨯=52.239)40075.0(52.464σβσ)(σ22222=⨯-=-=M Q Q Q e30040075.0σβ),(Cov 2=⨯==M Q M Q r r15. a.Beta Books adjusts beta by taking the sample estimate of beta and averaging it with 1.0, using the weights of 2/3 and 1/3, as follows:adjusted beta = [(2/3) × 1.24] + [(1/3) × 1.0] = 1.16b. If you use your current estimate of beta to be βt –1 = 1.24, thenβt = 0.3 + (0.7 × 1.24) = 1.16816. For Stock A:[()].11[.060.8(.12.06)]0.2%A A f A M f r r r r αβ=-+⨯-=-+⨯-= For stock B:[()].14[.06 1.5(.12.06)]1%B B f B M f r r r r αβ=-+⨯-=-+⨯-=-Stock A would be a good addition to a well-diversified portfolio. A short position in Stock B may be desirable. 17. a.Alpha (α)Expected excess returnαi = r i – [r f + βi × (r M – r f ) ]E (r i ) – r f αA = 20% – [8% + 1.3 × (16% – 8%)] = 1.6% 20% – 8% = 12% αB = 18% – [8% + 1.8 × (16% – 8%)] = – 4.4% 18% – 8% = 10% αC = 17% – [8% + 0.7 × (16% – 8%)] = 3.4% 17% – 8% = 9% αD = 12% – [8% + 1.0 × (16% – 8%)] = – 4.0%12% – 8% = 4%Stocks A and C have positive alphas, whereas stocks B and D have negative alphas.The residual variances are:?2(e A ) = 582 = 3,364 ?2(e B ) = 712 = 5,041 ?2(e C ) = 602 = 3,600 ?2(e D ) = 552 = 3,025b.To construct the optimal risky portfolio, we first determine the optimal active portfolio. Using the Treynor-Black technique, we construct the active portfolio:Be unconcerned with the negative weights of the positive α stocks —the entire active position will be negative, returning everything to good order.With these weights, the forecast for the active portfolio is:α = [–0.6142 × 1.6] + [1.1265 × (– 4.4)] – [1.2181 × 3.4] + [1.7058 × (– 4.0)] = –16.90%β = [–0.6142 × 1.3] + [1.1265 × 1.8] – [1.2181 × 0.70] + [1.7058 × 1] = 2.08 The high beta (higher than any individual beta) results from the short positions in the relatively low beta stocks and the long positions in the relatively high beta stocks.?2(e ) = [(–0.6142)2×3364] + [1.12652×5041] + [(–1.2181)2×3600] + [1.70582×3025]= 21,809.6 ? (e ) = 147.68%The levered position in B [with high ?2(e )] overcomes the diversificationeffect and results in a high residual standard deviation. The optimal risky portfolio has a proportion w * in the active portfolio, computed as follows:2022/().1690/21,809.60.05124[()]/.08/23M f Me w E r r ασσ-===-- The negative position is justified for the reason stated earlier. The adjustment for beta is:0486.0)05124.0)(08.21(105124.0)β1(1*00-=--+-=-+=w w wSince w * is negative, the result is a positive position in stocks with positive alphas and a negative position in stocks with negative alphas. The position in the index portfolio is:1 – (–0.0486) = 1.0486c.To calculate the Sharpe ratio for the optimal risky portfolio, we compute the information ratio for the active portfolio and Sharpe’s measure for the market portfolio. The information ratio for the active portfolio is computed as follows:A =()e ασ = –16.90/147.68 = –0.1144 A 2 = 0.0131Hence, the square of the Sharpe ratio (S) of the optimized risky portfolio is:1341.00131.02382222=+⎪⎭⎫ ⎝⎛=+=A S S MS = 0.3662Compare this to the market’s Sharpe ratio:S M = 8/23 = 0.3478 ✍ A difference of: 0.0184The only moderate improvement in performance results from only a small position taken in the active portfolio A because of its large residual variance.d.To calculate the makeup of the complete portfolio, first compute the beta, the mean excess return, and the variance of the optimal risky portfolio: βP = w M + (w A × βA ) = 1.0486 + [(–0.0486) ? 2.08] = 0.95E (R P ) = αP + βP E (R M ) = [(–0.0486) ? (–16.90%)] + (0.95 × 8%) = 8.42%()94.5286.809,21)0486.0()2395.0()(σσβσ222222=⨯-+⨯=+=P M P P e%00.23σ=PSince A = 2.8, the optimal position in this portfolio is:5685.094.5288.201.042.8=⨯⨯=yIn contrast, with a passive strategy:5401.0238.201.082=⨯⨯=y ✍A difference of: 0.0284 The final positions are (M may include some of stocks A through D): Bills 1 – 0.5685 = 43.15% M 0.5685 ? l.0486 = 59.61 A 0.5685 ? (–0.0486) ? (–0.6142) = 1.70 B 0.5685 ? (–0.0486) ? 1.1265 = – 3.11 C 0.5685 ? (–0.0486) ? (–1.2181) = 3.37 D 0.5685 ? (–0.0486) ? 1.7058 = – 4.71 (subject to rounding error) 100.00%18. a. I f a manager is not allowed to sell short, he will not include stocks with negative alphas in his portfolio, so he will consider only A and C:The forecast for the active portfolio is:α = (0.3352 × 1.6) + (0.6648 × 3.4) = 2.80% β = (0.3352 × 1.3) + (0.6648 × 0.7) = 0.90?2(e) = (0.33522 × 3,364) + (0.66482 × 3,600) = 1,969.03 σ(e) = 44.37%The weight in the active portfolio is:0940.023/803.969,1/80.2σ/)()(σ/α2220===MM R E e w Adjusting for beta:0931.0]094.0)90.01[(1094.0w )1(1w *w 00=⨯-+=β-+=The information ratio of the active portfolio is:2.800.0631()44.37A e ασ=== Hence, the square of the Sharpe ratio is:22280.06310.125023S ⎛⎫=+= ⎪⎝⎭Therefore: S = 0.3535The market’s Sharpe ratio is: S M = 0.3478When short sales are allowed (Problem 17), the manager’s Sharpe ratio is higher (0.3662). The reduction in the Sharpe ratio is the cost of the short sale restriction.The characteristics of the optimal risky portfolio are:222222(10.0931)(0.09310.9)0.99()()(0.0931 2.8%)(0.998%)8.18%()(0.9923)(0.09311969.03)535.5423.14%P M A A P P P M P P M P P w w E R E R e ββαβσβσσσ=+⨯=-+⨯==+⨯=⨯+⨯==⨯+=⨯+⨯== With A = 2.8, the optimal position in this portfolio is:5455.054.5358.201.018.8y =⨯⨯= The final positions in each asset are: Bills 1 – 0.5455 =45.45% M 0.5455 ? (1 ? 0.0931) =49.47 A 0.5455 ? 0.0931 ? 0.3352 =1.70 C 0.5455 ? 0.0931 ? 0.6648 =3.38100.00b. The mean and variance of the optimized complete portfolios in theunconstrained and short-sales constrained cases, and for the passive strategy are:E (R C ) 2σC Unconstrained0.5685 × 8.42% = 4.79 0.56852 × 528.94 = 170.95 Constrained0.5455 × 8.18% = 4.46 0.54552 × 535.54 = 159.36 Passive 0.5401 × 8.00% = 4.32 0.54012 × 529.00 = 154.31The utility levels below are computed using the formula: 2σ005.0)(C C A r E -Unconstrained8% + 4.79% – (0.005 × 2.8 × 170.95) = 10.40% Constrained8% + 4.46% – (0.005 × 2.8 × 159.36) = 10.23% Passive 8% + 4.32% – (0.005 × 2.8 × 154.31) = 10.16%19. All alphas are reduced to 0.3 times their values in the original case. Therefore, therelative weights of each security in the active portfolio are unchanged, but the alpha of the active portfolio is only 0.3 times its previous value: 0.3 × ?16.90% = ?5.07% The investor will take a smaller position in the active portfolio. The optimal risky portfolio has a proportion w * in the active portfolio as follows:2022/()0.0507/21,809.60.01537()/0.08/23M f M e w E r r ασσ-===-- The negative position is justified for the reason given earlier. The adjustment for beta is:0151.0)]01537.0()08.21[(101537.0)β1(1*00-=-⨯-+-=-+=w w w Since w * is negative, the result is a positive position in stocks with positive alphas and a negative position in stocks with negative alphas. The position in the index portfolio is: 1 – (–0.0151) = 1.0151To calculate the Sharpe ratio for the optimal risky portfolio we compute the information ratio for the active portfolio and the Sharpe ratio for the market portfolio. The information ratio of the active portfolio is 0.3 times its previous value: A = 5.07()147.68e ασ-== –0.0343 and A 2 =0.00118 Hence, the square of the Sharpe ratio of the optimized risky portfolio is:S 2 = S 2M + A 2 = (8%/23%)2 + 0.00118 = 0.1222S = 0.3495Compare this to the market’s Sharpe ratio: S M =8%23%= 0.3478 The difference is: 0.0017Note that the reduction of the forecast alphas by a factor of 0.3 reduced the squared information ratio and the improvement in the squared Sharpe ratio by a factor of: 0.32 = 0.0920. If each of the alpha forecasts is doubled, then the alpha of the active portfolio willalso double. Other things equal, the information ratio (IR) of the active portfolio also doubles. The square of the Sharpe ratio for the optimized portfolio (S -square) equals the square of the Sharpe ratio for the market index (SM -square) plus the square of the information ratio. Since the information ratio has doubled, its square quadruples. Therefore: S -square = SM -square + (4 × IR )Compared to the previous S -square, the difference is: 3IRNow you can embark on the calculations to verify this result.CFA PROBLEMS1. The regression results provide quantitative measures of return and risk based onmonthly returns over the five-year period.βfor ABC was 0.60, considerably less than the average stock’s β of 1.0. Thisindicates that, when the S&P 500 rose or fell by 1 percentage point, ABC’s returnon average rose or fell by only 0.60 percentage point. Therefore, ABC’s systematic risk (or market risk) was low relative to the typical value for stocks. ABC’s alpha(the intercept of the regression) was –3.2%, indicating that when the market returnwas 0%, the average return on ABC was –3.2%. ABC’s unsystematic risk (orresidual risk), as measured by σ(e), was 13.02%. For ABC, R2 was 0.35, indicating closeness of fit to the linear regression greater than the value for a typical stock.βfor XYZ was somewhat higher, at 0.97, indicating XYZ’s return pattern was very similar to the β for the market index. Therefore, XYZ stock had average systematic risk for the period examined. Alpha for XYZ was positive and quite large,indicating a return of 7.3%, on average, for XYZ independent of market return.Residual risk was 21.45%, half again as much as ABC’s, indicating a wider scatter of observations around the regression line for XYZ. Correspondingly, the fit of the regression model was considerably less than that of ABC, consistent with an R2 ofonly 0.17.The effects of including one or the other of these stocks in a diversified portfoliomay be quite different. If it can be assumed that both stocks’ betas will remainstable over time, then there is a large difference in systematic risk level. The betasobtained from the two brokerage houses may help the analyst draw inferences forthe future. The three estimates of ABC’s β are similar, regardless of the sampleperiod of the underlying data. The range of these estimates is 0.60 to 0.71, wellbelow the market average β of 1.0. The three estimates of XYZ’s β varysignificantly among the three sources, ranging as high as 1.45 for the weekly dataover the most recent two years. One could infer that XYZ’s β for the future mightbe well above 1.0, meaning it might have somewhat greater systematic risk thanwas implied by the monthly regression for the five-year period.These stocks appear to have significantly different systematic risk characteristics. If these stocks are added to a diversified portfolio, XYZ will add more to total volatility.2. The R2 of the regression is: 0.702 = 0.49Therefore, 51% of total variance is unexplained by the market; this is nonsystematic risk.3. 9 = 3 + ? (11 ? 3) ?? = 0.754. d.5. b.。

博迪《投资学》(第10版)笔记和课后习题详解 第11章~第13章【圣才出品】

博迪《投资学》(第10版)笔记和课后习题详解  第11章~第13章【圣才出品】

第11章有效市场假说11.1复习笔记1.随机漫步与有效市场假说随机漫步理论认为股价变动是随机且不可预测的。

正是市场上的充分的竞争消化了各种可得的市场信息,使得股价呈现随机游走的状态。

有效市场假定(EMH)认为任何可用于预测股票表现的信息一定已经在股价中被反映出来。

一旦有信息指出某种股票的价位被低估,存在一个套利机会,投资者的蜂拥购买会使股价立刻上升到正常的水平,从而只能得到与股票风险相称的收益率。

所以股价只对新信息做出上涨或下跌的反应。

由于新信息是不可预测的,股价的变动也是不可预测的,呈现随机游走的状态。

股价的这种变化规律正是反映了市场的有效性。

(1)有效性来源于竞争一般来说,只要进行分析,就能比别人得到更多的信息。

但是人们只有在收益高于分析花费的成本时,才愿意进行分析。

由于市场存在着激烈的竞争,证券分析师们具有强大财力支持、领取高薪、有野心,能够进行充分的信息挖掘,使得股价能够以适当的水平保证已有的信息,使市场能够较为接近有效水平。

(2)有效市场假说的形式有效市场假说一般有三种不同的形式:弱有效形式、半强有效形式和强有效形式。

这些形式通过对“全部可获得信息”的定义不同来区分。

①弱有效形式。

弱式有效市场假说认为,股价已经反映了全部能从市场交易数据中得到的信息。

股票的历史价格信息已经被市场充分消化,不可能通过市场的价格趋势分析获利。

②半强有效形式。

半强式有效市场假说认为,与公司前景有关的全部公开的已知信息一定已经在股价中反映出来了。

如果任一投资者能从公开已知资源获取这些信息,都可认为它会被反映在股价中。

③强有效形式。

强式有效市场假说认为股价反映了全部与公司有关的信息,甚至包括仅为内幕人员所知的信息。

所有有效市场假说的一个共同点:都提出价格应该反映可获得的信息。

2.有效市场假说的含义(1)技术分析技术分析中有两个常用的概念:阻力水平和支撑水平。

这些数值是指股价很难超越或不太可能再低于的水平,一般认为它们是由市场心理决定的。

投资学 (博迪) 第10版课后习题答案10 Investments 10th Edition Textbook Solutions Chapter 10

投资学 (博迪) 第10版课后习题答案10 Investments 10th Edition Textbook Solutions Chapter 10

CHAPTER 10: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY ANDMULTIFACTOR MODELS OF RISK AND RETURN PROBLEM SETS1. The revised estimate of the expected rate of return on the stock would be the oldestimate plus the sum of the products of the unexpected change in each factor times the respective sensitivity coefficient:Revised estimate = 12% + [(1 × 2%) + (0.5 × 3%)] = 15.5%Note that the IP estimate is computed as: 1 × (5% - 3%), and the IR estimate iscomputed as: 0.5 × (8% - 5%).2. The APT factors must correlate with major sources of uncertainty, i.e., sources ofuncertainty that are of concern to many investors. Researchers should investigatefactors that correlate with uncertainty in consumption and investment opportunities.GDP, the inflation rate, and interest rates are among the factors that can be expected to determine risk premiums. In particular, industrial production (IP) is a goodindicator of changes in the business cycle. Thus, IP is a candidate for a factor that is highly correlated with uncertainties that have to do with investment andconsumption opportunities in the economy.3. Any pattern of returns can be explained if we are free to choose an indefinitelylarge number of explanatory factors. If a theory of asset pricing is to have value, itmust explain returns using a reasonably limited number of explanatory variables(i.e., systematic factors such as unemployment levels, GDP, and oil prices).4. Equation 10.11 applies here:E(r p) = r f + βP1 [E(r1 ) −r f ] + βP2 [E(r2 ) – r f]We need to find the risk premium (RP) for each of the two factors:RP1 = [E(r1 ) −r f] and RP2 = [E(r2 ) −r f]In order to do so, we solve the following system of two equations with two unknowns: .31 = .06 + (1.5 ×RP1 ) + (2.0 ×RP2 ).27 = .06 + (2.2 ×RP1 ) + [(–0.2) ×RP2 ]The solution to this set of equations isRP1 = 10% and RP2 = 5%Thus, the expected return-beta relationship isE(r P) = 6% + (βP1× 10%) + (βP2× 5%)5. The expected return for portfolio F equals the risk-free rate since its beta equals 0.For portfolio A, the ratio of risk premium to beta is (12 − 6)/1.2 = 5For portfolio E, the ratio is lower at (8 – 6)/0.6 = 3.33This implies that an arbitrage opportunity exists. For instance, you can create aportfolio G with beta equal to 0.6 (the same as E’s) by combining portfolio A and portfolio F in equal weights. The expected return and beta for portfolio G are then: E(r G) = (0.5 × 12%) + (0.5 × 6%) = 9%βG = (0.5 × 1.2) + (0.5 × 0%) = 0.6Comparing portfolio G to portfolio E, G has the same beta and higher return.Therefore, an arbitrage opportunity exists by buying portfolio G and selling anequal amount of portfolio E. The profit for this arbitrage will ber G – r E =[9% + (0.6 ×F)] − [8% + (0.6 ×F)] = 1%That is, 1% of the funds (long or short) in each portfolio.6. Substituting the portfolio returns and betas in the expected return-beta relationship,we obtain two equations with two unknowns, the risk-free rate (r f) and the factor risk premium (RP):12% = r f + (1.2 ×RP)9% = r f + (0.8 ×RP)Solving these equations, we obtainr f = 3% and RP = 7.5%7. a. Shorting an equally weighted portfolio of the ten negative-alpha stocks andinvesting the proceeds in an equally-weighted portfolio of the 10 positive-alpha stocks eliminates the market exposure and creates a zero-investmentportfolio. Denoting the systematic market factor as R M, the expected dollarreturn is (noting that the expectation of nonsystematic risk, e, is zero):$1,000,000 × [0.02 + (1.0 ×R M)] − $1,000,000 × [(–0.02) + (1.0 ×R M)]= $1,000,000 × 0.04 = $40,000The sensitivity of the payoff of this portfolio to the market factor is zerobecause the exposures of the positive alpha and negative alpha stocks cancelout. (Notice that the terms involving R M sum to zero.) Thus, the systematiccomponent of total risk is also zero. The variance of the analyst’s profit is notzero, however, since this portfolio is not well diversified.For n = 20 stocks (i.e., long 10 stocks and short 10 stocks) the investor willhave a $100,000 position (either long or short) in each stock. Net marketexposure is zero, but firm-specific risk has not been fully diversified. Thevariance of dollar returns from the positions in the 20 stocks is20 × [(100,000 × 0.30)2] = 18,000,000,000The standard deviation of dollar returns is $134,164.b. If n = 50 stocks (25 stocks long and 25 stocks short), the investor will have a$40,000 position in each stock, and the variance of dollar returns is50 × [(40,000 × 0.30)2] = 7,200,000,000The standard deviation of dollar returns is $84,853.Similarly, if n = 100 stocks (50 stocks long and 50 stocks short), the investorwill have a $20,000 position in each stock, and the variance of dollar returns is100 × [(20,000 × 0.30)2] = 3,600,000,000The standard deviation of dollar returns is $60,000.Notice that, when the number of stocks increases by a factor of 5 (i.e., from 20 to 100), standard deviation decreases by a factor of 5= 2.23607 (from$134,164 to $60,000).8. a. )(σσβσ2222e M +=88125)208.0(σ2222=+×=A50010)200.1(σ2222=+×=B97620)202.1(σ2222=+×=Cb. If there are an infinite number of assets with identical characteristics, then awell-diversified portfolio of each type will have only systematic risk since thenonsystematic risk will approach zero with large n. Each variance is simply β2 × market variance:222Well-diversified σ256Well-diversified σ400Well-diversified σ576A B C;;;The mean will equal that of the individual (identical) stocks.c. There is no arbitrage opportunity because the well-diversified portfolios allplot on the security market line (SML). Because they are fairly priced, there isno arbitrage.9. a. A long position in a portfolio (P) composed of portfolios A and B will offer anexpected return-beta trade-off lying on a straight line between points A and B.Therefore, we can choose weights such that βP = βC but with expected returnhigher than that of portfolio C. Hence, combining P with a short position in Cwill create an arbitrage portfolio with zero investment, zero beta, and positiverate of return.b. The argument in part (a) leads to the proposition that the coefficient of β2must be zero in order to preclude arbitrage opportunities.10. a. E(r) = 6% + (1.2 × 6%) + (0.5 × 8%) + (0.3 × 3%) = 18.1%b.Surprises in the macroeconomic factors will result in surprises in the return ofthe stock:Unexpected return from macro factors =[1.2 × (4% – 5%)] + [0.5 × (6% – 3%)] + [0.3 × (0% – 2%)] = –0.3%E(r) =18.1% − 0.3% = 17.8%11. The APT required (i.e., equilibrium) rate of return on the stock based on r f and thefactor betas isRequired E(r) = 6% + (1 × 6%) + (0.5 × 2%) + (0.75 × 4%) = 16% According to the equation for the return on the stock, the actually expected return on the stock is 15% (because the expected surprises on all factors are zero bydefinition). Because the actually expected return based on risk is less than theequilibrium return, we conclude that the stock is overpriced.12. The first two factors seem promising with respect to the likely impact on the firm’scost of capital. Both are macro factors that would elicit hedging demands acrossbroad sectors of investors. The third factor, while important to Pork Products, is a poor choice for a multifactor SML because the price of hogs is of minor importance to most investors and is therefore highly unlikely to be a priced risk factor. Betterchoices would focus on variables that investors in aggregate might find moreimportant to their welfare. Examples include: inflation uncertainty, short-terminterest-rate risk, energy price risk, or exchange rate risk. The important point here is that, in specifying a multifactor SML, we not confuse risk factors that are important toa particular investor with factors that are important to investors in general; only the latter are likely to command a risk premium in the capital markets.13. The formula is ()0.04 1.250.08 1.50.02.1717%E r =+×+×==14. If 4%f r = and based on the sensitivities to real GDP (0.75) and inflation (1.25),McCracken would calculate the expected return for the Orb Large Cap Fund to be:()0.040.750.08 1.250.02.040.0858.5% above the risk free rate E r =+×+×=+=Therefore, Kwon’s fundamental analysis estimate is congruent with McCracken’sAPT estimate. If we assume that both Kwon and McCracken’s estimates on the return of Orb’s Large Cap Fund are accurate, then no arbitrage profit is possible.15. In order to eliminate inflation, the following three equations must be solvedsimultaneously, where the GDP sensitivity will equal 1 in the first equation,inflation sensitivity will equal 0 in the second equation and the sum of the weights must equal 1 in the third equation.1.1.250.75 1.012.1.5 1.25 2.003.1wx wy wz wz wy wz wx wy wz ++=++=++=Here, x represents Orb’s High Growth Fund, y represents Large Cap Fund and z represents Utility Fund. Using algebraic manipulation will yield wx = wy = 1.6 and wz = -2.2.16. Since retirees living off a steady income would be hurt by inflation, this portfoliowould not be appropriate for them. Retirees would want a portfolio with a return positively correlated with inflation to preserve value, and less correlated with the variable growth of GDP. Thus, Stiles is wrong. McCracken is correct in that supply side macroeconomic policies are generally designed to increase output at aminimum of inflationary pressure. Increased output would mean higher GDP, which in turn would increase returns of a fund positively correlated with GDP.17. The maximum residual variance is tied to the number of securities (n ) in theportfolio because, as we increase the number of securities, we are more likely to encounter securities with larger residual variances. The starting point is todetermine the practical limit on the portfolio residual standard deviation, σ(e P ), that still qualifies as a well-diversified portfolio. A reasonable approach is to compareσ2(e P) to the market variance, or equivalently, to compare σ(e P) to the market standard deviation. Suppose we do not allow σ(e P) to exceed pσM, where p is a small decimal fraction, for example, 0.05; then, the smaller the value we choose for p, the more stringent our criterion for defining how diversified a well-diversified portfolio must be.Now construct a portfolio of n securities with weights w1, w2,…,w n, so that Σw i =1. The portfolio residual variance is σ2(e P) = Σw12σ2(e i)To meet our practical definition of sufficiently diversified, we require this residual variance to be less than (pσM)2. A sure and simple way to proceed is to assume the worst, that is, assume that the residual variance of each security is the highest possible value allowed under the assumptions of the problem: σ2(e i) = nσ2MIn that case σ2(e P) = Σw i2 nσM2Now apply the constraint: Σw i2 nσM2 ≤ (pσM)2This requires that: nΣw i2 ≤ p2Or, equivalently, that: Σw i2 ≤ p2/nA relatively easy way to generate a set of well-diversified portfolios is to use portfolio weights that follow a geometric progression, since the computations then become relatively straightforward. Choose w1 and a common factor q for the geometric progression such that q < 1. Therefore, the weight on each stock is a fraction q of the weight on the previous stock in the series. Then the sum of n terms is:Σw i= w1(1– q n)/(1– q) = 1or: w1 = (1– q)/(1– q n)The sum of the n squared weights is similarly obtained from w12 and a common geometric progression factor of q2. ThereforeΣw i2 = w12(1– q2n)/(1– q 2)Substituting for w1 from above, we obtainΣw i2 = [(1– q)2/(1– q n)2] × [(1– q2n)/(1– q 2)]For sufficient diversification, we choose q so that Σw i2 ≤ p2/nFor example, continue to assume that p = 0.05 and n = 1,000. If we chooseq = 0.9973, then we will satisfy the required condition. At this value for q w1 = 0.0029 and w n = 0.0029 × 0.99731,000In this case, w1 is about 15 times w n. Despite this significant departure from equal weighting, this portfolio is nevertheless well diversified. Any value of q between0.9973 and 1.0 results in a well-diversified portfolio. As q gets closer to 1, theportfolio approaches equal weighting.18. a. Assume a single-factor economy, with a factor risk premium E M and a (large)set of well-diversified portfolios with beta βP. Suppose we create a portfolio Zby allocating the portion w to portfolio P and (1 – w) to the market portfolioM. The rate of return on portfolio Z is:R Z = (w × R P) + [(1 – w) × R M]Portfolio Z is riskless if we choose w so that βZ = 0. This requires that:βZ = (w × βP) + [(1 – w) × 1] = 0 ⇒w = 1/(1 – βP) and (1 – w) = –βP/(1 – βP)Substitute this value for w in the expression for R Z:R Z = {[1/(1 – βP)] × R P} – {[βP/(1 – βP)] × R M}Since βZ = 0, then, in order to avoid arbitrage, R Z must be zero.This implies that: R P = βP × R MTaking expectations we have:E P = βP × E MThis is the SML for well-diversified portfolios.b. The same argument can be used to show that, in a three-factor model withfactor risk premiums E M, E1 and E2, in order to avoid arbitrage, we must have:E P = (βPM × E M) + (βP1 × E1) + (βP2 × E2)This is the SML for a three-factor economy.19. a. The Fama-French (FF) three-factor model holds that one of the factors drivingreturns is firm size. An index with returns highly correlated with firm size (i.e.,firm capitalization) that captures this factor is SMB (small minus big), thereturn for a portfolio of small stocks in excess of the return for a portfolio oflarge stocks. The returns for a small firm will be positively correlated withSMB. Moreover, the smaller the firm, the greater its residual from the othertwo factors, the market portfolio and the HML portfolio, which is the returnfor a portfolio of high book-to-market stocks in excess of the return for aportfolio of low book-to-market stocks. Hence, the ratio of the variance of thisresidual to the variance of the return on SMB will be larger and, together withthe higher correlation, results in a high beta on the SMB factor.b.This question appears to point to a flaw in the FF model. The model predictsthat firm size affects average returns so that, if two firms merge into a largerfirm, then the FF model predicts lower average returns for the merged firm.However, there seems to be no reason for the merged firm to underperformthe returns of the component companies, assuming that the component firmswere unrelated and that they will now be operated independently. We mighttherefore expect that the performance of the merged firm would be the sameas the performance of a portfolio of the originally independent firms, but theFF model predicts that the increased firm size will result in lower averagereturns. Therefore, the question revolves around the behavior of returns for aportfolio of small firms, compared to the return for larger firms that resultfrom merging those small firms into larger ones. Had past mergers of smallfirms into larger firms resulted, on average, in no change in the resultantlarger firms’ stock return characteristics (compared to the portfolio of stocksof the merged firms), the size factor in the FF model would have failed.Perhaps the reason the size factor seems to help explain stock returns is that,when small firms become large, the characteristics of their fortunes (andhence their stock returns) change in a significant way. Put differently, stocksof large firms that result from a merger of smaller firms appear empirically tobehave differently from portfolios of the smaller component firms.Specifically, the FF model predicts that the large firm will have a smaller riskpremium. Notice that this development is not necessarily a bad thing for thestockholders of the smaller firms that merge. The lower risk premium may bedue, in part, to the increase in value of the larger firm relative to the mergedfirms.CFA PROBLEMS1. a. This statement is incorrect. The CAPM requires a mean-variance efficientmarket portfolio, but APT does not.b.This statement is incorrect. The CAPM assumes normally distributed securityreturns, but APT does not.c. This statement is correct.2. b. Since portfolio X has β = 1.0, then X is the market portfolio and E(R M) =16%.Using E(R M ) = 16% and r f = 8%, the expected return for portfolio Y is notconsistent.3. d.4. c.5. d.6. c. Investors will take on as large a position as possible only if the mispricingopportunity is an arbitrage. Otherwise, considerations of risk anddiversification will limit the position they attempt to take in the mispricedsecurity.7. d.8. d.。

  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS PROBLEM SETS1. The correlation coefficient between stock returns for two nonoverlapping periods should be zero. If not, returns from one period could be used to predict returns in later periods and make abnormal profits.2. No. Microsoft’s continuing profitability does not implythat stock market investors who purchased Microsoft shares afterits success was already evident would have earned an exceptionally high return on their investments. It simply means that Microsoft has made risky investments over the years that have paid off in the form of increased cash flows and profitability. Microsoft shareholders have benefited from the risk-expected return tradeoff, which is consistent with the EMH.3. Expected rates of return differ because of differential risk premiums across all securities.4. No. The value of dividend predictability would bealready reflected in the stock price.5. No, markets can be efficient even if some investors earn returns above the market average. Consider the Lucky Event issue: Ignoring transaction costs, about 50% of professional investors, by definition, will “beat” the market in any given year. The probability of beating it three years in a row, though small, isnot insignificant. Beating the market in the past does not predict future success as three years of returns make up too small a sample on which to base correlation let alone causation.6. Volatile stock prices could reflect volatile underlying economic conditions as large amounts of information being incorporated into the price will cause variability in stock price.The efficient market hypothesis suggests that investors cannot earn excess risk-adjusted rewards. The variability of the stock price is thus reflected in the expected returns as returns and risk are positively correlated.7. The following effects seem to suggest predictability within equity markets and thus disprove the efficient market hypothesis. However, consider the following:a. Multiple studie s suggest that “value” stocks(measured often by low P/E multiples) earn higher returns over time than “growth” stocks (high P/E multiples). This could suggest a strategy for earning higher returns over time. However, anotherrational argument may be that traditional forms of CAPM (such asSharpe’s model) do not fully account for all risk factors thataffect a firm’s price level. A firm viewed as riskier may have a lower price and thus P/E multiple.b. The book-to-market effect suggests that an investor canearn excess returns by investing in companies with high book value (the value of a firm’s assets minus its liabilities divided by the number of shares outstanding) to market value. A study by Fama and French1 suggests that book-to-market value reflects a risk factorthat is not accounted for by traditional one variable CAPM. Forexample, companies experiencing financial distress see the ratio of book to market value increase. Thus a more complex CAPM thatincludes book-to-market value as an explanatory variable should be used to test market anomalies.c. Stock price momentum can be positively correlated withpast performance (short to intermediate horizon) or negativelycorrelated (long horizon). Historical data seem to implystatistical significance to these patterns. Explanations for this include a bandwagon effect or the behaviorists’ (see Chapter 12) explanation that there is a tendency for investors to underreact to new information, thus producing a positive serial correlation.However, statistical significance does not imply economicsignificance. Several studies that included transaction costs inthe momentum models discovered that momentum traders tended to not outperform the efficient market hypothesis strategy of buy and hold.d. The small-firm effect states that smaller firms producebetter returns than larger firms. Since 1926, returns from smallfirms outpace large firm stock returns by about 1% per year. Dosmall cap investors earn excess risk-adjusted returns?1Fama, Eugene and Kenneth French, “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds,” Journal of Finance 33:1, pp. 3-56.The measure of systemati c risk according to Sharpe’s CAPM is the stock’s beta (or sensitivity of returns of the stock to market returns). If the stock’s beta is the best explanation of risk, then the small-firm effect does indicate an inefficient market. Dividing the market into deciles based on their betas shows an increasing relationship between betas and returns. Fama and French2 show that the empirical relationship between beta and stock returns is flat over a fairly long horizon (1963–1990). Breaking the market into deciles based on sizes and then examining the relationship between beta and stock returns within each size decile exhibits this flat relationship. This implies that firm size may be a better measure of risk than beta and the size-effect should not be viewed as an indicator that markets are inefficient. Heuristically this makes sense, as smaller firms are generally viewed as risky compared to larger firms and perceived risk and return are positively correlated.In addition this effect seems to be endpoint and data sensitive. For example, smaller stocks did not outperform larger stocks from the mid-1980s through the 1990s. In addition, databases contain stock returns from companies that have survived and do not include returns of those that went bankrupt. Thus small-firm data may exhibit survivorship bias.8. Over the long haul, there is an expected upward drift in stock prices based on their fair expected rates of return. The fair expected return over any single day is very small (e.g., 12% per year is only about 0.03% per day), so that on any day the price is virtually equally likely to rise or fall. Over longer periods, the small expected daily returns accumulate, and upward moves are more likely than downward ones. Remember that economies tend to grow over time and stock prices tend to follow economic growth, so it is only natural that there is an upward drift in equity prices.9. c. This is a predictable pattern in returns thatshould not occur if the weak-form EMH is valid.2 Ibid10. a. Acute market inefficiencies are temporary in nature and are more easily exploited than chronic inefficiencies. A temporary drop in a stock price due to a large sale would be more easily exploited than the chronic inefficiencies mentioned in the other responses.11. c. This is a classic filter rule that should not produce superior returns in an efficient market.12. b. This is the definition of an efficient market.13. a. Though stock prices follow a random walk and intraday price changes do appear to be a random walk, over the long run there is compensation for bearing market risk and for the time value of money. Investing differs from a casino inthat in the long-run, an investor is compensated for these risks, while a player at a casino faces less than fair-game odds.b. In an efficient market, any predictable future prospects of a company have already been priced into the current value of the stock. Thus, a stock share price can still follow a random walk.c. While the random nature of dart board selection seems to follow naturally from efficient markets, the role of rational portfolio management still exists. It exists to ensure a well-diversified portfolio, to assess the risk-tolerance of the investor, and to take into account tax code issues.14. d. In a semistrong-form efficient market, it is not possible to earn abnormally high profits by trading on publicly available information. Information about P/E ratios and recent price changes is publicly known. On the other hand, an investor who has advance knowledge of management improvements could earn abnormally high trading profits (unless the market is also strong-form efficient).15. Market efficiency implies investors cannot earn excess risk-adjusted profits. If the stock price run-up occurs when only insiders know of the coming dividend increase, then it is aviolation of strong-form efficiency. If the public also knows ofthe increase, then this violates semistrong-form efficiency.16. While positive beta stocks respond well to favorable new information about th e economy’s progress through the business cycle, they should not show abnormal returns around already anticipated events. If a recovery, for example, is already anticipated, the actual recovery is not news. The stock price should already reflect the coming recovery.17. a. Consistent. Based on pure luck, half of allmanagers should beat the market in any year.b. Inconsistent. This would be the basis of an “easymoney” rule: simply invest with last year's best managers.c. Consistent. In contrast to predictable returns,predictable volatility does not convey a means to earn abnormal returns.d. Inconsistent. The abnormal performance ought to occurin January when earnings are announced.e. Inconsistent. Reversals offer a means to earn easymoney: just buy last week’s losers.18. The return on the market is 8%. Therefore, the forecast monthly return for Ford is:0.10% + (1.1 × 8%) = 8.9%Ford’s actual return was 7%, s o the abnormal return was –1.9%.19. a. Based on broad market trends, the CAPM indicatesthat AmbChaser stock should have increased by: 1.0% + 2.0 ×(1.5% – 1.0%) = 2.0%Its firm-specific (nonsystematic) return due to the lawsuit is $1 million per $100 million initial equity, or 1%. Therefore, the total return should be 3%. (It is assumed here that theoutcome of the lawsuit had a zero expected value.)b. If the settlement was expected to be $2 million, thenthe actual settlement was a “$1 million disappointment,” and so the firm-specific return would be –1%, for a total returnof 2% – 1% = 1%.20. Given market performance, predicted returns on the twostocks would be:Apex: 0.2% + (1.4 × 3%) = 4.4%Bpex: –0.1% + (0.6 × 3%) = 1.7%Apex underperformed this prediction; Bpex outperformed the prediction. We conclude that Bpex won the lawsuit.21. a. E(r M) = 12%, r f = 4% and β = 0.5Therefore, the expected rate of return is:4% + 0.5 × (12% – 4%) = 8%If the stock is fairly priced, then E(r) = 8%.b.If r M falls short of your expectation by 2% (that is,10% – 12%) then you would expect the return for ChangingFortunes Industries to fall short of your original expectation by: β× 2% = 1%Therefore, you would forecast a revised expectation for Changing Fortunes of: 8% – 1% = 7%c. Given a market return of 10%, you would forecast areturn for Changing Fortunes of 7%. The actual return is 10%.Therefore, the surprise due to firm-specific factors is 10% –7% = 3%, which we attribute to the settlement. Because the firm is initially worth $100 million, the surprise amount of thesettlement is 3% of $100 million, or $3 million, implying that the prior expectation for the settlement was only $2 million.22. Implicit in the dollar-cost averaging strategy is the notion that stock prices fluctuate around a “normal” level. Otherwise, there is no meaning t o statements such as: “when the price is high.” How do we know, for example, whether a price of $25 today will turn out to be viewed as high or low compared tothe stock price six months from now?23. The market responds positively to new news. If the eventual recovery is anticipated, then the recovery is already reflected in stock prices. Only a better-than-expected recovery should affect stock prices.24. Buy. In your view, the firm is not as bad as everyone else believes it to be. Therefore, you view the firm as undervalued by the market. You are less pessimistic about the firm’s prospects than the beliefs built into the stock price.25. Here we need a two-factor model relating Ford’s return to those of both the broad market and the auto industry. If we call r I the industry return, then we would first estimate parametersα,β,βM INDin the following regression:FORD αββεM M IND INDr r r=+++Given these estimates we would calculate Ford’s firm-specific return as:FORD [αββε] M M IND INDr r r-+++This estimate of firm-specific news would measure the market’s assessment of the potential profitability of Ford’s new model.26. The market may have anticipated even greater earnings. Compared to prior expectations, the announcement was a disappointment.27. Thinly traded stocks will not have a considerable amount of market research performed on the companies they represent. This neglected-firm effect implies a greater degree of uncertainty with respect to smaller companies. Thus positive CAPM alphas amongthinly traded stocks do not necessarily violate the efficientmarket hypothesis since these higher alphas are actually riskpremiums, not market inefficiencies.28. The negative abnormal returns (downward drift in CAR) justprior to stock purchases suggest that insiders deferred theirpurchases until after bad news was released to the public. This is evidence of valuable inside information. The positive abnormalreturns after purchase suggest insider purchases in anticipation of good news. The analysis is symmetric for insider sales.29. a. The market risk premium moves countercyclical to theeconomy, peaking in recessions. A violation of the efficient market hypothesis would imply that investors could take advantage of this predictability and earn excess risk adjusted returns. However,several studies, including Siegel,3 show that successfully timingthe changes have eluded professional investors thus far. Moreover a changing risk premium implies changing required rates of return for stocks rather than an inefficiency with the market.b. As the market risk premium increases during a recession,stocks prices tend to fall. As the economy recovers, the marketrisk premium falls, and stock prices tend to rise. These changescould give investors the impression that markets overreact,especially if the underlying changes in the market risk premium are small but cumulative. For example, the October Crash of 1987 iscommonly viewed as an example of market overreaction. However, inthe weeks running up to mid-October, several underlying changes to the market risk premium occurred (in addition to changes in theyields on long-term Treasury Bonds). Congress threatened investors with a “merger tax” that would have truncated the booming merger industry and loosened the discipline that the threat of mergersprovides to a firm’s management. In addition, the Secretary ofTreasury threatened further depreciation in the value of the dollar, frightening foreign investors. These events may have increased the3 Jeremy Siegel, Stocks for the Long Run: The Definitive Guide to Financial Market Returns and Long-Term Investment Strategies, 2002, New York: McGraw-Hill.market risk premium and lowered stock prices in a seeming overreaction.CFA PROBLEMS1. b. Semistrong form efficiency implies that marketprices reflect all publicly available information concerningpast trading history as well as fundamental aspects of the firm.2. a. The full price adjustment should occur just asthe news about the dividend becomes publicly available.3. d. If low P/E stocks tend to have positive abnormalreturns, this would represent an unexploited profit opportunity that would provide evidence that investors are not using allavailable information to make profitable investments.4. c. In an efficient market, no securities areconsistently overpriced or underpriced. While some securitieswill turn out after any investment period to have providedpositive alphas (i.e., risk-adjusted abnormal returns) and some negative alphas, these past returns are not predictive offuture returns.5. c. A random walk implies that stock price changesare unpredictable, using past price changes or any other data.6. d. A gradual adjustment to fundamental values wouldallow for the use of strategies based on past price movements in order to generate abnormal profits.7. a.8. a. Some empirical evidence that supports the EMH:(i)Professional money managers do not typically earnhigher returns than comparable risk, passive index strategies.(ii)Event studies typically show that stocks respond immediately to the public release of relevant news.(iii)Most tests of technical analysis find that it is difficult to identify price trends that can be exploited toearn superior risk-adjusted investment returns.b.Some evidence that is difficult to reconcile with the EMH concerns simple portfolio strategies that apparently would have provided high risk-adjusted returns in the past. Some examples of portfolios with attractive historical returns:(i)Low P/E stocks.(ii)High book-to-market ratio stocks.(iii)Small firms in January.(iv)Firms with very poor stock price performance in the last few months.Other evidence concerns post-earnings-announcement stock price drift and intermediate-term price momentum.c. An investor might choose not to index even if marketsare efficient because he or she may want to tailor a portfolioto specific tax considerations or to specific risk management issues, for example, the need to hedge (or at least not add to) exposure to a particular source of risk (e.g., industry exposure).9. a. The efficient market hypothesis (EMH) statesthat a market is efficient if security prices immediately andfully reflect all available relevant information. If the market fully reflects information, the knowledge of that information would not allow an investor to profit from the information because stock prices already incorporate the information.i. The weak form of the EMH asserts that stock prices reflect all the information that can be derived by examining markettrading data such as the history of past prices and trading volume.A strong body of evidence supports weak-form efficiency inthe major U.S. securities markets. For example, test results suggest that technical trading rules do not produce superior returns after adjusting for transaction costs and taxes.ii.The semistrong form states that a firm’s stock price reflects all publicly available information about a firm’s prospects. Examples of publicly available information are company annual reports and investment advisory data.Evidence strongly supports the notion of semistrong efficiency, but occasional studies (e.g., identifying market anomalies such as the small-firm-in-January or book-to-market effects) and events (e.g. stock market crash of October 19, 1987) are inconsistent with this form of market efficiency. There is a question concerning the extent to which these “anomalies”result from data mining.iii. The strong form of the EMH holds that current market prices reflect all information (whether publicly available or privately held) that can be relevant to the valuation of thefirm.Empirical evidence suggests that strong-form efficiencydoes not hold. If this form were correct, prices would fully reflect all information. Therefore even insiders could not earn excess returns. But the evidence is that corporate officers do have access to pertinent information long enough before public release to enable them to profit from trading on this information.b. i. Technical analysis involves the search for recurrent and predictable patterns in stock prices in order to enhance returns. The EMH implies that technical analysis is without value. If past prices contain no useful information for predicting future prices, there is no point in following any technical trading rule.ii. Fundamental analysis uses earnings and dividend prospects of the firm, expectations of future interest rates, and risk evaluation of the firm to determine proper stock prices. The EMH predicts that most fundamental analysis is doomed to failure. According to semistrong-form efficiency, no investor can earn excess returns from trading rules based on publicly available information. Only analysts with unique insight achieve superior returns.In summary, the EMH holds that the market appears to adjust so quickly to information about both individual stocks and the economy as a whole that no technique of selecting a portfoliousing either technical or fundamental analysis can consistently outperform a strategy of simply buying and holding a diversified portfolio of securities, such as those comprising the popular market indexes.c. Portfolio managers have several roles andresponsibilities even in perfectly efficient markets. The most important responsibility is to identify the risk/return objectives for a portfolio given the investor’s constraints. In an efficient market, portfolio managers are responsible for tailoring the portfolio to meet the investor’s n eeds, rather than to beat the market, which requires identifying the client’s return requirements and risk tolerance. Rational portfolio management also requires examining the investor’s constraints, including liquidity, time horizon, laws and regulations, taxes, and unique preferences and circumstances such as age and employment.10. a. The earnings (and dividend) growth rate of growth stocks may be consistently overestimated by investors. Investors may extrapolate recent growth too far into the future and thereby downplay the inevitable slowdown. At any given time, growth stocks are likely to revert to (lower) mean returns and value stocks are likely to revert to (higher) mean returns, often over an extended future time horizon.b.In efficient markets, the current prices of stocks already reflect all known relevant information. In this situation, growth stocks and value stocks provide the same risk-adjusted expected return.。

相关文档
最新文档