The impact of banking regulations on banks' cost and profit efficiency-Cross-country evidence
《货币金融学(第十三版)》英文版教学课件mishkin_econ13e_ppt_10

The Spread of Government Deposit Insurance Throughout the World: Is This a Good Thing?
• Has government deposit insurance helped improve the performance of the financial system and prevent banking crises? The answer seems to be “no.” Research at the World Bank seems to answer “no,” since on average, the adoption of explicit government deposit insurance is associated with less banking sector stability and a higher incidence of banking crises. Furthermore, on average, deposit insurance seems to retard financial development.
Copyright © 2022, 2019, 2016 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Types of Financial Regulation: Restrictions on Asset Holdings
• Attempts to restrict financial institutions from too much risk taking: – Bank regulations ▪ Promote diversification ▪ Prohibit holdings of common stock – Capital requirements ▪ Minimum leverage ratio (for banks) ▪ Basel Accord: risk-based capital requirements ▪ Regulatory arbitrage
《金融专业英语》chapter 6

6.2.2 Factorsorities
IN EVALUATING A CHARTER APPLICATION, THE CHARTERING AUTHORITIES GENERALLY CONSIDERS 4 FACTORS:
➢ Thirdly, a related goal is to protect depositors’ funds and, if any bank should fail, to minimize the losses to be absorbed by the deposit insurance fund.
experience commensurate with their positions; and ➢ Having the required business premise, safety measures and other
facilities relevant with the business thereof.
金 融 专 业 英语
Part Two
Banking Industry in China
Contents
4
5
6
Central Bank—PBC
Commercial Banks
Supervision of Banking
6 Supervision
Chapter of Banking
Chapter 6 Supervision of Banking
Section 6.2 Licensing Process
6.2.1 Phases of the Process 6.2.2 Factors Evaluated by the Chartering Authorities 6.2.3 Basel Committee’s Requirements on Bank Licensing
《货币金融学(第十三版)》英文版教学课件mishkin_econ13e_ppt_09

$90M
$80M $10M
Bank Capital
Blank
$10M
Blank
– Suppose a bank’s required reserves are 10%.
– If a bank has ample excess reserves, a deposit outflow does not necessitate changes in other parts of its balance sities
Required reserves
Loans
+$10 +$90
Checkable deposits
Blank
+$100
Blank
• Asset transformation: selling liabilities with one set of characteristics and using the proceeds to buy assets with a different set of characteristics
• The bank borrows short and lends long
Copyright © 2022, 2019, 2016 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
General Principles of Bank Management
• Liquidity Management • Asset Management • Liability Management • Capital Adequacy Management • Credit Risk • Interest-rate Risk
审慎监管对我国商业银行经营效率的影响——基于全要素生产率的视角

Research on the Impact of Prudential Supervision on the Operational Efficiency of China’s Commercial Banks:Based on the Perspective of Total
Factor Productivity
作者: 赫国胜[1];马妍妮[1]
作者机构: [1]辽宁大学经济学院
出版物刊名: 财经科学
页码: 16-29页
年卷期: 2020年 第5期
主题词: 商业银行;审慎监管;经营效率;全要素生产率
摘要:审慎监管是商业银行持续稳健发展的必然选择。
基于此背景,利用2011-2017年22家A股上市商业银行面板数据,测算全要素生产率以度量商业银行经营效率,运用系统GMM估计方法实证考察了主要审慎监管工具对我国商业银行经营效率的影响。
研究发现:上市商业银行整体经营效率下降,但从时间序列上看,随着审慎监管政策的实施,上市商业银行全要素生产率经历先下降后上升的过程;不同类型商业银行经营效率及影响因素均存在一定差异。
审慎监管工具中的资本充足率、杠杆率对商业银行经营效率具有显著促进作用,流动性占比及贷款拨备率对商业银行经营效率产生显著负面效应,但整体来看,就四大审慎监管工具而言,其对商业银行经营效率的正面效应明显大于负面效应。
根据上述实证研究结果,提出相应的政策建议。
Big bad banks The winners and losers from bank deregulation in the United States

THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE•VOL.LXV,NO.5•OCTOBER2010Big Bad Banks?The Winners and Losers from Bank Deregulation in the United States THORSTEN BECK,ROSS LEVINE,and ALEXEY LEVKOV∗ABSTRACTWe assess the impact of bank deregulation on the distribution of income in the UnitedStates.From the1970s through the1990s,most states removed restrictions onintrastate branching,which intensified bank competition and improved bank per-formance.Exploiting the cross-state,cross-time variation in the timing of branchderegulation,wefind that deregulation materially tightened the distribution of in-come by boosting incomes in the lower part of the income distribution while havinglittle impact on incomes above the median.Bank deregulation tightened the distribu-tion of income by increasing the relative wage rates and working hours of unskilledworkers.I NCOME DISTRIBUTIONAL CONSIDERATIONS have played a central—if not the central—role in shaping the policies that governfinancial markets.For in-stance,Thomas Jefferson’s fears that concentrated banking power would help wealthy industrialists at the expense of others spurred him tofight against the Bank of the United States,and similar anxieties fueled Andrew Jackson’s veto of the re-chartering of the Second Bank of the United States(Hammond(1957), Bodenhorn(2003)).During the20th century,politicians in many U.S.states implemented and maintained restrictions on bank branching,arguing that the formation of large banks would disproportionately curtail the economic oppor-tunities of the poor(Southworth(1928),White(1982),Kroszner and Strahan (1999)).And today,in the midst of afinancial crisis,unease about central-ized economic power and growing income inequality have fueled debates about Gramm-Leach-Bliley and the desirability of stiffer regulations onfinancial con-glomerates.1However,while beliefs about the influence offinancial regulations ∗Beck is from CentER,Department of Economics and EBC,Tilburg University;Levine is with the Brown University and NBER;Levkov is with The Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.Martin Goetz and Carlos Espina provided exceptional research assistance.We thank an anonymous ref-eree,the Editors,Phil Strahan,and Yona Rubinstein for detailed comments on earlier drafts.We received many helpful comments at the Bank of Israel,Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,Brown University,Boston University,International Monetary Fund,European Central Bank,Georgia State University,New York University,Tilburg University,Vanderbilt University, University of Frankfurt,University of Lausanne,University of Mannheim,University of Virginia, and the World Bank.We are grateful to the Charles G.Koch Charitable Foundation for providing financial support.The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston or the Federal Reserve System.1On compensation in thefinancial sector and income inequality in the overall economy,see Philippon and Reshef(2009)and Kaplan and Rauh(2010).Many have recently suggested that16371638The Journal of Finance Ron the distribution of income affect policies,researchers have devoted few re-sources toward evaluating the actual impact offinancial regulations on the distribution of income.In this paper we econometrically evaluate the causal impact of bank regulations on income distribution.Theoretical debates and welfare concerns further motivate our analyses of the distributional effects of bank regulation.If banking is a natural monopoly, then unregulated,monopolistic banks may earn rents through highfixed fees that disproportionately hurt the poor as developed in models by Greenwood and Jovanovic(1990),Banerjee and Newman(1993),and Galor and Zeira(1993). Countervailing arguments,however,challenge the view that restricting the consolidation and expansion of banks will help the poor.Regulatory restrictions on bank mergers,acquisitions,and branching could create and protect local banking monopolies,curtailing competition and raising fees that primarily hurt the poor.In light of this debate,we evaluate whether regulatory restrictions on bank expansion increased,decreased,or had no effect on income inequality. Furthermore,bank regulations could directly affect social welfare by altering the distribution of income.As summarized by Kahneman and Krueger(2006) and Clark,Frijters,and Shields(2008),people care about relative income,as well as absolute income and risk.Thus,understanding the impact offinancial regulations on the distribution of income provides additional information on the welfare implications offinance.More specifically,this paper assesses how branch deregulation altered the distribution of income in the United States.From the1970s through the1990s, most states removed restrictions on intrastate branching,which intensified bank competition and improved bank efficiency and performance(Flannery (1984),Jayaratne and Strahan(1998)).Researchers have examined the im-pact of these reforms on economic growth(Jayaratne and Strahan(1996), Huang(2008)),entrepreneurship(Black and Strahan(2002),Kerr and Nanda (2009)),economic volatility(Morgan,Rime,and Strahan(2004),Demyanyk, Ostergaard,and Sørensen(2007)),and the wage gap between male and female bank executives(Black and Strahan(2001)).In this paper,we provide thefirst evaluation of the impact of branch deregulation on the distribution of income in the overall economy and help resolve a debate about bank deregulation that extends across two centuries.The removal of branching restrictions by states provides a natural setting for identifying and assessing who won and lost from bank deregulation.As shown by Kroszner and Strahan(1999),national technological innovations triggered branch deregulation at the state level.Specifically,(i)the invention of auto-matic teller machines(ATMs),in conjunction with court rulings that ATMs are not bank branches,weakened the geographical bond between customers and banks;(ii)checkable money market mutual funds facilitated banking by mail and telephone,which weakened local bank monopolies;and(iii)improve-ments in communications technology lowered the costs of using distant banks.financial deregulation,including bank branch deregulation,the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act,and the accommodating supervisory approach at the Federal Reserve,contributed both to thefinancial crisis and to growing income inequality;see,for example,Moss(2009).Big Bad Banks?1639 These innovations reduced the monopoly power of local banks,weakening their ability and desire tofight against deregulation.Kroszner and Strahan(1999) further show that cross-state variation in the timing of deregulation reflects the interactions of these national technological innovations with pre-existing state-specific conditions.For example,deregulation occurred later in states where politically powerful groups viewed large,multiple-branch banks as po-tentially serious competitors.Moreover,as we demonstrate below,neither the level nor rate of change in the distribution of income before deregulation help predict when a state removed restrictions on bank branching,suggesting that the timing of branch deregulation at the state level is exogenous to the state’s distribution of income.Consequently,we employ a difference-in-differences es-timation methodology that exploits the exogenous cross-state,cross-year vari-ation in the timing of branch deregulation to assess the causal impact of bank deregulation on the distribution of income.The paper’s majorfinding is that deregulation of branching restrictions sub-stantively tightened the distribution of income by disproportionately raising incomes in the lower half of the income distribution.While income inequality widened in the overall U.S.economy during the sample period,branch deregu-lation lowered inequality relative to this national trend.Thisfinding is robust to using different measures of income inequality,controlling for time-varying state characteristics,and controlling for both state and yearfixed effects.We find no evidence that reverse causality or prior trends in the distribution of income account for thesefindings.Furthermore,the economic magnitude is consequential.Eight years after deregulation,the Gini coefficient of income in-equality is about4%lower than before deregulation after controlling for state and yearfixed effects.Put differently,deregulation explains about60%of the variation of inequality after controlling for state and yearfixed effects. Removing restrictions on intrastate bank branching reduced inequality by boosting incomes in the lower part of the income distribution,not by shrinking incomes above the median.Deregulation increased the average incomes of the bottom quarter of the income distribution by more than5%,but deregulation did not significantly affect the upper half of the distribution of income.These results are consistent with the view that the removal of intrastate branching restrictions triggered changes in banking behavior that had disproportionately positive repercussions on lower income individuals.To provide additional evidence that bank deregulation tightened the distri-bution of income via changes in bank performance and not through some other mechanism,we show that the impact of deregulation on the distribution of in-come varied across states in a theoretically predictable manner.In particular, if branch deregulation tightened the distribution of income by improving the operation of banks,then deregulation should have had a more pronounced ef-fect on the distribution of income in those states where branching restrictions were particularly harmful to bank operations before deregulation.Based on Kroszner and Strahan(1999),we use four indicators of the degree to which intrastate branching restrictions hurt bank performance prior to deregula-tion.For example,in states with a more geographically diffuse population,1640The Journal of Finance Rbranching restrictions were particularly effective at creating local banking mo-nopolies that hindered bank performance.After deregulating,therefore,we should observe a bigger effect on bank performance in states with more diffuse populations.This is what wefind.Across the four indicators of the cross-state severity of branching restrictions and their impact,wefind that deregulation reduced income inequality more in those states where these branching restric-tions had been particularly harmful to bank operations.Thesefindings increase confidence in the interpretation that deregulation reduced income inequality by enhancing bank performance.Wefinish by conducting a preliminary exploration of three possible explana-tions for the channels underlying thesefindings.We view this component of the analysis as a preliminary exploration because each of these explanations war-rants independent investigation with individual-level longitudinal data sets. Nevertheless,we provide this extension to further motivate and guide future research on the channels linking bank performance and the distribution of income.Thefirst two explanations stress the ability of the poor to access banking services directly.In Galor and Zeira(1993),for example,credit market imper-fections prevent the poor from borrowing to invest more in education,which hinders their access to higher paying jobs.Deregulation that eases these credit constraints,therefore,allows lower income individuals to invest more in edu-cation,reducing inequality.A second explanation focuses on the ability of the poor to become entrepreneurs.In Banerjee and Newman(1993),financial im-perfections are particularly binding on the poor because they lack collateral and because their incomes are relatively low compared to thefixed costs of obtaining bank loans.Thus,deregulation that improves bank performance by lowering collateral requirements and borrowing costs will disproportionately benefit the poor by expanding their access to bank credit.A third explanation highlights the response offirms to the lower interest rates triggered by deregulation,rather than stressing increased access to credit by lower income individuals.While the drop in the cost of capital encourages firms to substitute capital for labor,the cost reduction also increases production, boosting the demand for capital and labor.On net,if the drop in the cost of capital increases the demand for labor and this increase falls disproportionately on lower income workers,then deregulation could reduce inequality by affecting firms’demand for labor.Although branch deregulation stimulated entrepreneurship and increased education,our results suggest that deregulation reduced income inequality primarily by boosting the relative demand for low-skilled workers.More specifi-cally,deregulation dramatically increased the rate of new incorporations(Black and Strahan(2002))and the rates of entry and exit of nonincorporatedfirms (Kerr and Nanda(2009)).However,the reduction in total income inequality is fully accounted for by a reduction in earnings inequality among salaried employees,not by a movement of lower income workers into higher paying self-employed activities or by a change in income differentials among the self-employed.Furthermore,the self-employed account for only about9%of the working age population,and this percentage did not change significantly afterBig Bad Banks?1641 deregulation.On education,Levine and Rubinstein(2009)find that the fall in interest rates caused by bank deregulation reduced high school dropout rates in lower income households.Yet,changes in educational attainment do not ac-count for the reduction in income inequality triggered by branch deregulation during our sample period.Rather,consistent with the view that bank dereg-ulation increased the relative demand for low-income workers,wefind that deregulation increased the relative wages and relative working hours of un-skilled workers,thus accounting for a tightening of income distribution.Beyond the increase in the relative wages and working hours of low-income workers, bank deregulation also lowered the unemployment rate,further emphasizing the labor demand channel.This paper relates to policy debates concerning the currentfinancial crisis and the role offinancial markets in promoting economic development.First, the international policy community increasingly emphasizes the benefits of providing the poor with greater access tofinancial services as a vehicle for fighting poverty and reducing inequality.In a broad cross-section of countries, Beck,Demirguc-Kunt,and Levine(2007)find that an overall index of banking sector development is associated with a reduction in income inequality across countries,but they do not analyze the impact of a specific,exogenous policy change.Burgess and Pande(2005)find that when India reformed its banking laws to provide the poor with greater access tofinancial services,this policy change reduced poverty by boosting wages in rural areas.Ourfindings also suggest thatfinancial development might help the poor primarily by intensi-fying competition and boosting wage earnings,not by increasing the income of the poor from self-employment.Second,given the severity of the globalfinancial crisis,many governments are re-evaluating their approaches to bank regulation.Many economists and policymakers stress the potential dangers offinancial deregulation.Though our work does not examine the current crisis,the results do indicate that regulations that impeded competition among banks during the20th century were disproportionately harmful to lower income individuals,which should not be ignored as countries rethink and redesign their regulatory systems.The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows.Section I describes the data and econometric methodology.Section II provides the core results,while Section III provides further evidence on how deregulation influences labor mar-ket conditions.Section IV concludes.I.Data and MethodologyTo assess the effect of branch deregulation on income distribution,we gather data on the timing of deregulation,income distribution,and other banking sec-tor and state-level characteristics.This section presents the data and describes the econometric methods.A.Branch DeregulationHistorically,most U.S.states had restrictions on branching within and across state borders.With regards to intrastate branching restrictions,most states1642The Journal of Finance Rallowed bank holding companies to own separately capitalized and licensed banks throughout a state.Other states were“unit banking states,”in which each bank was typically permitted to operate only one office.Beginning in the early1970s,states started relaxing these restrictions,al-lowing bank holding companies to consolidate subsidiaries into branches and permitting de novo branching throughout the state.This deregulation led to significant entry into local banking markets(Amel and Liang(1992)),consolida-tion of smaller banks into large bank holding companies(Savage(1993),Calem (1994)),and conversion of existing bank subsidiaries into branches(McLaughin (1995)).This relaxation,however,came gradually,with the last states lifting restrictions following the1994passage of the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act.Consistent with Jayaratne and Strahan(1996)and others,we choose the date of deregulation as the date on which a state permitted branching via merg-ers and acquisitions(M&As)through the holding company structure,which was thefirst step in the deregulation process,followed by de novo branch-ing.In the Internet Appendix(an Internet Appendix for this article is avail-able online in the“Supplements and Datasets”section at / supplements.asp)we present the deregulation dates.Twelve states deregulated before the start of our sample period in1976.Arkansas,Iowa,and Minnesota were the last states to deregulate,only after the passage of the Riegle-Neal Act in1994.We have data for50states and the District of Columbia.Consis-tent with the literature on branch deregulation,we drop Delaware and South Dakota because the structure of their banking systems was heavily affected by laws that made them centers for the credit card industry.Over this period,states also deregulated restrictions on interstate banking by allowing bank holding companies to expand across state borders.We con-firm this paper’s results using the date of interstate deregulation instead of the date of intrastate deregulation.However,when we simultaneously control for inter-and intrastate bank deregulation,wefind that only intrastate deregu-lation enters significantly.Thus,we focus on intrastate rather than interstate deregulation throughout the remainder of this paper.B.Income Distribution DataInformation on the distribution of income comes from the March Supplement of the Current Population Survey(CPS),which is an annual survey of about 60,000households across the United States.The CPS is a repeated,representa-tive sampling of the population,but it does not trace individuals over time.The CPS provides information on total personal income,wage and salary income (earnings),proprietor income,income from other sources,and a wide array of demographic characteristics in the year prior to the survey.Most importantly for our study,we start with the1977survey because the exact state of residence is unavailable prior to this survey.Each individual in the CPS is assigned a probability sampling weight corresponding to his or her representativeness in the population.We use sampling weights in all our analyses.Big Bad Banks?1643 We measure the distribution of income for each state and year over the pe-riod1976to2006in four ways.First,the Gini coefficient of income distribution is derived from the Lorenz rger values of the Gini coefficient imply greater income inequality.The Gini coefficient equals zero if everyone receives the same income,and equals one if a single individual receives all of the econ-omy’s income.We present results with both the natural logarithm of the Gini coefficient as well as the logistic transformation of the Gini coefficient(logis-tic Gini)in the regression analyses.While using the logistic Gini does bound the minimum value at zero,using the log of Gini allows one to interpret the regression coefficient as a percentage change.Our second measure of income distribution is the Theil index,which is also increasing in the degree of income inequality.If all individuals receive the same income,the Theil index equals zero,while the Theil index equals Ln(N)if one individual receives all of the economy’s income,where N equals the number of individuals.An advantage of the Theil index is that it is computationally easy to decompose the index into that part of inequality accounted for by differences in income between groups in the sample and that part of inequality accounted for by differences within each group.Third,we examine the difference between the natural logarithm of incomes of those at the90th percentile and those at the10th percentile (Log(90/10)).Finally,we use the difference between the natural logarithm of incomes of those at the75th percentile and those at the25th percentile((Log (75/25)).The Internet Appendix provides more detailed information on the construction of these income distribution indicators.Consistent with studies of the bor market,our main sample includes prime-age(age25to54)civilians that have nonnegative personal income,and excludes(i)individuals with missing observations on key variables(education, demographics,etc.),(ii)individuals with total personal income below the1st or above the99th percentile of the distribution of income,(iii)people living in group quarters,(iv)individuals who receive zero income and live in house-holds with zero or negative income from all sources of income,and(v)a few individuals for whom the CPS assigns a zero(or missing)sampling weight.As discussed below,the results are robust to relaxing these standard definitions of the relevant labor market.The Internet Appendix provides details on the construction of the sample.There are1,859,411individuals in our sample.The average age in the sample is38years,49%are female,and75%are white,non-Hispanic individuals.In the sample,49%have a high school degree or less,while27%graduated from college.Only9%of the individuals report being self-employed(entrepreneurs). In the Internet Appendix,we present basic descriptive statistics on thefive measures of income inequality,which are measured at the state-year level.In particular,we have data for the31years between1976and2006and for48 states plus the District of Columbia.Thus,there are1,519state-year observa-tions.Besides providing information on the means of the inequality indicators and their minimum and maximum values,we also present three types of stan-dard deviations of the natural logarithms of the inequality indexes:cross-state, within-state,and within state-year.The cross-state standard deviation of Y is1644The Journal of Finance Rthe standard deviation of(Y st−˜Y s),where˜Y s is the average value of Y in state s over the sample period.The within-state standard deviation of Y is the standard deviation of(Y st−˜Y t),where˜Y t is the average value of Y in year t. The within state-year standard deviation of Y is the standard deviation of (Y st−˜Y s−˜Y t),where˜Y s is the average value of Y in state s and˜Y t is the average value of Y in year t.These standard deviations help in assessing the economic magnitude of the impact of bank branch deregulation on the distri-bution of income.C.Control V ariablesTo control for time-varying changes in a state’s economy,we use U.S.Depart-ment of Commerce data to calculate the growth rate of per capita Gross State Product(GSP).We also control for the unemployment rate,obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics,and a number of state-specific,time-varying socio-demographic characteristics,including the percentage of high school dropouts, the proportion of blacks,and the proportion of female-headed households.We also test whether the impact of deregulation on income inequality varies in a predictable way with different state characteristics at the time of dereg-ulation.As we discuss below,we control for the interaction of branch dereg-ulation with a unit banking indicator,the small bank share,the smallfirm share,and population dispersion.The unit banking indicator equals one if the state had unit banking restrictions prior to deregulation and zero otherwise. The following states had unit banking before deregulation:Arizona,Colorado, Florida,Illinois,Iowa,Kansas,Minnesota,Missouri,Montana,Nebraska, North Dakota,Oklahoma,Texas,West Virginia,Wisconsin,and Wyoming.The small bank share equals the fraction of banking assets in the state that are held by banks with assets below the median size bank of each state,while the smallfirm share equals the proportion of all establishments operating in a state with fewer than20employees.Data on the smallfirm share and small bank share are from Kroszner and Strahan(1999).Population dispersion equals one divided by population per square mile,which is obtained from the U.S.Census Bureau.D.MethodologyWe use a difference-in-differences specification to assess the relation between branch deregulation and income distribution,based on the following regression set-up:Y st=α+βD st+δX st+A s+B t+εst,s=1,...,49;t=1976, (2006)(1) In equation(1),Y st is a measure of income distribution in state s in year t, A s and B t are vectors of state and year dummy variables that account for state and yearfixed effects,X st is a set of time-varying state-level variables,andεstBig Bad Banks?1645 is the error term.The variable of interest is D st,a dummy variable that equals one in the years after state s deregulates and zero otherwise.The coefficient,β, therefore indicates the impact of branch deregulation on income distribution.A positive and significantβsuggests that deregulation exerts a positive effect on the degree of income inequality,while a negative and significantβindicates that deregulation pushed income inequality lower.In total,we have data for 48states plus the District of Columbia,over31years,so the1,519state-year observations serve as the basis for much of our analysis.The difference-in-differences estimation technique allows us to control for omitted variables.We include year-specific dummy variables to control for nation-wide shocks and trends that shape income distribution over time,such as business cycles,national changes in regulations and laws,long-term trends in income distribution,and changes in female labor force participation.We in-clude state-specific dummy variables to control for time-invariant,unobserved state characteristics that shape income distribution across states.We estimate equation(1)allowing for state-level clustering of the errors,that is allowing for correlation in the error terms over time within states.2II.Branch Deregulation and Income DistributionA.Preliminary ResultsOur empirical analysis rests on the assumption that the cross-state tim-ing of bank branch deregulation was unaffected by the distribution of income. Figure1shows that neither the level of the Gini coefficient before deregula-tion nor its rate of change prior to deregulation explains the timing of branch deregulation.In a regression of the year of deregulation on the average Gini coefficient before deregulation or on the rate of change of the Gini coefficient in the years before deregulation,the t-statistic on the inequality indicators is 0.20and–1.16,respectively.Additional evidence that income inequality did not affect the timing of branch deregulation emerges from a hazard model study of deregulation.Following Kroszner and Strahan(1999),Table I reports tests of whether the Gini coef-ficient of income inequality influences the likelihood that a state deregulates in a specific year given that it has not deregulated yet.While the Kroszner and Strahan(1999)sample period starts in1970,we do not have Gini data available before1976.Also,since we use the original Kroszner and Strahan 2In robustness tests,reported in the Internet Appendix,we confirm the results using both boot-strapped standard errors and seemingly unrelated regression(SUR)standard errors.Bootstrapped standard errors are calculated using the following procedure:First,we take a random sample of 1,519state-year observations from our data and calculate the impact of deregulation on income in-equality while accounting for state and yearfixed effects.The sample size is done with replacement such that a certain state in a certain year may appear several times.We take500such samples and estimate the impact of deregulation on income inequality500times.The standard deviation of the resulting estimates is the bootstrapped standard error.Second,following Bekaert,Harvey, and Lundblad(2005),we estimate SUR standard errors,restricting the off-diagonal elements of the weighting matrix to be identical.。
美国小型和大型商业银行的利润效率来源及差异[文献翻译]
![美国小型和大型商业银行的利润效率来源及差异[文献翻译]](https://img.taocdn.com/s3/m/74719ee5b8f67c1cfad6b8ad.png)
本科毕业论文外文翻译外文题目:Profit efficiency sources and differences among small and Large U.S commercial banks出处:Journal of economic and finance (2005):289-299作者:Aigbe Akhigbe and James McNulty原文:IntroductionScale economies in banking have long been of interest to financial economists, and this interest has been heightened in recent years by two developments. The first is increased concern about the survivability of small community banks in an era of bank consolidation. This theme was the subject of a March 2003 conference at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and formed the basis for a special March 2004 issue of the Journal of Financial Services Research.The second development is recent academic research suggesting that small banks may have both an information advantage over large banks, as in Nakamura (1993), Mester, Nakamura, and Renault (2001), and Carter and McNulty (2004), and an incentive to use this information advantage in the lending process. Berger et al. (2002) provide evidence on the second point. They suggest that small banks may have a comparative advantage in developing and using the “soft” information often associated with small business lending. PROFEFF is an econometric financial performance measure that indicates how actual financial performance compares to a theoretical best-practice frontier. Considering differences in, and sources of, profit efficiency (PROFEFF) by bank size groups can help shed light on the issue of which banks use their capital more efficiently (provided profits are normalized by equity, which is the approach we take in this paper).Relevant Literature and Estimation IssuesMost studies done in the 1980s and early 1990s suggest that scale economies areslight or nonexistent beyond asset sizes of $50 to $100 million. Some early examples are Benston, Hanweck, and Humphrey (1982), Gilligan, Smirlock, and Marshall (1984), Clark (1984), Nelson (1985), and Berger, Hanweck, and Humphrey (1987). Using 1984 data, Berger and Humphrey (1991) find that economies of scale at the firm level are exhausted beyond $200 million in asset size. Since this influential study, which found that gains from reducing cost inefficiencies dominate gains from realizing scale economies, the focus of most studies has shifted to inefficiencies and hence away from optimum size. However, using cost efficiency, Berger and Mester (1997) conclude that scale economies are exhausted well before $10 billion in asset size.Since these studies estimate cost economies, they cannot directly address the possibility that revenues may be more than proportionately higher for larger banks. However, another related trend in this literature has been increased recognition that profit efficiency is a more appropriate technique to use in evaluating bank performance than cost efficiency since PROFEFF incorporates both revenues and costs. Recent profit efficiency studies include Altunbas, Evans, and Molyneux (2001), Akhigbe and McNulty (2003), Berger and Mester (1997, 2001), DeYoung and Hasan (1998), and DeYoung and Nolle (1996), among others. Other recent studies of U.S. banking efficiency include Barr, Kilgo, Siems, and Stiroh (2000), Zimmel (2002), Berger and DeYoung (2001), and Wheelock and Walker (1999, 2000).The keynote paper at the above-mentioned conference, by DeYoung, Hunter, and Udell (2004), argues that small banks and large banks have a different focus and a different business model—personalized service and customized financial services (e.g., small business loans) in the case of small banks and efficient distribution of relatively uniform types of financial services (e.g., credit cards and home equity loans) in the case of large banks. The business model of the small bank requires relatively high cost, while larger banks can keep cost low. Under this line of reasoning, both types of banks should have a role to play in the future financial services marketplace. Nonetheless, differences in PROFEFF are important because ultimately small and large banks compete for capital. For example, the decision of a smaller bank to join ornot to join a large banking organization through a merger is ultimately a subjective decision about how its capital can be best employed.Given these considerations, two important questions raised by Berger and Mester (1997) must be considered before we proceed. The first is the appropriate variable—assets or equity—to use in normalizing profits in computing the PROFEFF measure. The second is the use of one frontier or several frontiers in comparing banks of different sizes. Because PROFEFF, when normalized by equity, measures how well a bank utilizes its financial capital, we choose to use this measure. Some earlier studies comparing large and small banks, such as Akhigbe and McNulty (2003), use assets and find small banks have higher PROFEFF. Use of equity can be expected to produce the opposite result since large banks use more leverage than small banks. In other words, the PROFEFF measure that we use is closer to return on equity, which should show greater PROFEFF for large banks. Normalizing by assets is likely to produce the opposite result.Since we want to consider the sources of the differences in PROFEFF, we use three different frontiers for small, medium, and large banks. This is consistent with the assumption that their focus, and their basic business model, is different. This procedure allows the PROFEFF measures to have maximum flexibility—small bank PROFEFF and its frontier are not constrained or affected in any way by the activities and balance-sheet structure of large banks, and vice versa. Thus, when we look at the determinants of PROFEFF for the three groups, if they are different, this will reflect real differences, and if they are the same, it will not be because the same frontier was imposed on all banks. We recognize the alternative argument that, in comparing the performance of different banks, one normally wants to use the same test, not two or three different tests.(We made this argument ourselves in an earlier paper.) Profit Efficiency Trends for Various Bank Size GroupsPROFEFF has declined sharply in recent years for small banks, from 0.778 in 1995 to 0.702 in 2001. We consider the hypothesis that this decline may reflect an increasing number of de novo banks in the small bank category. FDIC data indicate that between 1992 and 1994 only 74 new banks per year were chartered, which nodoubt reflects the depressed state of the banking industry at that time. In contrast, in the six year period from 1995 to 2000, there were an average of 175 new bank charters per year. Many of these banks remain small for a number of years after being chartered. DeYoung and Hasan (1998) show that de novo banks are much less profit efficient than older, similarly sized banks. In Table 1 the percent of banks in the under $100 million dollar category that are de novos (age under 10 years) has increased from 11.4 percent to 13.5 percent. Moreover, DeYoung and Hasan (1998) show that the first three years of operations show particularly low PROFEFF for new banks. The greater dispersion of the data for small banks in recent years also supports this explanation. Thus, the hypothesis that at least part of the decline in small bank PROFEFF between 1995 and 2001 reflects the performance of the de novo banks in the sample appears reasonable.In contrast to the small banks, PROFEFF is relatively stable for medium-size and large banks when trends in both median and mean values are taken into account. For example, mean PROFEFF for medium size banks remains above 0.81 throughout the period and large bank PROFEFF remains above 0.84. Nonetheless, some decline is evident in the estimates, which probably reflects in part the fact that banks in all size groups are using less leverage because of pressures from regulators to increase the amount of equity capital on their balance sheet.Results of the Regression Analysis of the Correlates of Profit EfficiencyAs noted, we consider differences in the significance of the correlates among the size groups as an indication that banks of different sizes have different ways of achieving high profitability. The equity/assets ratio (EQUITY) is negative (as expected) and significant at medium and large banks. This indicates that, within these size groups, the more profit-efficient banks, ceteris paribus, use more leverage (less equity) than the other banks in the same size group. Age is positive and significant for small and medium-size banks but not for large ones. This would be consistent with the notion that the establishment of a strong credit culture is an important element in small and medium-size bank profitability. Overlapping generations of loan officers (each generation training the next in the art of making loans in the local community)and relationship development are important elements in developing such a culture. Successful implementation of these strategies would require that the bank be in existence for a considerable perio d of time. This is the “learning by doing” discussed by Berger and Mester (1997) and mentioned above.The marketplace nonperforming loan ratio (MKTNPL) is significant with the expected negative sign for small and medium-sized banks but is actually positive for large banks. This ratio is not particularly relevant for larger banks since it only considers nonperforming loans in the county where the home office of the bank is located; most large banks have offices and loans in more than one county. Membership in a multibank holding company (MBHC) is negative and significant for small and medium-size banks but not for large ones. Apparently the most successful small and mediumsized banks are independent. It also suggests that large banks that are members of holding companies are less likely to be affected by developments at the holding company level than are the smaller and medium-sized holding company members. The relative nonperforming loan ratio (RELNPL) is significant and negative but only for medium-size banks.Differences in fee revenue (FEEREV) are an important source of differences in profitability at small and medium-size banks (note the very high significance levels) but not at larger ones. The most likely explanation for this is that virtually all large banks depend on fee revenue rather than that fee revenue is unimportant for these banks. [See Table 1.] The year dummy variables are also significant for small and medium-size banks only. This suggests that larger banks have more consistent profitability over time than the other banks.Competitive conditions matter but only for the two smaller size groups. Differences in PROFEFF among small banks are positively related to the HHI. In other words, ceteris paribus, PROFEFF is higher in more concentrated markets, which is exactly what we would expect. The same relationship holds for medium-size banks but not for large ones. Berger and Mester (1997) and Akhigbe and McNulty (2003) also find a positive relationship between PROFEFF and the HHI. In addition, most of the coefficients of the other correlates are consistent with the findings ofAkhigbe and McNulty (2003). The fact that banks of different size attain high (or low) profit efficiency through different means is consistent with the above-mentioned recent analysis of DeYoung, Hunter, and Udell (2004) that suggests that banks of different sizes have different business models.Summary and ConclusionsWe examine the differences in profit efficiency at small (under $100 million in assets), medium size ($100 million to $1 billion) and large (more than $1 billion) banks for the period 1995 to 2001, and we also examine the sources of these differences. Since we calculate PROFEFF normalized by equity, it is not surprising that large banks rank highest. However, the differences are quite large. For the period as a whole, average PROFEFF is 0.752 for the small banks, 0.823 for the medium-size banks, and 0.856 for the large banks. In other words, the difference between small and large is more than 10 basis points, which is economically (and statistically) quite significant. Small banks can attain high PROFEFF by being older, by operating in markets with low default rates, by being independent of a holding company, by generating high fee income, by operating in a concentrated market, and by having more of their assets in loans as opposed to securities. Large banks that have high PROFEFF do so primarily by using more leverage since none of the other variables are significant.DeYoung, Hunter, and Udell (2004) argue that different types of banks have different business models. The business model of the small bank is customized and personalized service but at high cost, while larger banks aim to deliver relatively uniform financial services to large groups of customers at lower cost. Our analysis is consistent with this notion that different types of banks attain high profitability in different ways.译文:美国小型和大型商业银行的利润效率来源及差异简介金融经济学家一直对银行的规模经济很感兴趣,近几年,由于两次发展而对银行规模经济的这个兴趣进一步的加深。
政治关联英文文献索引
政治关联英文文献索引1.T he stock market implication of political connections: evidence from firms' dividend policy 政治关系的证券市场含义:来自公司股利政策的证据(Cao et al.2012)2.C orporate ownership, corporate governance reform and timeliness of earnings: Malaysian evidence公司所有权、公司治理改革与盈余及时性:马来西亚的证据3.P olitical connections, bank deposits, and formal deposit insurance: Evidence from an emerging economy政治关系、银行存款与正式的存款保险:来自新兴经济体的证据(June 18, 2013)4.P olitical connections and investment efficiency: Evidence from Chinese listed private firms 政治关系与投资效率:来自中国民营上市公司的证据(August 27, 2013)5.T he Political Determinants of the Cost of Equity: Evidence from Newly Privatized Firms权益资本成本的政治因素:来自刚刚私有化公司的证据(August 2008)6.C ronyism and Capital Controls: Evidence from Malaysia任人唯亲与资本管制:来自马来西亚的证据7.Capital Structure and Political Patronage: Evidence from China资本结构与政治庇护:来自中国的证据8.P olitical Connection and Government Patronage:Evidence from Chinese Manufacturing Firms政治关联与政府赞助:来自中国制造业企业的证据9.P olitical Connections and Firm V alue: Evidence from the Regression Discontinuity Design of Close Gubernatorial Elections政治关联与公司价值:来自临近州长竞选的不连续回归设计的证据10.How does state ownership affect tax avoidance? Evidence from China国家所有权如何影响避税?来自中国的证据11.Do Strong Corporate Governance Firms Still Require Political Connection? And Vice V ersa公司治理强的企业仍然需要政治关系吗?反之亦然12.Political Connections and Preferential Access to Finance: The Role of Campaign Contributions政治关联与优先获得融资:竞选捐款的作用13.Political Connections and the Cost of Equity Capital政治关联与权益资本成本(Boubakri et al. January 2012)14.The Impact of Political Connections on Firms' Operation Performance and Financing Decisions政治关联对公司经营业绩及融资决策的影响(Boubakri et al. November 29, 2011)15.Political Connections and the Cost of Bank Loans政治关系与银行贷款成本(Houston et al. February 15, 2012)16.Politicians and the IPO Decision: The impact of impending political promotions on IPO activity in China政治家与IPO决策:即将来临的政治晋升对中国IPO活动的影响17.Accounting Conservatism and Bankruptcy Risk会计稳健性与破产风险(Biddle et al. October 7, 2013)18.Accounting Conservatism and its Effects on Financial Reporting Quality:A Review of the Literature会计稳健性及其对影响财务报告质量:文献综述(September 9, 2011)19.Conservatism, Disclosure and the Cost of Equity Capital稳健性、披露与权益资本成本(Artiach et al. January 2012)20.Does Access to Finance Lower Firms’ Cost of Capital? Empirical Evidence from International Manufacturing Data获得融资降低了企业的资本成本吗?来自国际制造业数据的实证证据21.Political connections, founding family ownership and leverage decision of privately owned firms政治关联、创始家族所有权与私有企业杠杆决策22.The Impact of Political Connectedness on Firm V alue and Corporate Policies: Evidence from Citizens United政治关系对公司价值及公司政策的影响:来自美国公民的证据23.The Quality of Accounting Information in Politically Connected Firms政治关联企业的会计信息质量24.The political economy of corporate governance, cost of equity, and earnings quality: evidence from newly privatized firms公司治理的政治经济、权益资本成本与盈余质量:来自刚刚私有化公司的证据25.Do Political Connections Help Firms Gain Access to Bank Credit in Vietnam政治关系帮助越南企业获得银行信贷吗?26.Firm performance effects of nurturing political connections through campaign contributions通过竞选捐款培育政治关系的公司绩效效应27.The Chrysler Effect: The Impact of the Chrysler Bailout on Borrowing Cost克莱斯勒效应:克莱斯勒救助对借贷成本的影响28.Politically connected firms in Poland and their access to bank financing波兰的政治关联企业及他们获得银行融资29.Political Connections and Corporate Bailouts政治关系与企业救助30.The characteristics of politically connected firms政治关联企业的特征31.Rent Seeking Incentives, Political Connections and Organizational Structure: Empirical Evidence from Listed Family Firms in China寻租动机、政治关系与组织结构:来自中国上市家族企业的经验证据32.The V alue of Connections In Turbulent Times: Evidence from the United States在动荡的时代关系价值:来自美国的证据33.Malaysian Capital Controls: Macroeconomics and Institutions马来西亚的资本控制:宏观经济和制度34.Rent Seeking and Corporate Finance: Evidence from Corruption Cases寻租与公司融资:腐败案件的证据35.Political Motivation, Over-investment and Firm Performance政治动机、过度投资与公司绩效36.Political connections and earnings quality: evidence from malaysia政治关系与盈余质量——来自马来西亚的证据37.Political Connections and Minority-Shareholder Protection: Evidence from Securities-Market Regulation in China政治关系与少数股东保护:来自中国证券市场监管的经验证据38.Accounting Conservatism, Corporate Governance and Political Influence: Evidence from Malaysia会计稳健性、公司治理与政治影响:来自马来西亚的证据39.Internationalization and Capital Structure: Evidence from Malaysian Manufacturing Firm国际化和资本结构:来自马来西亚制造企业的证据40.Firm size and corporate financial leverage choice in a developing economy Evidence from Nigeria企业规模和企业财务杠杆的选择:来自尼日利亚发展中经济的证据41.Ownership and the V alue of Political Connections: Evidence from China所有权和政治关系的价值:来自中国的证据42.Ownership Types, CEO and Chairman Political Connections, and Long-run Post-IPO Performance: Evidence from China所有权类型、CEO和董事长的政治联系与IPO后长期绩效:来自中国的证据43.Theoretical Investigation on Determinants of Government-Linked Companies Capital Structure关于政府联系公司资本结构的影响因素的理论研究44.Auditor Choice in Privatized Firms: Empirical Evidence on the Role of State and Foreign Owners私有化企业的审计师选择:来自国家和外国所有者作用的经验证据45.The Political Economy of Residual State Ownership in Privatized Firms: Evidence from Emerging Markets私有化企业中剩余政府所有权的政治经济:从新兴市场的证据46.Political Connections and the Process of Going Public: Evidence from China政治关系和上市的过程:来自中国的证据47.Public policy, political connections,and effective tax rates: Longitudinal evidence from Malaysia公共政策、政治关系与有效税率:来自马来西亚的纵向证据48.Why do countries adopt International Financial Reporting Standards为什么各国采用国际财务报告准则49.Political Relationships, Global Financing and Corporate Transparency政治关系、全球融资与公司透明度50.Politically Connected CEOs and Corporate Outcomes: Evidence from France政治关系的首席执行官和公司的结果:来自法国的证据51.Corporate Lobbying, Political Connections, and the Bailout of Banks公司游说、政治关系与银行救助52.Corruption, Political Connections, and Municipal Finance腐败、政治关系与城市金融53.Political connections, corporate governance and preferential bank loans政治联系、公司治理与优惠的银行贷款54.Politically connected firms: an international event study政治关系的企业:一个国际事件研究55.Politicians at work:The private returns and social costs of political connections政客们在工作:私人收益与政治关系的社会成本56.Political Connection, Financing Frictions, and Corporate Investment: Evidence from Chinese Listed Family Firms政治联系、融资摩擦与企业投资——来自中国上市家族企业的证据57.The Role Political Connections Play in Access to Finance:Evidence from Cross-Listing 政治关系在获得融资中发挥的作用:来自交叉上市的证据58.Auditor Choice in Politically Connected Firms政治关联公司的审计师选择59.Financial liberalization, financing constraints and political connection: evidence from Chinese firms金融自由化、融资约束与政治联系:来自中国上市公司的经验证据60.Effects of Financial Liberalization and Political Connection on Listed Chinese Firms' Financing Constraints金融自由化与政治关系对中国上市公司融资约束的影响61.Auditor Tenure, Non-Audit Services and Earnings Conservatism: Evidence from Malaysia审计任期,非审计服务与盈余稳健性——来自马来西亚的证据62.Political Connections of Newly Privatized Firms新私有化企业的政治关系63.Social network, entertainment expenditures and bank lending decisions: Evidence from China’s nonSOE firms社会网络、娱乐支出和银行贷款决策:来自中国非国有企业的证据64.Bank connection, corruption and collateral in China银行联系、腐败和担保:来自中国的证据65.Red Capitalists: Political Connections and Firm Performance in China红色资本家:政治关系与中国公司的业绩66.Political connections, bank deposits, and formal deposit insurance: Evidence from an emerging economy政治关系、银行存款与正式存款保险:来自新兴经济体的证据67.Executive’s former banking experience, entertainment expenditures and bank lending decisions: Evidence from China’s non-SOE firms执行官以前的银行业经验、娱乐支出与银行信贷决策:来自中国的非国有企业的证据68.The effect of political connections on the level and value of cash holdings: International evidence政治关联对现金持有水平及其价值的影响:国际证据69.The Effect of Political Influence and Corporate Transparency on Firm Performance: Empirical Evidence From Indonesian Listed Companies政治影响力与企业透明度对企业绩效的影响:来自印尼股票上市公司的经验证据70.Going Public Process and Political Connections: Evidence from an Emerging Market上市过程与政治联系:来自新兴市场的证据71.Do IPOs Reduce Firms’ Cost of Bank Loans? Evidence from ChinaIPO降低企业的银行贷款成本?来自中国的证据72.Public governance and corporate finance: Evidence from corruption cases公共治理与公司融资:腐败案件的证据73.Dividends, ownership structure and board governance on firm value: empirical evidence from malaysian listed firms股利、股权结构和董事会治理与公司价值:来自马来西亚上市公司的经验证据74.Management Quality and the Cost of Debt: Does Management Matter to Lenders管理质量和债务成本:管理对贷款人重要吗75.Do Educational Ties with Politicians Increase Agency Problems教育与政客联结增加代理问题吗76.Red Capitalists: Political Connections and the Growth and survival of Start-up Companies in China红色资本家:政治关系、成长和中国创业企业的生存77.The Impact of Legal and Political Institutions on Equity Trading Costs: A Cross-Country Analysis法律和政治制度对股票交易成本的影响:一个跨国家分析78.Expropriation of minority shareholders in politically connected firms政治关系企业中侵占小股东利益79.The Political Economy of Residual State Ownership in Privatized Firms: Evidence from Emerging Markets私有化企业中剩余政府所有权的政治经济:来自新兴市场的证据80.Does Financial Globalization Discipline Politically Connected Firms金融全球化约束政治关联的企业吗81.Audit fees in malaysia: does corporate governance matter马来西亚的审计费用:公司治理重要吗82.The Costs of Political Influence: Firm-Level Evidence from Developing Countries政治影响的成本:来自发展中国家的企业层面的证据83.Corporate social responsibility disclosure and its relation on institutional ownership企业社会责任披露及其与机构所有权的关系84.Political Connections and the Process of Going Public: Evidence from China政治关系和上市过程:来自中国的证据85.The Economic Benefits of Political Connections in Late Victorian Britain英国维多利亚时代后期政治关系的经济效益86.Corporate Cash Holdings, Board Structure, and Ownership Concentration: Evidence from Singapore企业现金持有量、董事会结构与股权集中度:来自新加坡的证据Political Uncertainty and Corporate Investment Cycles政治的不确定性与企业投资周期The Chinese Corporate Savings Puzzle: A Firm-Level Cross-Country Perspective中国公司储蓄的困惑:一个企业层面跨国家的视角Chinese firms’ political connection, ownership, and financing constraints中国企业的政治联系,、所有权与融资约束Political Relations and Overseas Stock Exchange Listing: Evidence from Chinese StateownedEnterprises政治关系和海外证券交易所上市:来自中国国有企业的证据Determinants and Effects of Corporate Lobbying企业游说的影响因素及影响Tunneling or Propping: Evidence from Connected Transactions in China隧道还是支持:来自中国关联交易的证据Sheltering Corporate Assets from Political Extraction保护公司资产从政治的提取Bank Power and Cash Holdings: Evidence from Japan银行权利与现金持有:来自日本的证据OLIGARCHIC FAMIL Y CONTROL, SOCIAL ECONOMIC OUTCOMES, AND THE QUALITY OF GOVERNMENT寡头的家族控制、社会的经济成果与政府质量Government Ownership and Corporate Governance: Evidence from the EU政府所有权与公司治理:来自欧盟的证据The Political Economy of Financial Systems金融体系的政治经济Escaping Political Extraction: Political Participation, Institutions, and Cash Holdings in China逃避政治的提取:政治参与、制度与中国的现金持有The value of local political connections in a low-corruption environment地方政治关系在低的腐败环境中的价值Retained State Shareholding in Chinese PLCs: Does Government Ownership Reduce Corporate Value中国上市公司保留的国有股:政府所有权降低企业价值吗Ownership Structure, Institutional Development, and Political Extraction: Evidence from China所有权结构、制度发展与政治提取:来自中国的证据How Do Agency Costs Affect Firm Value? Evidence from China代理成本如何影响公司价值吗?来自中国的证据Corporate Lobbying and Financial Performance公司游说与财务绩效Rights Issues in China as Evidence for the Existence of Two Types of Agency Problems中国人权问题作为两类代理问题存在的证据Auditor Choice in Politically Connected Firms政治关联公司的审计师选择(Journal of Accounting Research,V ol. 52 No. 1 March 2014)Transparency in Politically Connected Firms: Evidence from Private Sector Firms in China政治关联公司的透明度:来自中国私营公司的证据Capital Structure and Political Patronage: Evidence from China资本结构与政治赞助:来自中国的证据Competitive Pressure and Corporate Policies竞争压力与公司政策Political Capital and Moral Hazard1政治资本与道德风险The Effects of Government Quality on Corporate Cash Holdings政府质量对企业现金持有量的影响Corruption in Developing Countries腐败在发展中国家Large investors, capital expenditures, and firm value: Evidence from the Chinese stock market大投资者、资本支出与企业价值:来自中国证券市场的经验证据Firm Investment & Credit Constraints in India, 1997 – 2006: A stochastic frontier approach印度公司的投资与信贷约束,1997–2006:随机前沿方法State Ownership, Soft-Budget Constraint and Cash Holdings:Evidence from China’s Privatized Firms政府所有权、软预算约束与现金持有:来自中国私有化企业的证据Why Do Firms Hold Less Cash为什么公司持有更少的现金Directors’ Political Conn ections and Compliance with Board of Directors Regulations: The Case of S&P/Tsx 300 Companies董事会的政治关系和董事会遵守:标准普尔/ TSX 300公司为例Political Connection and Firm Value政治联系与企业价值The Impact of Political Connectedness on Firm Value and Corporate Policies: Evidence from Citizens United政治关系对公司价值和公司政策的影响:来自美国公民的证据The Impact of Political Connectedness on Cash Holdings: Evidence from Citizens United政治关系对现金持有的影响:来自美国公民的证据Political power and blood-related firm performance政治权力与有血缘关系的公司绩效Politically-Connecte d Boards and the Structure of Chief Executive Officer Compensation Packages in Taiwanese Firms政治关联董事会和台湾公司CEO薪酬结构Government Ownership and Agency Problems in Equity Offerings in China政府所有权与中国股票发行的代理问题Political Uncertainty and Accounting Conservatism: Evidence from the U.S. Presidential Election Cycle 政治不确定性与会计稳健性:来自美国总统选举周期的证据Effect of political uncertainty and corporate investment cycles in Nepal政治不确定性对尼泊尔企业投资周期的影响CEOs’ Connectedness, Social Capital, and Corporate InvestmentCEO关联、社会资本与企业投资Sovereign Wealth Funds and Politically Connected Firms主权财富基金与政治关联企业Political reforms and family-related firm performance政治改革与家族企业绩效Family connections in a low-corruption environment: Evidence from revised municipality borders在一个较低的腐败环境中家族联系:来自修订市边界的证据Does Political Uncertainty Affect Capital Structure Choices政治不确定性影响资本结构的选择吗Corporate Political Connections and Tax Aggressiveness企业政治关系与税收激进性Executive Compensation vis-à-vis Firm Performance: Identifying Future Research Agenda经理薪酬相对于公司绩效:识别未来的研究议程,Does Organizational-level Affiliation of Internal Audit Influence Corporate Risk-Taking? -Evidences from Chinese Listed Companies内部审计风险水平影响企业组织的联系吗?——来自中国股票上市公司的证据Principal-Principal Conflicts under Weak Institutions: A Study of Corporate Takeovers in China较弱制度下的委托代理冲突:中国公司并购的研究Earnings Management Practices Between Government Linked and Chinese Family Linked Companies 政府关联公司与中国家族关联企业之间的盈余管理实践Managerial Agency Costs of Socialistic Internal Capital Markets: Empirical Evidence from China社会主义内部资本市场的经理人代理成本:来自中国的经验证据Firm Size, Sovereign Governance, and Value Creation公司规模、主权治理与价值创造Bank firm relationship and firm performance under a state-owned bank system: evidence from China银企关系与企业国有银行制度下的绩效:来自中国的证据Excess control rights and corporate acquisitions超额控制权与公司并购Bank loan and the agency costs of debt in indonesia; free cash flows and managerial perks perspective 银行贷款和印度尼西亚债务的代理成本:自由现金流与管理津贴的视角CEO Compensation and Political ConnectednessCEO薪酬与政治关联Enterprises, Political Connections and Public Procurement at a Time of Landmark企业、政治关系与公共采购:一次具有里程碑意义的The Political Determinants of the Cost of Equity: Evidence from Newly Privatized Firms股权成本的政治因素:来自刚刚私有化的公司的证据Managerial Attributes and Executive Compensation管理者特征与高管薪酬An Empirical Investigation into the Political Economy of the Firm in a Globalizing World Economy: How Domestic Political Connections Affect Cross-listing Choices实证研究在全球化的世界经济的坚定的政治经济:国内政治关系如何影响交叉上市的选择Capital Markets and Capital Allocation:Implications for Economies of Transition资本市场与资本配置:经济转型的影响Responding to Financial Crisis: The Rise of State Ownership and Implications for Firm Performance应对金融危机:国家所有权上升对企业绩效的影响Influential ownership and capital structure有影响力的所有权与资本结构The Strategic Role Firms’ Political Connections Play in Access to Finance: Coercion of Domestic Banks or Implicit Property Rights Protections企业政治关系在获得融资中的战略作用:国内银行或隐含产权保护的强制手段Corporate Bailouts: the Role of Costly External Finance and Operating Performance企业救助:昂贵的外部融资的作用与经营绩效Do Political Connections Matter? Empirical Evidence from Listed Firms in Pakistan政治联系重要吗?来自巴基斯坦上市公司的经验证据Tycoons Turned Leaders: Market Valuation of Political Connections富豪转身领导:政治联系的市场价值Political Contributions and CEO Pay政治捐款和首席执行官工资Valuing Changes in Political Networks: Evidence from Campaign Contributions to Close Congressional 重视政治网络的变化:从运动的贡献接近国会的证据Corruption in state asset sales – Evidence from China国有资产销售中的腐败–来自中国的证据Investor Protection and Interest Group Politics投资者保护与利益集团政治Privatization, Large Shareholders’ In centive to Expropriate, and Firm Performance私有化、大股东掠夺激励与公司绩效Advances in Measuring Corruption in the Field腐败测量领域的进展Macroeconomic Conditions and the Puzzles of Credit Spreads and Capital Structure宏观经济条件、信用利差的困惑与资本结构Family Ownership and the Cost of Under Diversification家族所有权与多元化的成本Political Geography and Corporate Political Strategy政治地理学与企业政治策略Evidence on the existence and impact of corruption in state asset sales in China中国国有资产出售中腐败现象的存在及影响的证据Stock versus cash dividends: signaling or catering股票与现金股利:信号或宴会The impact of corruption on state asset sales – Evidence from China腐败对国有资产出售的影响-来自中国的证据Executive Compensation and CEO Equity Incentives in China’s Listed Firms高管薪酬与中国上市公司首席执行官的股权激励Political Constraints, Organizational Forms, and Privatization Performance:Evidence from China政治约束、组织形式与民营化绩效:来自中国的证据State Ownership, Political Institutions, and Stock Price Informativeness: Evidence from Privatization政府所有权、政治制度与股价信息含量:来自私有化的证据Corporate Governance in Emerging Markets: A Survey新兴市场的公司治理:文献综述Politically Connected Boards and Top Executive Pay In Chinese Listed Firms1.Political connection and leverage: Some Malaysian evidence2.Do political connections affect the role of independent audit committees and CEO Duality? Someevidence from Malaysian audit pricing3.Board, audit committee and restatement-induced class action lawsuits4.The Political Determinants of the Cost of Equity: Evidence from Newly Privatized Firms5.The impact of political connections on firms’ operating performance and financing decisionsernment Connections and Financial Constraints:Evidence from a Large Representative Sampleof Chinese Firms7.Listing approach, political favours and earnings quality: Evidence from Chinese family firms8.Political connections and tax-induced earnings management: evidence from China9.Ownership Concentration, State Ownership, and Effective Tax Rates: Evidence from China's ListedContext: European Evidence10.Impact of financial reporting quality on the implied cost of equity capital: Evidence from theMalaysian listed firms公允价值会计准则在新兴市场实施的挑战:来自中国采用国际财务报告准则的证据制度环境、政治关系与融资约束——来自中国民营企业的证据(March 1, 2012)政治关联、终极控制人性质与权益资本成本政治关联、盈余质量与权益资本成本政治联系、市场化进程与权益资本成本——来自中国民营上市公司的经验证据政府干预、政治关联与权益资本成本民营企业的政治关联能降低权益资本成本吗。
商业银行英语作文
商业银行英语作文In the heart of the financial ecosystem, commercial banks play a pivotal role in the modern economy. They serve as the backbone of financial transactions, providing a wide array of services that facilitate the flow of money and credit. This essay will delve into the essential functions of commercial banks, their impact on economic growth, and the challenges they face in the digital age.Functions of Commercial Banks1. Deposits: Commercial banks accept deposits fromindividuals and businesses, offering various types of accounts such as savings, checking, and time deposits. These deposits form the primary source of funds that banks use to extend credit to borrowers.2. Lending: By lending money to individuals and businesses, commercial banks stimulate economic activity. They assess the creditworthiness of borrowers and provide loans for various purposes, including personal loans, mortgages, and business loans.3. Payment Services: Banks facilitate the transfer of funds through various payment services such as checks, electronic funds transfers, and credit card transactions. They also issue debit and credit cards, which have become indispensable in today's cashless society.4. Investment Services: Many commercial banks offerinvestment services, helping customers invest in stocks, bonds, and mutual funds. They provide advice and manage portfolios, contributing to the growth of capital markets.Impact on Economic GrowthCommercial banks are instrumental in economic development. They:1. Allocate Resources Efficiently: By lending to businesses with the most promising projects, banks help direct resources to where they can be most productively used.2. Encourage Savings: By offering interest on deposits, banks incentivize individuals to save, which in turn provides more capital for lending and investment.3. Reduce Transaction Costs: Through their payment services, banks reduce the costs and complexities associated with financial transactions, making commerce more efficient.Challenges in the Digital AgeDespite their importance, commercial banks face several challenges in the era of digital finance:1. Technological Disruption: The rise of fintech companiesand digital currencies poses a threat to traditional banking services. Banks must innovate and adapt to remain competitive.2. Regulatory Compliance: Banks must navigate a complex web of regulations designed to prevent financial crises and protect consumers. Compliance can be costly and time-consuming.3. Cybersecurity: As banks become more reliant on digital systems, they also become more vulnerable to cyberattacks. Ensuring the security of customer data and transactions is a top priority.In conclusion, commercial banks are vital institutions in the modern economy, providing essential services that facilitate financial transactions and contribute to economic growth. However, they must continuously evolve to meet the challenges posed by technological advancements and regulatory requirements. As society becomes increasingly digital, the role of commercial banks will continue to transform, buttheir importance will remain undiminished.。
【银行零售业务转型发展研究国内外文献综述5000字】
银行零售业务转型发展研究国内外文献综述银行零售业务已经存在了近百年。
从20世纪20年代花旗银行开设世界上第一家零售业务银行开始,至20世纪90年代,零售银行业务发展迅速,已经逐渐成为国际银行业的核心业务。
1国外有关零售业务转型的研究现状国外商业银行起步较早,在零售业发展方面积累了丰富的经验。
银行零售业务研究出现在18世纪末。
随着银行业的逐步发展和国外市场环境的快速变化,国外学者的银行零售业务相关研究也形成了较为丰富的研究成果。
关于银行零售业务未来发展方向以及影响零售业务发展主要因素,不同学者有不同观点。
部分学者认为,商业银行零售业转型,离不开客户这个关键因素,以客户为中心,提高客户满意度是商业银行零售业务转型方向之一。
在银行零售业务发展的过程中,客户需求呈现多元化趋势,银行需要以此为基础提供优质、高效、多元化的金融服务,并逐步扩大市场规模(Stevek,2012)。
因此,为客户提供优质的金融服务,创新现代金融产品为商业银行零售业转型起到事半功倍的作用。
Wruuck(2013)通过研究产品定价与提高零售银行客户满意度和利润的途径,发现客户满意度和银行收入之间存在正相关关系。
在确定零售银行资产管理产品的价格时,客户满意度将成为关键判断因素。
满意度较高的客户往往会从银行购买更多的金融产品并将其推荐给其他客户,从而显著提高银行的业绩。
也证实了提升客户满意度可以作为银行零售业务转型的方向。
银行零售业务以客户为中心才能制定出最佳策略(Blankson,2017)。
Fernandes(2019)从数百家银行收集和分析客户数据,通过研究也证实了银行需要与其客户建立良好的关系,强调以客户为中心的服务理念。
部分学者认为,数字化是现代商业银行零售业务转型的主要方向。
这部分研究学者,先是研究证实了银行零售数字化转型的必要性,以及现代化信息科学技术对银行零售业务转型的作用。
例如,Hirtle 和Stiroh(2005)研究认为,电子信息革命和互联网的兴起改变了银行的传统业务模式。
翻译2
国家经济研究局记者:研究综述 2005年秋银行监管和监督罗斯莱文大量的研究表明,银行机构关乎人类福利的问题。
最为明显的是,当他们失败潦倒时,银行就与他们息息相关了。
事实上,自1980年以来发展中国家银行危机所导致的财政成本,已超过1万亿美元,并且一些人估计这其中还不包括日本银行问题所导致的成本。
最近的研究还标明,银行关乎到经济的增长。
银行通过有效的调动和分配储蓄,配置用于期望得到最高社会回报的投资资金,扩大投资公司的有效管理来促进一个国家的创新与增长。
银行不会将其信贷渠道与任何不主张企业家精神和阻碍经济发展的政党和政治势力相连。
最近的工作进一步证明,银行关注贫困和收入分配问题。
运作良好的银行会向那些最好的项目提供信贷,而不是富人或与之相连的那些家庭,政治,或腐败,进一步发挥银行调节收入分配方面的作用,扩大对穷人所产生的积极影响,通过一些好的思想和做法将其与过去财富积累与协会影响脱钩。
银行与经济福利的重要关系导致研究人员和国际机构制定有关银行监管和监督方面的政策。
国际货币基金组织,世界银行以及其他国际机构已经制定了“最佳做法”的建议,他们敦促所有国家采取这些举措。
最有影响力的巴塞尔银行监督委员会最近修订和延长了1988年巴塞尔资本协议。
这些新建议中首要的一条是广泛的发展了银行在计算最低资本金要求方面的程序。
第二个方面是重点加强官方的监督措施和确保监管机构在审议和约束银行方面的权力。
第三个方面设想通过提高银行的市场政策,纪律,强制银行披露准确透明的信息。
虽然对这些政策的有效性存在大量的辩论,100多个国家已经表示,他们最终将采用巴塞尔协议。
数据到目前为止,关于银行监管和监督方面缺乏数据,使得一些跨国研究无法进行,这些研究是关于加强银行监督管理能够健全银行体系。
虽然分析师使用模型,实施国家研究,监管者有制定监管政策建议方面的经验,但也没有足够数据来进行广泛的国际比较,并测试新巴塞尔协议或其他改革建议的有效性。
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
The impact of banking regulations on banks'cost and pro fit ef ficiency:Cross-country evidenceFotios Pasiouras a ,⁎,Sailesh Tanna b ,Constantin Zopounidis ca School of Management,University of Bath,UKb Department of Economics,Finance and Accounting,Coventry University,UKcDepartment of Production Engineering and Management,Technical University of Crete,Greecea b s t r a c ta r t i c l e i n f o Article history:Received 19June 2008Received in revised form 26March 2009Accepted 29July 2009Available online 6August 2009JEL classi fication:G21G28D2C24Keywords:Banking Ef ficiency RegulationsStochastic frontier analysisThis paper uses stochastic frontier analysis to provide international evidence on the impact of the regulatory and supervision framework on bank ef ficiency.Our dataset consists of 2853observations from 615publicly quoted commercial banks operating in 74countries during the period 2000–2004.We investigate the impact of regulations related to the three pillars of Basel II (i.e.capital adequacy requirements,of ficial supervisory power,and market discipline mechanisms),as well as restrictions on bank activities,on cost and pro fit ef ficiency of banks,while controlling for other country-speci fic characteristics.Our results suggest that banking regulations that enhance market discipline and empower the supervisory power of the authorities increase both cost and pro fit ef ficiency of banks.In contrast,stricter capital requirements improve cost ef ficiency but reduce pro fit ef ficiency,while restrictions on bank activities have the opposite effect,reducing cost ef ficiency but improving pro fit ef ficiency.©2009Elsevier Inc.All rights reserved.1.IntroductionAs banks operate in one of the most heavily regulated environ-ments,research in banking regulations and their effect on bank performance and stability has long attracted both theoretical and empirical interest.At the international level,Barth et al.(2004)investigate the effect of a broad range of regulatory and supervisory measures on bank stability,development and performance,while Demirguc-Kunt et al.(2008)and Pasiouras et al.(2006)study the effect of similar measures on banks'overall soundness,as measured by credit ratings.Similarly,other studies have examined the effect of regulations on banking sector crises (Demirguc-Kunt and Detra-giache,2002;Beck et al.,2006a )and banks'risk-taking behaviour (Gonzalez,2005;Laeven and Levine,2009).An issue that has received comparatively little attention,however,is what impact the regulatory environment has on bank ef ficiency,as opposed to other measures of bank performance.This paper seeks to address thisissue by offering international evidence on the cost and pro fit ef ficiency of banks.Prior studies in the literature have sought to account for the in fluence of banking regulations as part of the environmental factors affecting bank ef ficiency.Dietsch and Lozano-Vivas (2000),for example,highlight the impact of differences in the environmental conditions on banks'cost ef ficiency,using a sample of Spanish and French banks.Similarly,multi-country studies that examine sources of differences in bank ef ficiency account for country-speci fic differences in the economic,financial or technological environments using aggregate measures such as market capitalization,GDP growth,number of banks or ATMs per population,etc.In accounting for regulatory in fluences,however,these studies have,owing to data limitations,resorted to use of simple proxies such as the degree of market concentration,industry average capital,industry average pro fitability,and intermediation ratios (e.g.Dietsch and Lozano-Vivas,2000).Similarly,Grigorian and Manole (2002),in examining bank ef ficiency differences for the transition countries of Eastern Europe and former Soviet Union,account for the in fluence of reg-ulatory measures such as capital adequacy ratio,maximum exposure to single borrower and limits on foreign exchange open positions.Furthermore,a few recent studies,also focussing on transition countries,have used the European Bank for Reconstruction andInternational Review of Financial Analysis 18(2009)294–302⁎Corresponding author.Tel.:+441225384297.E-mail address:f.pasiouras@ (F.Pasiouras).1057-5219/$–see front matter ©2009Elsevier Inc.All rights reserved.doi:10.1016/j.irfa.2009.07.003Contents lists available at ScienceDirectInternational Review of Financial AnalysisDevelopment(EBRD)index of banking sector reform among the environmental factors affecting bank efficiency(e.g.Fries and Taci, 2005).1Most recently,Pasiouras(2008)tackles the issue at the cross-country level by employing a broad range of regulatory and supervision measures developed by the World Bank(Barth et al.,2001b)to investigate the technical efficiency of ing data envelopment analysis(DEA)and Tobit regressions on a sample of715banks operating in95countries during2003,hefinds that banks'technical efficiency is positively influenced in some regressions by capital adequacy standards, powerful supervisory agencies and market discipline mechanisms(the latter being significant in all his regressions).The present paper provides further international evidence in relation to the impact of the regulatory environment by focussing on the cost and profit efficiency of banks.The specific regulations of concern in this paper are related to restrictions on banks'activities and the three pillars of Basel II,namely capital requirements(Pillar1),official supervisory power(Pillar2),and market discipline mechanisms(Pillar3).While around100countries have stated their intention to adopt Basel II,there is an on-going debate about the costs and benefits of the proposed regulatory approaches(Barth et al.,2006).Hence,the importance of our study lies in providing cross-country analysis and evidence relating to some of the enduring questions about the impact of the new regulatory framework for the banking industry.While the present study is related to Pasiouras(2008)in studying the impact of regulations on bank efficiency,it is fundamentally different in three respects.Thefirst and probably the most important is that we examine the impact on cost and profit efficiency of banks. Cost efficiency is a wider concept than technical efficiency,since it refers to both technical and allocative efficiency.Profit efficiency is an even wider concept as it combines both costs and revenues in the measurement of efficiency.2Maudos et al.(2002)point out that the estimation of profit efficiency and its comparison to cost efficiency, and international efficiency comparisons are two areas where the available evidence on bank efficiency is very limited.Thus,our study contributes in bridging this gap,while at the same time provides statistical evidence of the association of these two efficiency measures with capital requirements,official supervisory power,market disci-pline,and restriction on bank activities.Second,we use stochastic frontier analysis(SFA)rather than DEA.The main advantage of SFA over DEA is that it allows us to distinguish between inefficiency and other stochastic shocks in the estimation of efficiency scores(Yildirim and Philippatos,2007).Finally,our sample is more representative as we use panel data over the period2000–2004rather than cross-section data at one point in time(i.e.2003);it has been argued that efficiency is better studied and modelled with panels(Coelli et al., 2005).3As noted in the Introduction section,our paper is also related in spirit to recent studies that provide international evidence on the impact of regulations and supervision on banks'performance(e.g. Barth et al.,2002;Demirguc-Kunt et al.,2004).In contrast to these studies,which mainly usefinancial ratios as indicators of perfor-mance,we measure bank efficiency using an efficient frontier technique.Berger and Humphrey(1997)emphasise that efficient frontier approaches are superior when compared to traditional measures of performance(e.g.return on assets,cost/revenue),since they account simultaneously for relevant inputs and outputs of a bank,as well as for differences in the input prices.Furthermore,they offer an overall objective numerical score and ranking that complies with an optimization mechanism.The rest of the paper is structured as follows.Section2provides a brief background discussion on the impact of regulations on bank performance.Section3covers the methodological issues and data for our empirical work.Section4discusses the empirical results,and Section5concludes.2.Theoretical background and discussionIn this section,we discuss some theoretical and empirical studies that examine the impact of Basel II type regulations on aspects of bank performance such as profitability,efficiency,soundness,and risk-taking.We also examine the theoretical implications and evidence with regard to restrictions on bank activities which,although not part of the new Basel framework,is another feature of efficiency affecting regulation that has traditionally attracted the attention of policy makers and researchers.As mentioned already,and discussed further below in more detail, bank efficiency measures show how efficient banks are,relative to the best-practice frontier,in transforming their inputs(e.g.deposits)to outputs(e.g.loans).Therefore,capital requirements can affect bank efficiency by influencing:(i)the quantity and quality of lending,(ii) the decision of banks in allocating their asset portfolios,and(iii)the decision of banks regarding their sources of funds(i.e.equity, deposits).For instance,in relation to(i),the theoretical model of Kopecky and VanHoose(2006)predicts that the introduction of binding regulatory capital requirements on a previously unregulated banking system reduces aggregate lending,while loan quality may either improve or worsen.With regard to the latter,Berger and DeYoung(1997)argue that loan quality and efficiency can be related in several ways through the“bad luck”,“bad management”,“skimp-ing”and“moral hazard”hypotheses.In relation to(ii),VanHoose (2007)argues that stricter capital standards may influence banks in substituting loans with alternative forms of assets.Obviously,this could influence their cost and profit efficiency,because different asset portfolios will generate different returns,and require different resources to be managed;furthermore,despite potential diversifica-tion benefits,there is the question of whether banks can manage efficiently a portfolio of different assets.Finally,in relation to(iii), capital requirements may influence the decisions of banks with regard to the mix of deposits and equity,which bear different costs for banks. The results of Pasiouras(2008)indicate a positive association between capital requirements and technical efficiency,although this1In addition,there are numerous other studies,focussing on individual countries, which attempt to account for the impact offinancial regulation(or deregulation)by using dummy variables in their empirical specifications,while studies for the US have incorporated proxies for differences in state regulations.However,these studies do not explicitly focus on the impact of regulatory policies and,more important,they are country specific.With regard to the practice of bank regulations and what works best, Barth et al.(2004a)quote“…there is no evidence:that any universal set of best practices is appropriate for promoting well-functioning banks;that successful practices in the United States,for example,will succeed in countries with different institutional settings;…”(p.206).Acknowledging this viewpoint,we assume that regulatory and environmental differences exist across countries and our cross-country analysis attempts to investigate their impact on bank efficiency.2Technical efficiency(TE)indicates whether a bank uses the minimum quantity of inputs to produce given quantity of outputs.Allocative efficiency(AE)refers to the ability of a bank to use the optimum mix of inputs given their respective prices.Cost efficiency,which is the product of TE and AE,shows the ability of a bank to provide services without wasting resources as a result of technical or allocative efficiency. More detailed,cost efficiency indicates how close a bank's cost is to what a best practice bank's cost would be for producing the same outputs under the sameconditions.Similarly,profit efficiency shows how close afirm is to earning the profit that a best-practice bank would earn under the same conditions.In other words, efficiency measures how close to the minimum cost or maximum profit a banks is, with the minimum and maximum being determined by the best performers in the sample.Maudos et al.(2002)argue:“Computing profit efficiency,therefore, constitutes a more important source of information for bank management than the partial vision offered by analyzing cost efficiency”(p.34).3The use of panel data over a cross-section provides more degrees of freedom in the estimation of the parameters.Furthermore,and more importantly,the use of panel data accounts for time variations in efficiency given the possibility that managers might learn from previous experience in the production process,thereby indicating that inefficiency effects would change in some persistent pattern over time.Finally, there may be regulatory or environmental factors that affect the performance of banks over time.295F.Pasiouras et al./International Review of Financial Analysis18(2009)294–302is not statistically significant in all cases.Studies that focus on other aspects of bank behaviour and performance generally indicate that capital requirements increase risk-taking(e.g.Blum,1999),although that may happen only under specific circumstances(Kendall,1992). Barth et al.(2004)find that while stringent capital requirements are associated with fewer non-performing loans,capital stringency is not robustly linked with banking sector stability,development or bank performance(as measured by overhead and margin ratios)when controlling for other supervisory-regulatory policies.Finally, Pasiouras et al.(2006)find a negative relationship between capital requirements and banks'soundness as measured by Fitch ratings.In theory,there tends to be support for both the official supervision approach and the private monitoring approach to bank supervision.4The official supervision approach argues that official supervisors have the capabilities to avoid market failure by directly overseeing,regulating,and disciplining banks.Consequently,as Beck et al.(2006a)suggest,a powerful supervisor could enhance the corporate governance of banks, reduce corruption in bank lending,and improve the functioning of banks asfinancial intermediaries.By contrast,the private monitoring approach argues that powerful supervision might be related to corruption or other factors that impede bank operations,whereas regulations that promote market discipline through private monitoring from depositors,debt-holders and equity holders,will result in better outcomes for the banking sector.Thus,under the private monitoring empowerment view,we would expect that improved private governance of banks will boost their functioning(Levine,2005)and consequently their efficiency.However, requirements for increased disclosures can also have a negative impact on efficiency due to direct costs of making additional disclosures,maintaining investor relations departments,additional time and efforts to prepare formal disclosure documents,and the release of sensitive information to competitors(Duarte et al.,2008).The empirical results in relation to the above two arguments are mixed.Although Barth et al.(2004)and Levine(2005)provide evidence that only private monitoring has an impact on banks'performance, Pasiouras(2008)finds that official supervisory power also positively influences banks'technical efficiency in several cases.Beck et al.(2006a)find that empowerment of private monitoring assists efficient corporate finance and has a positive effect on the integrity of bank lending in countries with sound legal institutions.Demirguc-Kunt et al.(2008) show that the reporting of regular and accuratefinancial data to regulators and market participants results in sounder banks;however Pasiouras et al.(2006)find a negative relationship between credit ratings and disclosure requirements(though this is significant only at the10%level and not robust across their specifications).Finally,Barth et al.(2004)indicate that there is no evidence that regulations that foster private monitoring reduce the likelihood of suffering major banking crises.With respect to the power of supervisors,evidence suggests that it is associated with higher levels of non-performing loans (Barth et al.,2002),it can be harmful to bank development(Barth et al., 2003b)and it is also negatively associated with overall bank soundness (Pasiouras et al.,2006).Finally,Barth et al.(2004)summarize several theoretical reasons for restricting bank activities as well as alternative reasons for allowing banks to participate in a broad range of activities.For example,as moral hazard encourages riskier behaviour,banks will have greater opportu-nities to increase risk if allowed to engage in a broader range of activities. On the other hand,fewer regulatory restrictions permit the utilization of economies of scale and scope,whilst also increase the franchise value of banks and result in a more sensible behaviour.Thus,while their argument suggests ambiguous predictions,empirical evidence is relied upon.To this end,Barth et al.(2004)find a negative association between restrictions on bank activities and banking sector development and stability.Barth et al.(2001a)also confirm that greater regulatory restrictions on bank activities are associated with higher probability of suffering a major banking crisis,as well as lower banking sector ef-ficiency.In contrast,Fernandez and Gonzalez(2005)find that stricter restrictions on bank activities are effective at reducing banking risk, although they argue that this is mitigated by higher information dis-closure and auditing requirements.Lower restrictions on bank activities have also been associated with higher credit ratings(Pasiouras et al., 2006),although Pasiouras(2008)finds no significant association with technical efficiency.3.Methodology and data3.1.MethodologyWe use the Battese and Coelli(1995)model that provides estimates of efficiency in a single-step in whichfirm effects are directly influenced by a number of variables.5This approach allows us to estimate a global frontier while accounting for cross-country differences.6In its general form,the cost model can be written as follows7:ln C i;t=Cðq i;t;p i;t;βÞ+u i;t+v i;t;i=1;2;:::;N;t=1;2;:::;Tð1Þwhere:C i,t is the total cost of bank i at time t;q i,t is a vector of outputs;p i,t denotes a vector of values of input prices associated with a suitable functional form;βis a vector of unknown scalar parameters to be estimated;v i,t s are random errors,assumed to be i.i.d.and have N(0,σv2); u i,t s are the non-negative inefficiency effects in the model which are assumed to be independently(but not identically)distributed,such that u i,t is obtained by truncation(at zero)of the N(m i,t,σu2)distribution where the mean is defined by:m i;t=z i;tδð2Þwhere z i,t is a(1×M)vector of observable explanatory variables that influence the inefficiency of bank i at time t;andδis an(M×1)vector of coefficients to be estimated(which would generally be expected to include an intercept parameter).The parameters of Eqs.(1)and(2)are estimated in one step using maximum likelihood.8The individual bank (in)efficiency scores are calculated from the estimated frontiers as CE kt= exp(u i)and PEF kt=exp(−u i),the former taking a value between one and infinity and the latter between zero and one.To make our results comparable,however,we calculate the index of cost efficiency as follows: CEF kt=1/CE kt.Hence,in both cases our efficiency scores will be between0 and1with values closer to1indicating a higher level of efficiency.Concerning the specification of the efficiency frontier,we follow the value added approach which suggests using deposits as outputs since they imply the creation of value added.Thus,following Dietsch and Lozano-Vivas(2000),Maudos et al.(2002),and others,we choose the following three outputs:loans(Q1),other earning assets(Q2),and total deposits(i.e.customer and interbank)(Q3).Furthermore,consistent with most previous studies on bank efficiency we select the following4Barth et al.(2004a)and Levine(2005)provide discussions of these two approaches.5We use a single-step procedure instead of the two-step method for the following reasons:1)predicted inefficiencies are only a function of environmental variables if the latter are included into thefirst step,which makes the second stage unnecessary; and2)if the environmental variables will not be included in thefirst stage,one will obtain biased estimators of the parameters of the deterministic part of the frontier, resulting in biased estimators of efficiency as well(see Coelli et al.,2005).6An advantage of estimating a global frontier,instead of country-specific frontiers, is that it increases the number of available observations.Furthermore,as Berger and Humphrey(1997)argue,“a frontier formed from the complete dataset across nations would allow for a better comparison across nations,since the banks in each country would be compared against the same standard”(p.187–188).7For brevity of space,we present only the cost function here,noting that,under the alternative profit approach,we simply replace total costs by profit before taxes as the dependent variable and change the sign of the inefficiency term(−u it)to estimate profit efficiency.8See Battese and Coelli(1995)and Coelli et al.(2005),for further details.296 F.Pasiouras et al./International Review of Financial Analysis18(2009)294–302three input prices:cost of borrowed funds(P1),calculated as the ratio of interest expenses to total deposits;cost of physical capital(P2), calculated by dividing the expenditures on plant and equipment(i.e. overhead expenses net of personnel expenses)by the book value of fixed assets;and cost of labour(P3),calculated by dividing the personnel expenses by total assets.9As mentioned above,in the case of the cost frontier model,the dependent variable is bank's total cost(TC)calculated as the summation of interest expenses and non-interest expenses.In the case of the profit frontier model,the variable to be explained is the profit before taxes(PBT). As in most previous studies,we estimate an alternative profit frontier that is specified in terms of input prices and output quantities.Berger and Mester(1997)outline a number of cases under which the alternative profit function may be more appropriate than the standard one. Furthermore,based on these arguments,Maudos et al.(2002)and Kasman and Yildirim(2006)point out that in international comparisons across a diverse group of countries and competition levels it seems more appropriate to estimate an alternative rather than a standard profit function.To account for changes in technology over time,we include year dummies in the frontier.10Furthermore,in line with Berger and Mester (1997)among others,we use equity(E)to control for differences in risk preferences.11Finally,we impose linear homogeneity restrictions by normalizing the dependent variables and all input prices by the third input price P3.As in several recent studies(e.g.Dietsch and Lozano-Vivas,2000;Fries and Taci,2005),we use the multi-product translog specification which results in an empirical cost frontier model of the following format:ln TCP3=β0+β1lnðQ1Þ+β2lnðQ2Þ+β3lnðQ3Þ+β4lnP1P3+β5lnP2P3+β612ðlnðQ1ÞÞ2+β7lnðQ1ÞlnðQ2Þ+β8lnðQ1ÞlnðQ3Þ+β912ðlnðQ2ÞÞ2+β10lnðQ2ÞlnðQ3Þ+β111ðlnðQ3ÞÞ2+β121ln P12+β13lnP1lnP2+β141lnP22+β15lnðQ1ÞlnP1+β16lnðQ1ÞlnP2+β17lnðQ2ÞlnP1+β18lnðQ2ÞlnP2+β19lnðQ3ÞlnP1+β20lnðQ3ÞlnP2+β21lnðEÞ+β221ðlnðEÞÞ2+β23lnðEÞlnðQ1Þ+β24lnðEÞlnðQ2Þ+β25lnðEÞlnðQ3Þ+β26lnðEÞlnP1+β27lnðEÞlnP2P3+β28D2004+β29D2003+β30D2002 +β31D2001+u i;t+v i;t:ð3Þ3.1.1.Determinants of inefficiencyTo examine the impact of the regulatory variables on(in)efficiency while controlling for other country-specific characteristics,m it in Eq.(2)is specified as:m it=δ+δ1CAPITRQ+δ2OFFPR+δ3MDISCIP+δ4ACTRS+δ5INFL+δ6GDPGR +δ7MACGDP+δ8CLAIMS+δ9GOVERN+δ10FOREIGN+δ11CONC+δ12DEVELð4Þwhere CAPITRQ,OFFPR,MDISCIP and ACTRS are the four regulatory variables;INFL and GDPGR control for the macroeconomic environ-ment;MACGDP and CLAIMS are controls forfinancial development; CONC,FOREIGN,GOVERN are controls for market structure;and DEVEL is a dummy variable to control for the state of economic development. These control variables are discussed briefly below,while further information about the regulatory variables is provided in Appendix A.CAPITRQ is an index of capital requirements,accounting for both initial and overall capital stringency.The former indicates whether the sources of funds counted as regulatory capital can include assets other than cash or government securities and borrowed funds,as well as whether the regulatory or supervisory authorities verify these sources.The latter indicates whether risk elements and value losses are considered while calculating the regulatory capital.CAPITRQ can take values between0and8with higher values indicating more stringent capital requirements.12OFFPR is a measure of the power of the supervisory agencies.It is calculated on the basis of the answers to14questions indicating the extent to which supervisors can change the internal organizational structure of the bank and/or take specific disciplinary action against bank management and directors,shareholders,and bank auditors.MDISCIP is an indicator of market discipline that takes values between0and8with higher values indicating higher disclosure requirements and more incentives to increase private monitoring.For example,MDISCIP indicates among others whether subordinated debt is allowable or required as part of capital,whether banks must disclose their off-balance sheet items and their risk management procedures to the public,whether accrued,though unpaid interest/ principal enter the income statement while loan is non-performing, and whether there is an explicit deposit insurance protection system.ACTRS indicates the level of restrictions on banks'activities.It can take values between0and4with higher values indicating higher restrictions. It is determined by considering whether securities,insurance,real estate activities,and ownership of non-financialfirms is unrestricted(=1), permitted(=2),restricted(=3)or prohibited(=4).We construct an overall index by calculating the average value over all four activities.INFL is the annual inflation rate,and GDPGR is the real GDP growth. Both of these are used to control for the macroeconomic environment,as in Maudos et al.(2002),Kasman and Yildirim(2006)and Pasiouras (2008).CLAIMS is the ratio of bank claims to the private sector to GDP, which serves as an indicator of activity in the banking sector,while MACGDP is a measure of stock market size,calculated as the ratio of stock market capitalization to GDP.Same or similar measures have been used in other studies(e.g.Barth et al.,2003a;Kasman and Yildirim,2006; Pasiouras,2008).Also,following previous studies that focus on banks' performance(Barth et al.,2004;Fries and Taci,2005;Pasiouras,2008),we control for cross-country differences in the national structure and competitive conditions of the banking sector,using the following measures:(i)the percentage of foreign-owned banks operating in the market,FOREIGN;(ii)the percentage government-owned banks operating in the market,GOVERN;and(iii)the percentage of assets held by the three largest commercial banks relative to the total assets of the commercial banking sector within the country,CONC.Finally,DEVEL is a dummy9We use total assets rather than the number of employees due to several missing values for the latter.Our approach is consistent with several previous studies(e.g. Maudos et al.,2002).10Estimating our models with a time trend,as an alternative to including year dummies,has no impact on our results.These alternative estimations are available from the authors upon request.11Since a number of banks in the sample exhibit negative profits(i.e.losses),we added a constant value to every bank's profit so as to make them all positive,as it is common in the literature,thus allowing natural logarithms to be taken.We followed the same approach for equity as we had a small number of banks with negative equity values(see,e.g.Yildirim and Philippatos,2007).12For the construction of the capital requirements(CAPITRQ),power of supervisory agencies(OFFPR)and market discipline(MDISC)indices,we use the summation of the 0/1quantified answers as in Barth et al.(2001b),Fernandez and Gonzalez(2005), Pasiouras et al.(2006)and Pasiouras(2008).An alternative would be to use the principal component approach as in Levine(2005b).Barth et al.(2004a)have followed both approaches.They mention that the drawback of using the summation for the construction of the index is that it assigns equal weight to each of the questions, whereas thefirst principal component has the disadvantage of being less transparent in how a change in the response to a question changes the index.They confirm“all this paper's conclusions using both methods”(p.218),implying that there are no significant differences in the results,although they report only the results using the principal component method.297F.Pasiouras et al./International Review of Financial Analysis18(2009)294–302。