资本成本,公司财务和投资理论【外文翻译】
资本成本通俗解释

资本成本通俗解释资本成本是指企业应该付出的资金成本,这个成本要求企业面对市场价格按照“最优决策”把资金转化为最有利的利润机会。
它一般用来衡量资金的生产效率,以及企业的投资行为和风险承受能力。
从投资理论的角度来讲,资本成本是一个投资者在获得一定投资收益前,必须承受的投资成本。
它反映出资金投资可以获得的期望回报,也是投资者最终受益的比率。
资本成本的计算可以分为内部资本成本和外部资本成本两类。
内部资本成本是指一定投资费用,即财务费用、资本金成本等,它反映出企业在自由市场上获得资金所必须付出的成本。
外部资本成本则是指投资者在投资收益前所必须付出的资金成本,这种成本可以把市场上存在的风险加入考虑之中。
计算资本成本可以利用“资本资产定价模型”(CAPM),它是一种在财务理论中用来测算一定投资收益年化率的模型,而结果就是资本成本。
CAPM的核心思想是,投资者的投资收益(超额收益)与其预期的市场风险度有关,这种风险度反映在一定的投资收益率上,这就是资本成本的概念。
企业的投资行为通常依据几个原则,其中最重要的原则就是最大化投资回报即要使投资回报大于资本成本,使企业整体投资收益最大化。
这样一来,企业就可以按照自己的投资行为带来的收益与资本成本之间的关系,来分析各种投资行为所带来的投资效果。
资本成本是影响企业投资行为的重要参考基础,它可以帮助企业通过评估投资收益带来的财务风险而使投资效益最大化。
它可以为企业的财务管理提供一个客观的标准,以评估决策过程中所承受的经济收益和风险。
资本成本的计算不仅仅需要考虑企业内部因素,还要考虑外部环境因素,这样才能更准确地评估企业投资行为带来的收益。
此外,资本成本也与企业的财务目标密切相关,因此企业投资者应当结合自身的投资状况和长远目标,认真分析资本成本,以便为投资做出更好的决策。
总之,资本成本是投资者选择投资的重要参考标准之一,也是企业进行投资决策的重要依据。
很明显,正确计算准确的资本成本能帮助企业和投资者判断投资是否合算,并有助于投资决策的可行性,为企业实现最大投资回报提供了充足的帮助。
财务 会计 外文翻译 外文文献 英文文献 成本控制和财务控制

财务会计外文翻译外文文献英文文献成本控制和财务控制Cost control and financial controlBy cost control and financial control goal by the cost control and the financial control goal financial control is the business management important constituent, seeps to inenterprise's each domain, each link. The financial control directlyrelates the enterprise the survival and the development, said from some kind of significance, the financial control is an enterprise sustainable development key. However, some enterprises' financial control. These enterprises' financial control have two erroneous zones: One, the financial control simplification, the financial control is only the financial department's matter as if, neglects its whole management function; Two is the financial department completely takes orders from to " Boss " Neglect financial control own regularity and relative independence. Presently on enterprise question and so on in financial control investment management, fund management, financial surveillance management, appropriation of profit management makes the discussion.First, modern enterprise system and financial control The financial control is the social productive forces development result, probably in 15-16 century, area the Mediterranean Sea coast city trade obtained the rapid development, the initial period joint stock system company's appearance request financial control was born as enterprise's one kindof organization form. But this time financial control also merely is only in a business management appendage, but also does not have own independent function, also lacks the financial control theory and the experience; therefore, this only can be the financial control shade bud time. To 19th century50's after, enters along with the west industrial revolution completes the time, with gradually improves along with the joint stock system company’sunceasing expansion, how in order to adapt collects the capital, the outstanding share, how assigns the profit the need, only then has had the specialized financial control. Our country business management and manages finances the development should say was passes through the tortuous path, has paid the suitable price. In the planned economy time, our country business management and the financial control are not take pursues the enterprise benefits the goal, the income assignment is under the distribution according to work slogan egalitarianism. After reform and open policy, specially in 1993, the Central Party1Committee 14 sessions of three CCP plenary conferences explicitly proposed the state-owned enterprise's reform direction is “Establishment modern enterprise system andimplementation science business management (financial control) "The financial control is only then taken. At present, the state-owned enterprise is speeding up the enterprise to change the system the work. The sole state-owned enterprise is facing the investment main bodymultiplication joint stock system mixed type economic form development, the operator and the enterprise staff holds the stock to cause thestate-owned enterprise and the general staffs truly becomes common fate group. After the state-owned enterprise transforms the management mechanism, will become the genuine market competition main body and the legal person governs the entity. The state-owned enterprise established the modern enterprise system and the state-owned enterprise changes the system to the financial control seta more urgent higher request.Second, when good gives advice, invests the good enterprise thepolicy-making pass the decision-making is in the business management a most important work. The decision-making has the cost; this point is easily neglected by the person. For example a correct decision-making gains 1million Yuan for the enterprise, if has lost the opportunity, has not made the prompt decision-making, this policy-making cost is 1million Yuan; If has made a wrong decision-making, not only has not gained to1 million Yuan, instead lost money 1 million Yuan, then, this wrong policy-making cost is 2 million Yuan. Therefore, the decision-making also must speak the cost control. The investment decision-making is in enterprise all decisions-makings most essential, the most important decision-making, because we often said: The investment decision-making fault is the enterprise biggest fault, an important investment decision-making fault often can cause an enterprise to fall into the difficult position, even goes bankrupt. Therefore, a financialcontrol extremely important function for the enterprise when good gives advice the good investment decision-making pass.The investment is refers to the delivery financial resource to the certain object, expected will gain the income in the future the economic activities. The investment has very many types: From the investment recycling time division, has the long-term investment and the short term investment; Looked from the investment direction that, has2to in investment and the foreign investment; Take invests to the enterprise future influence as the basis, may divide into the strategic investment and the tactic investment, as well as newly established investment and following investment; Definite investment and venture capital; Relevant investment and non- relevant investment and so on. These classifications are divide from the logical division dichotomy, each kind invests itself has the many kinds of types the nature and the characteristic, for example long-term investment itself, it both is possibly the strategic investment, and possibly is risk investment and so on. Therefore, we in consideration investment below time must be good "four passes". First, good economic activities pass. Must be clear about the investment is economic activities, must seek the basis from the economic law, thus makes the correct investment decision-making. The author has investigated certain state-owned enterprises many faults investment decision-making, very big fault reason has not gone to thedecision-making from economic law itself, but was from "politics”,” the interpersonal relationship" and so on the factorrashly has made the investment decision-making. For example a state-owned enterprise’sboard of directors takes orders from Yu higher authority officer "to suggest", for higher authority's senior officer's son's corporate investment 3 million Yuan, the result is " The meat dumpling beats a dog " Has not returns; Also for example a very successful state-owned enterprise's general manager, in order to repay his hometown, forcefully advocated invests 5 million Yuan in his hometown to manage the factory, but his hometown actually does not have supplies this kind of factory the condition, finally the factory was manages successfully, actually year after year lost money, has become this enterprise's " Heavy cloth wrapper " . Even also has the state-owned enterprise the person in charge invests at will the state asset for own relative friend and the side person, strictly said, this already was one kind of corrupt behavior, is one kind of crime. This investment way has unexpectedly accounted for about 40% in the investigation investment decision-making fault, is a phenomenon which one kind of ten points is worth taking. Another kind of investment decision-making fault is invests the policy-maker quality to be bad, the bureaucratic, acts arbitrarily, own do not understand the decision-making which the economic law makes. This investment way approximately composes 50% in the investigationinvestment decision-making fault. Second, good investigation and study pass,3strictly according to international convention management, according to government by law management. The investment decision-making is a process. In makes in front of the investment decision-making, must thoroughly conduct the investigation and study, carries on thefeasibility analysis, otherwise cannot easily invest. Specially foreign invests, namely the enterprise by way and so on cash, material object, intangible asset, or by the stock, the negotiable securities and so on the negotiable securities way invests to other units, certainly must according to the international convention management, to throw the capital the capital letter, the financial resource and so on many aspects has the reliable proof. The contract must strictly check, conforms to the relevant law procedure, cuts cannot remain has the hidden danger. Third, the good investment executive program pass, achieves the investment decision-making scientific style and the democratization. The different type investment all has own characteristic, thus has the different executive program, must after the different department examination and approval, for example: Some investments, general manager individual may make the decision-making, some investments must authorize by the board of directors, but some investments must report the higher authority department to examine and approve. Fourth, good cost control, risk and income pass. The investmentgoalies must have the benefit, must make money, because must implement the investment cost control; Must have the risk consciousness, dodges the risk with every effort; The investment must have the benefit, but also must promptly recycle, guarantees invests successfully.Third, manages well the fund, guarantees the enterprise fund circulation and the security At present, many enterprises have three problems in the fund management: One is the fund is unable to make ends meet, existence fund gap; Two is the fund is diverted, is occupied; Three, is called the person the headache "the triangle debt". How solves these three problems, is in the enterprise financial control urgent matter. Certainly, first must tap new resources and reduce expenses, increases income and reduces expenses; Its secondary raises funds through the short-term and invests fills a prescription the fund -odd to lack; Third must to the fund implementation track management, achieve earmarks a fund for a specific purpose, prevented the fund is diverted and forms newly "the triangle debt".Fourth, the full display finance surveillance function, guarantees the state asset to4guarantee the value increment the perfect enterprise legal people govern the structure are important issue which the present state-owned enterprise changes the system. The enterprise must truly become in the market economy the competition main body and the responsibility power explicit legal person entity, must have to have a set the drivemechanism which adapts with it. Constructs a unity, the development, the honest management is does well the state-owned enterprise the key. From prevented corrupt considers, the enterprise must strengthen the surveillance function. Just like the traffic regulations is same, doesn’t have the red candle the restraint, and does not have the green light the freedom. Restrains in the mechanism in the enterprise, fully plays the financial surveillance role to have the specially vital significance. The financial worker must have the high sense of responsibility, regarding according to the financial system management person, do not have to dare to resist, until reports the situation to the higher authority. The state-owned enterprise's financial personnel fundamentally mention, is responsible for the state asset, but is not is responsible for some concrete general manager. But said from the government by law, also must protect the financial p ersonnel’s responsibility withindividual rights and interests, also only has this, can fully play the financial surveillance role. At present the state-owned enterprise implements under the financial manager to manage level of systems is effective. The s ubordinate enterprise’s financial person in charge by the upper level of department responsible for the work,the enterprise directly delegates, its organization relates, the wages and welfare in the previous unit, like this he can not have the extra worries to exercise the financial surveillance function.Fifth, under new situation appropriation of profit management the appropriation of profit is the enterprise basis country related stipulation and investor's resolution the assignment which carries on to the enterprise only profit. The appropriation of profit gets up the leverage in the enterprise, it to the correct processing enterprise with various aspects economical relations, transfers various aspects the enthusiasm, the promotion enterprise develops has the extremely vital significance. For many years, our country enterprise appropriation of profit as are suit of planned economy influence, in "distribution according to work" under the slogan, in the essence has the serious egalitarianism, enormously dampened populace's enthusiasm, this also is many state-owned enterprises is in the5difficult position for a long time an important reason. A factory manager, general manager wages is very few with an ordinary staff phase difference, which regardless of from on the one hand said, all is unreasonable. Had some factory managers, general manager has laboriously done for several dozens years, near arrived the retirement only then to discover oneself "did not have aching in the world", the psychology was not balanced. Few people unexpectedly take risks, violate the law knowingly, the embezzlement bribe, so-called forms "59 year old of phenomenon". Senior intellectuals, a scientific and technical worker receives the identical strong back phase difference to be also very few, this also is the appropriation of profit extremely unreasonablephenomenon. Eats the mess in the appropriation of profit is one kind of backwardness consciousness, has the very big harm. After reform and open policy, Comrade Deng Xiaoping proposed "lets part of people get rich first", its essence is breaks the appropriation of profit "the egalitarianism". Comrade Deng Xiaoping also proposed "the science and technology is the first productive forces", summoned "the respect knowledge, respects the talented person", this further reformed for the appropriation of profit has laid the rationale. At present, thescientific and technical worker may buy stock by the science and technology draws bonus, the enterprise operator implements the yearly salary system and so on, mayday is the appropriation of profit under the new situation inevitable result. The distribution according to work and the element of production will participate in the assignment to become the enterprise the main appropriation of profit form, the staff holds the stock, the operator will hold the stock to cause.6成本控制和财务控制以成本控制和财务控制为目标——财务控制是企业管理的重要组成部分,渗透到企业的各个领域、各个环节。
会计信息披露行为和资本成本【外文翻译】

外文文献翻译原文:Accounting Information, Disclosure, and the Cost of CapitalIn this paper we examine whether and how accounting information about a firm manifests in its cost of capital, despite the forces of diversification. We build a model that is consistent with the Capital Asset Pricing Model and explicitly allows for multiple securities whose cash flows are correlated. We demonstrate that the quality of accounting information can influence the cost of capital, both directly and indirectly. The direct effec t occurs because higher quality disclosures affect the firm’s assessed covariances with other firms’ cash flows, which is nondiversifiable. The indirect effect occurs because higher quality disclosures affect a firm’s real decisions, which likely changes t he firm’s ratio of the expected future cash flows to the covariance of these cash flows with the sum of all the cash flows in the market. We show that this effect can go in either direction, but also derive conditions under which an increase in information quality leads to an unambiguous decline in the cost of capital.The link between accounting information and the cost of capital of firms is one of the most fundamental issues in accounting. Standard setters frequently refer to it. For example, Arthur Levitt, the former chairman of the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), suggests that “high quality accounting standards . . . reduce capital costs” (Levitt [1998, p. 81]). Similarly, Neel Foster, a former member of the Financial Accounting Standards Boar d (FASB), claims that “More information always equates to less uncertainty, and . . . people pay more for certainty. In the context of financial information, the end result is that better disclosure results in a lower cost of capital” (Foster [2003, p. 1]). While these claims have intuitive appeal, there is surprisingly little theoretical work on the hypothesized link.In particular, it is unclear to what extent accounting information or firm disclosures reduce nondiversifiable risks in economies with multiple securities. Asset pricingmodels, such as the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), and portfolio theory emphasize the importance of distinguishing between risks that are diversifiable and those that are not. Thus, the challenge for accounting researchers is to demonstrate whether and how firms’ accounting information manifests in their cost of capital, despite the forces of diversification.This paper examines both of these questions. We define the cost of capital as the expected return on a firm’s stock. This definition is consistent with standard asset pricing models in finance (e.g., Fama and Miller [1972, p. 303]), as well as numerous studies in accounting that use discounted cash flow or abnormal earnings models to infer firms’ cost of capital (e.g.,Botosan [1997], Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan [2001]). In our model, we explicitly allow for multiple firms whose cash flows are correlated. In contrast, most analytical models in accounting examine the role of information in single-firm settings (see Verrecchia [2001] for a survey). While this literature yields many useful insights, its applicability to cost of capital issues is limited. In single-firm settings, firm-specific variance is priced because there are no alternative securities that would allow investors to diversify idiosyncratic risk.We begin with a model of a multisecurity economy that is consistent with the CAPM. We then recast the CAPM, which is expressed in terms of returns, into a more easily interpreted formulation that is expressed in terms of the expected values and covariances of future cash flows. We show that the ratio of the expected future cash flow to the covariance of the firm’s cash flow with the sum of all cash flows in the market is a key determinant of the cost of capital.Next, we add an information structure that allows us to study the effects of accounting information. We characterize firms’ accounting reports as noisy information about future cash flows, which comports well with actual reporting behavior. We demonstrate t hat accounting information influences a firm’s cost of capital in two ways: (1) direct effects—where higher quality accounting information does not affect cash flows per se, but affects the market participants’ assessments of the distribution of future cash flows; and (2) indirect effects—where higher quality accounting information affects a firm’s real decisions, which, in turn, influence itsexpected value and covariances of firm cash flows.In the first category, we show (not surprisingly) that higher quality information reduces the assessed variance of a firm’s cash flow. Analogous to the spirit of the CAPM, however, we show this effect is diversifiable in a “large economy.” We discuss what the concept of “diversification” means, and show that an econo mically sensible definition requires more than simply examining what happens when the number of securities in the economy becomes large.The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the basic model in a world of homogeneous beliefs, defines terms, and derives the determinants of the cost of capital. Sections 3 and 4 analyze the direct and indirect effects of accounting information on firms’ cost of capital, respectively. Section 5 summarizes our findings and concludes the paper. A final lingering worry I have concerns whether timely disclosure could ever be observed, let alone enforced. Would it require managers to hold press conferences at the precise moment they receive any important bit of accounting information? Such immediate disclosure seems to be necessary since Hakansson makes clear that even "very slight delay" can "render potentially valuable information untimely and therefore worthless," How could the enforcers tell when that moment occurs? Such extremely important questions would have to be answered before such a scheme could be put into practice.Moreover, we demonstrate that an increase in the quality of a firm’s disclosure about its own future cash flows has a direct effect on the assessed covariances with other firm s’ cash flows. This result builds on and extends the work on “estimation risk” in finance. In this literature, information typically arises from a historical time series of return observations. In particular, Barry and Brown [1985] and Coles, Loewenstein, and Suay [1995] compare two information environments: In one environment the same amount of information (e.g., the same number of historical time-series observations) is available for all firms in the economy, whereas in the other information environment there are more observations for one group of firms than another. They find that the betas of the “high information” securities are lower than they would be in the equal information case. They cannot unambiguously sign,however, the difference in betas for t he “low information” securities in the unequal- versus equal-information environments. Moreover, these studies do not address the question of how an individual firm’s disclosures can influence its cost of capital within an unequal information environment.Rather than restricting attention to information as historical observations of returns, our paper uses a more conventional information-economics approach in which information is modeled as a noisy signal of the realization of cash flows in the future. With this approach, we allow for more general changes in the information environment, and we are able to prove much stronger results. In particular, we show that higher quality accounting information and financial disclosures affect the assessed covariances with other firms, and this effect unambiguously moves a firm’s cost of capital closer to the risk-free rate. Moreover, this effect is not diversifiable because it is present for each of the firm’s covariance terms and hence does not disappear in “large economies.”Next, we discuss the effects of disclosure regulation on the cost of capital of firms. Based on our framework, increasing the quality of mandated disclosures should in general move the cost of capital closer to the risk-free rate for all firms in the economy. In addition to the effect of an individual firm’s disclosures, there is an externality from the disclosures of other firms, which may provide a rationale for disclosure regulation. We also argue that the magnitude of the cost of capital effect of mandated disclosure is unequal across firms. In particular, the reduction in the assessed covariances between firms and the market does not result in a decrease in the beta coefficient of each firm. After all, regardless of information quality in the economy, the average beta across firms has to be 1.0. Therefore, even though firms’ cost of capital (and the aggregate risk premium) declines with improved mandated disclosure, their beta coefficients need not.In the “indirect effect” category, we show that the quality of accounting information influences a firm’s cost of capital through its effect on a firm’s real decisions. First, we demonstrate that if better information reduces the amount of firm cash flow that managers appropriate for themselves, the improvements in disclosurenot only increase firm price, but in general also reduce a firm’s cost of capital. Second, we allow information quality to change a firm’s real decisions, for example, with respect to production or investment. In this case, information quality changes decisions, which changes the ratio of expected cash flow to nondiversifiable covariance risk and hence influences a firm’s cost of capital. We derive conditions under which an increase in information quality results in an unambiguous decrease in a firm’s cost of capital.Our paper makes several contributions. First, we extend and generalize prior work on estimation risk. We show that information quality directly influences a firm’s cost of capital and that improvements in information quality by individual firms unambiguously affect their nondiversifiable risks. This finding is important as it suggests that a firm’s beta factor is a function of its information quality and disclosures. In this sense, our study provides theoretical guidance to empirical studies that examine the link between firms’ disclosures and information quality, and their cost of capital (e.g., Botosan [1997], Botosan and Plumlee [2002], Francis et al. [2004], Ashbaugh-Skaife et al. [2005], Berger, Chen, and Li [2005], Core, Guay, and Verdi [2006]). We discuss this guidance in more detail in our conclusion. In addition, our study provides an explanation for international differences in the equity risk premium or firms’ average cost of equity capital, stemming from differences in disclosure regulation across countries (e.g., Hail and Leuz [2006]).It is important to recognize, however, that the effects of a firm’s disclosures on its cost of capital, as demonstrated by our model, are fully captured by an appropriately specified, forward-looking beta and the expected return on the market as a whole.3 Thus, our model does not provide support for an additional risk factor capturing “information risk.”One way to justify the inclusion of additional information variables in a cost of capital model is to note that empirical proxies for beta, which for instance are based on historical data alone, may not capture all information effects. In this case, however, it is incumbent on researchers to specify a “measurement error” model or, at least, provide a careful justification for the inclusion of information variables, and their functional form, in the empirical specification. Based on ourresults, however, the most natural way to empirically analyze the link between information quality and the cost of capital is via the beta factor.A second contribution of our paper is that it provides a direct link between information quality and the cost of capital, without reference to market liquidity. Prior work suggests an indirect lin k between disclosure and firms’ cost of capital based on market liquidity and adverse selection in secondary markets (e.g., Diamond and Verrecchia [1991], Baiman and Verrecchia [1996], Easley and O’Hara [2004]). These studies, however, analyze settings with a single firm (or settings where cash flows across firms are uncorrelated). Thus, it is unclear whether the effects demonstrated in these studies survive the forces of diversification and extend to more general multisecurity settings. We emphasize, however, that we do not dispute the possible role of market liquidity for firms’ cost of capital, as several empirical studies suggest (e.g., Amihud and Mendelson [1986], Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam [2001], Easley, Hvidkjaer, and O’Hara [2002], Pastor and S tambaugh [2003]). Our paper focuses on an alternative, and possibly more direct, explanation as to how information quality influences nondiversifiable risks.Finally, our paper contributes to the literature by showing that information quality has indirec t effects on real decisions, which in turn manifest in firms’ cost of capital. In this sense, our study relates to work on real effects of accounting information (e.g., Kanodia et al. [2000], Kanodia, Sapra, and Venugopalan [2004]). These studies, however, do not analyze the effects on firms’ cost of capital or nondiversifiable risks.Resource:Richard Lambert, Chirstian Leuz, and Robert E Verrecchia.Accounting Information, Disclosure, and the Cost of Capital. Journal of Accounting Research, 2007: p385-420.译文:会计信息披露行为和资本成本在本文中,我们探讨在多元化经营,消费者对企业会计信息是如何体现在它的资本成本。
公司理财 lecture 11 资本成本

例题
某公司需筹措100万元资金,40%发行债券,10%发行 优先股,其余为普通股。已知债券为面值发行,无 发行成本,票息利率为8%,债券面值为1000元,期限 为10年。优先股发行价格为12元/股,股息为1.2 元/股。又知该公司的β值为1.5,市场平均风险 溢价为6%,所的税税率为33%,无风险报酬为8 %。求该公司筹措这一笔资金的加权平均的资本 成本为多少?
假设资本i的资本成本为Ri , 在总资本构成中的权重为Wi : WACC = ∑ Wi Ri
i =1 n
如果A = D + P + E : D P E WACC ′ = × RD × (1 − TC ) + × RP + × RE A A A
2011年3月20日星期日 年 月 日星期日 Yixia Wang CM,HUST 10
2011年3月20日星期日 年 月 日星期日 Yixia Wang CM,HUST 3
普通股资本成本的计算
方法一:戈登公式 D1 RE = + g P0 方法二: CAPM RE = R f + RM − R f )β (
E
2011年3月20日星期日 年 月 日星期日 Yixia Wang
CM,HUST
2011年3月20日星期日 年 月 日星期日 Yixia Wang
CM,HUST
11
例题(续)
RD = 8% 1.2 RP = ×100 =10% % 12 RE = 8%+ 6%×1.5 =17% WACC= 8%× 40%×(1− 33%)+10%×10%+ 50%×17% =11.644 %
CM,HUST
2
资本成本
公司使用资本所付出的代价, 公司使用资本所付出的代价,通常用相对成本来 表示。 表示。 站在投资者的角度,就是投资者期望得到的报酬。 站在投资者的角度,就是投资者期望得到的报酬。 资本成本是投资与融资相沟通的桥梁。 资本成本是投资与融资相沟通的桥梁。 由融资结构所决定的资本成本是公司投资项目投 资决策时所采用的贴现率及IRR的判断 标准。 资决策时所采用的贴现率及 的判断 标准。 资本成本衡量方式: 资本成本衡量方式:加权平均资本成本 (Weighted Average Cost of Capital ,WACC) 投资项目的贴现率=投资项目的期望收益率期= 投资项目的贴现率=投资项目的期望收益率期= 资本成本
2021 年注册会计师《财务成本管理英语》资本成本与资本结构

第01讲资本成本与资本结构Part 1 核心词汇Part 2 重难点讲解—资本成本(一)普通股成本的估计(二)优先股成本的估计(三)债务成本的估计特殊债券的成本估计(四)加权平均资本成本(WACC)【例题·2017年考题】甲公司为扩大产能,拟平价发行分离型附认股权证债券进行筹资,方案如下:债券每份面值1000元,期限5年,票面利率5%。
每年付息一次。
同时附送20份认股权证。
认股权证在债券发行3年后到期,到期时每份认股权证可按11元的价格购买1股甲公司普通股股票。
甲公司目前有发行在外的普通债券,5年后到期,每份面值1000元,票面利率6%,每年付息一次,每份市价1020元(刚刚支付过最近一期利息)公司目前处于生产的稳定增长期,可持续增长率5%。
普通股每股市价10元。
公司企业所得税率25%。
要求:(1)计算公司普通债券的税前资本成本。
(2)计算分离型附认股权证债券的税前资本成本。
(3)判断筹资方案是否合理,并说明理由,如果不合理,给出调整建议。
『正确答案』(1)令税前资本成本为iAssume Pre-tax cost of capital is i1020=1000×6%×(P/A,i,5)+1000×(P/F,i,5)当i=4%时,等式右边=1000×6%×4.4518+1000×0.8219=1089When i equals 4%, the right side of the equation=1000×6%×4.4518+1000×0.8219=1089 continuing当i=6%时, 等式右边=1000×6%×4.2124+1000×0.7473=1000When i equals 6%, the right side of the equation =1000×6%×4.2124+1000×0.7473=1000 列出等式:Write out the equality :(i-4%)/(6%-4%)=(1020-1089)/(1000-1089)i=4%+[(1020-1089)/(1000-1089)]×(6%-4%)=5.55%(2)第3年末行权支出=11×20=220(元)Exercise expenditure at the end of the third year=11×20=220(yuan )取得股票的市价=10×(F/P,5%,3)×20=231.525(元)The market price of the acquired stock=10×(F/P,5%,3)×20=231.525(yuan )行权现金净流入=231.5325-220=11.525(元)Net cash inflow when option are exercised= 231.5325-220=11.525(yuan )令税前资本成本为k,Assume Pre-tax cost of capital is K1000=1000×5%×(P/A,K,5)+11.525×(P/F,K,3)+1000×(P/F,K,5)K=5%时,等式右边=1000×5%×4.3295+11.525×0.8638+1000×0.7835=1009.93(元)When K equals 5%, the right side of the equation =……K=6%时,等式右边=1000×5%×4.2124+11.525×0.8396+1000×0.7473=967.60(元)When K equals 6%, the right side of the equation =……(K-5%)/(6%-5%)=(1000-1009.93)/(967.60-1009.93)K=5%+[(1000-1009.93)/(967.60-1009.93)]×(6%-5%)=5.23%(3)该筹资方案不合理,原因是附认股权证债券的税前资本成本低于普通债券的税前资本成本。
会计信息披露行为和资本成本【外文翻译】

外文文献翻译原文:Accounting Information, Disclosure, and the Cost of CapitalIn this paper we examine whether and how accounting information about a firm manifests in its cost of capital, despite the forces of diversification. We build a model that is consistent with the Capital Asset Pricing Model and explicitly allows for multiple securities whose cash flows are correlated. We demonstrate that the quality of accounting information can influence the cost of capital, both directly and indirectly. The direct effec t occurs because higher quality disclosures affect the firm’s assessed covariances with other firms’ cash flows, which is nondiversifiable. The indirect effect occurs because higher quality disclosures affect a firm’s real decisions, which likely changes t he firm’s ratio of the expected future cash flows to the covariance of these cash flows with the sum of all the cash flows in the market. We show that this effect can go in either direction, but also derive conditions under which an increase in information quality leads to an unambiguous decline in the cost of capital.The link between accounting information and the cost of capital of firms is one of the most fundamental issues in accounting. Standard setters frequently refer to it. For example, Arthur Levitt, the former chairman of the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), suggests that “high quality accounting standards . . . reduce capital costs” (Levitt [1998, p. 81]). Similarly, Neel Foster, a former member of the Financial Accounting Standards Boar d (FASB), claims that “More information always equates to less uncertainty, and . . . people pay more for certainty. In the context of financial information, the end result is that better disclosure results in a lower cost of capital” (Foster [2003, p. 1]). While these claims have intuitive appeal, there is surprisingly little theoretical work on the hypothesized link.In particular, it is unclear to what extent accounting information or firm disclosures reduce nondiversifiable risks in economies with multiple securities. Asset pricingmodels, such as the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), and portfolio theory emphasize the importance of distinguishing between risks that are diversifiable and those that are not. Thus, the challenge for accounting researchers is to demonstrate whether and how firms’ accounting information manifests in their cost of capital, despite the forces of diversification.This paper examines both of these questions. We define the cost of capital as the expected return on a firm’s stock. This definition is consistent with standard asset pricing models in finance (e.g., Fama and Miller [1972, p. 303]), as well as numerous studies in accounting that use discounted cash flow or abnormal earnings models to infer firms’ cost of capital (e.g.,Botosan [1997], Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan [2001]). In our model, we explicitly allow for multiple firms whose cash flows are correlated. In contrast, most analytical models in accounting examine the role of information in single-firm settings (see Verrecchia [2001] for a survey). While this literature yields many useful insights, its applicability to cost of capital issues is limited. In single-firm settings, firm-specific variance is priced because there are no alternative securities that would allow investors to diversify idiosyncratic risk.We begin with a model of a multisecurity economy that is consistent with the CAPM. We then recast the CAPM, which is expressed in terms of returns, into a more easily interpreted formulation that is expressed in terms of the expected values and covariances of future cash flows. We show that the ratio of the expected future cash flow to the covariance of the firm’s cash flow with the sum of all cash flows in the market is a key determinant of the cost of capital.Next, we add an information structure that allows us to study the effects of accounting information. We characterize firms’ accounting reports as noisy information about future cash flows, which comports well with actual reporting behavior. We demonstrate t hat accounting information influences a firm’s cost of capital in two ways: (1) direct effects—where higher quality accounting information does not affect cash flows per se, but affects the market participants’ assessments of the distribution of future cash flows; and (2) indirect effects—where higher quality accounting information affects a firm’s real decisions, which, in turn, influence itsexpected value and covariances of firm cash flows.In the first category, we show (not surprisingly) that higher quality information reduces the assessed variance of a firm’s cash flow. Analogous to the spirit of the CAPM, however, we show this effect is diversifiable in a “large economy.” We discuss what the concept of “diversification” means, and show that an econo mically sensible definition requires more than simply examining what happens when the number of securities in the economy becomes large.The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the basic model in a world of homogeneous beliefs, defines terms, and derives the determinants of the cost of capital. Sections 3 and 4 analyze the direct and indirect effects of accounting information on firms’ cost of capital, respectively. Section 5 summarizes our findings and concludes the paper. A final lingering worry I have concerns whether timely disclosure could ever be observed, let alone enforced. Would it require managers to hold press conferences at the precise moment they receive any important bit of accounting information? Such immediate disclosure seems to be necessary since Hakansson makes clear that even "very slight delay" can "render potentially valuable information untimely and therefore worthless," How could the enforcers tell when that moment occurs? Such extremely important questions would have to be answered before such a scheme could be put into practice.Moreover, we demonstrate that an increase in the quality of a firm’s disclosure about its own future cash flows has a direct effect on the assessed covariances with other firm s’ cash flows. This result builds on and extends the work on “estimation risk” in finance. In this literature, information typically arises from a historical time series of return observations. In particular, Barry and Brown [1985] and Coles, Loewenstein, and Suay [1995] compare two information environments: In one environment the same amount of information (e.g., the same number of historical time-series observations) is available for all firms in the economy, whereas in the other information environment there are more observations for one group of firms than another. They find that the betas of the “high information” securities are lower than they would be in the equal information case. They cannot unambiguously sign,however, the difference in betas for t he “low information” securities in the unequal- versus equal-information environments. Moreover, these studies do not address the question of how an individual firm’s disclosures can influence its cost of capital within an unequal information environment.Rather than restricting attention to information as historical observations of returns, our paper uses a more conventional information-economics approach in which information is modeled as a noisy signal of the realization of cash flows in the future. With this approach, we allow for more general changes in the information environment, and we are able to prove much stronger results. In particular, we show that higher quality accounting information and financial disclosures affect the assessed covariances with other firms, and this effect unambiguously moves a firm’s cost of capital closer to the risk-free rate. Moreover, this effect is not diversifiable because it is present for each of the firm’s covariance terms and hence does not disappear in “large economies.”Next, we discuss the effects of disclosure regulation on the cost of capital of firms. Based on our framework, increasing the quality of mandated disclosures should in general move the cost of capital closer to the risk-free rate for all firms in the economy. In addition to the effect of an individual firm’s disclosures, there is an externality from the disclosures of other firms, which may provide a rationale for disclosure regulation. We also argue that the magnitude of the cost of capital effect of mandated disclosure is unequal across firms. In particular, the reduction in the assessed covariances between firms and the market does not result in a decrease in the beta coefficient of each firm. After all, regardless of information quality in the economy, the average beta across firms has to be 1.0. Therefore, even though firms’ cost of capital (and the aggregate risk premium) declines with improved mandated disclosure, their beta coefficients need not.In the “indirect effect” category, we show that the quality of accounting information influences a firm’s cost of capital through its effect on a firm’s real decisions. First, we demonstrate that if better information reduces the amount of firm cash flow that managers appropriate for themselves, the improvements in disclosurenot only increase firm price, but in general also reduce a firm’s cost of capital. Second, we allow information quality to change a firm’s real decisions, for example, with respect to production or investment. In this case, information quality changes decisions, which changes the ratio of expected cash flow to nondiversifiable covariance risk and hence influences a firm’s cost of capital. We derive conditions under which an increase in information quality results in an unambiguous decrease in a firm’s cost of capital.Our paper makes several contributions. First, we extend and generalize prior work on estimation risk. We show that information quality directly influences a firm’s cost of capital and that improvements in information quality by individual firms unambiguously affect their nondiversifiable risks. This finding is important as it suggests that a firm’s beta factor is a function of its information quality and disclosures. In this sense, our study provides theoretical guidance to empirical studies that examine the link between firms’ disclosures and information quality, and their cost of capital (e.g., Botosan [1997], Botosan and Plumlee [2002], Francis et al. [2004], Ashbaugh-Skaife et al. [2005], Berger, Chen, and Li [2005], Core, Guay, and Verdi [2006]). We discuss this guidance in more detail in our conclusion. In addition, our study provides an explanation for international differences in the equity risk premium or firms’ average cost of equity capital, stemming from differences in disclosure regulation across countries (e.g., Hail and Leuz [2006]).It is important to recognize, however, that the effects of a firm’s disclosures on its cost of capital, as demonstrated by our model, are fully captured by an appropriately specified, forward-looking beta and the expected return on the market as a whole.3 Thus, our model does not provide support for an additional risk factor capturing “information risk.”One way to justify the inclusion of additional information variables in a cost of capital model is to note that empirical proxies for beta, which for instance are based on historical data alone, may not capture all information effects. In this case, however, it is incumbent on researchers to specify a “measurement error” model or, at least, provide a careful justification for the inclusion of information variables, and their functional form, in the empirical specification. Based on ourresults, however, the most natural way to empirically analyze the link between information quality and the cost of capital is via the beta factor.A second contribution of our paper is that it provides a direct link between information quality and the cost of capital, without reference to market liquidity. Prior work suggests an indirect lin k between disclosure and firms’ cost of capital based on market liquidity and adverse selection in secondary markets (e.g., Diamond and Verrecchia [1991], Baiman and Verrecchia [1996], Easley and O’Hara [2004]). These studies, however, analyze settings with a single firm (or settings where cash flows across firms are uncorrelated). Thus, it is unclear whether the effects demonstrated in these studies survive the forces of diversification and extend to more general multisecurity settings. We emphasize, however, that we do not dispute the possible role of market liquidity for firms’ cost of capital, as several empirical studies suggest (e.g., Amihud and Mendelson [1986], Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam [2001], Easley, Hvidkjaer, and O’Hara [2002], Pastor and S tambaugh [2003]). Our paper focuses on an alternative, and possibly more direct, explanation as to how information quality influences nondiversifiable risks.Finally, our paper contributes to the literature by showing that information quality has indirec t effects on real decisions, which in turn manifest in firms’ cost of capital. In this sense, our study relates to work on real effects of accounting information (e.g., Kanodia et al. [2000], Kanodia, Sapra, and Venugopalan [2004]). These studies, however, do not analyze the effects on firms’ cost of capital or nondiversifiable risks.Resource:Richard Lambert, Chirstian Leuz, and Robert E Verrecchia.Accounting Information, Disclosure, and the Cost of Capital. Journal of Accounting Research, 2007: p385-420.译文:会计信息披露行为和资本成本在本文中,我们探讨在多元化经营,消费者对企业会计信息是如何体现在它的资本成本。
第九章 资本成本 公司理财
K K ( 1 T Bt B c)
( 1 )
I ( 1 T ) M t c P ( 1 f ) B t t t 1 ( 1 K ) ( 1 K ) B B
n
( 2 )
Pb — 债券的价格 f — 筹资费率 n — 债券的期限 I — 债券年利息 M —债券的面值 Tc — 所得税税率 Kb —债券的税前成本率 Kbt — 债券的税后成本率
2
66 )t
t 1 ( 1 Kbt
1000 ( 1 Kbt )2
试 错 法 求 出Kbt 6.6%
当考虑税时,筹资成本降低。
【例】假设BBC公司资产负债表中长期负债账面价值为3 810万元(每张债券面值为1 000元),息票率为8%,期限6年, 每半年付息一次,假设同等期限政府债券收益率为7%,考 虑风险因素,投资者对公司债券要求的收益率为9%,则半 年为4.4%[ (1.09)1/2-1]。假设公司所得税税率为40%,税前 筹资费率为发行额的3%。
若公司某项投资所获得的收益率等于公司的资本成本, 则该公司普 通股的价值将不会由于该项投资而改变, 即公司的价值没有变化; 若公司某项投资的收益率高于 ( 低于 ) 公司的资金成本,则该公司 普通股的价值由于该项投资而发生了改变,即公司的价值产生了 增值(减值)。 资本成本应该是公司新资本投资所要求的最低收益率。
9.1 资本成本的概念
Concept about Capital Cost
资本成分 资本: 企业购置资产和支持运营所需流动资产而筹集的资金。通
常它表现为资产负债表的右栏各个科目。即长、短期负债、优先 股和普通股权益,它们构成了企业的全部资本。 一般来说,短期负债不列入资本预算的资本成分中。因为一些短 期负债是无息的,如:应付帐款、应交税金、应付工资等。而企 业购置资产,只需筹集总资产与无息负债的差额资金就可以了。
第四章 资本成本理论
D D P0 KC KC P0
2015-5-3
19
(2)股利折现模型
如果企业采用固定股利增长的股利政策:
预期第一年股利为D1,固定股利增长率为g D1 D1 (1 g ) D1 (1 g ) 2 P0 2 3 1 KC (1 KC ) (1 KC ) D1 1 g n ( )[1 ( ) ] 1 KC 1 KC 1 g 1 ( ) 1 KC D1 D1 Kc g KC g P0
I1 (1 t ) i1 (1 t ) K1 P1 (1 f1 ) 1 f1 式中: K1——银行借款资本成本; I1 ——银行借款年利息; P1——银行借款筹资总额; t ——所得税税率; f1——银行借款筹资费率; i1——银行借款年利息率。
13
【例1】M公司欲从银行取得长期借款1000万元,年利率 5%,手续费率0.1%,期限3年,每年结息一次,到期一次 还本,公司所得税率为25%。这批借款的资本成本是多少?
式中 : K5 ——留存收益资本成本,其余同普通股。
D1 K5 G P4
25
(三)综合资本成本
综合资金成本就是指一个企业各种不同筹 资方式总的平均资金成本,它是以各种资本所 占的比重为权数,对各种资金成本进行加权平 均计算出来的,所以又称加权平均资金成本。 其计算公式为:
K W KjWj
j 1
26
n
(三) 综合资本成本
例5: 某企业共有资金1 000万元,其中长期债 券为400万元,优先股为100万元,普通股为 300万元,留存收益为200万元。各种来源资 金的资金成本分别为:7%、10%、14%、 12%。要求计算该企业综合资金成本。 解 Kw =7%×40%+10%×10%+ 14%×30%+12%×20%=10.4%
资本成本理论分析及在财务中的应用研究
资本成本理论分析及在财务中的应用研究概述资本成本是公司投资项目的成本,通常用于衡量公司资本结构的费用或者是最小要求回报率(MARR)。
在这篇文章中,我们将讨论资本成本的理论分析和在财务中的应用研究。
资本成本理论分析资本成本是衡量公司风险的重要指标,它包括两部分:债务成本和股权成本。
债务成本是公司借款的成本,而股权成本是股东投资的回报率,可以反映出股东对公司投资的期望收益。
债务成本的计算方法债务成本往往被称为债务利率,通常由公司向金融机构借款的成本。
债务成本的计算方法如下:债务成本 = 借贷利率 x (1 - 税率)其中,借贷利率是公司向金融机构借款的利率,税率是公司实际缴纳的税率。
因为公司缴纳的利息支出可以减少公司所需缴纳的所得税金额,所以公司实际支付的债务成本要减去税率所占的部分。
股权成本的计算方法股权成本是股东对公司期望的回报率,它可以反映出公司所承担的风险程度。
股权成本的计算方法有两种:股权成本模型和资本资产定价模型(CAPM)。
股权成本模型股权成本模型是在考虑公司股票价格波动因素的基础上计算股权成本的方法。
股权成本模型可以通过以下公式来计算:股权成本 = (股息/股票价格) + 通货膨胀率其中,股息是公司股票每年支付的股息,股票价格是公司股票的市场价格,通货膨胀率是通货膨胀的预期增长率。
资本资产定价模型资本资产定价模型是一种计算若干个风险投资项目的成本方法,它基于两个假设:风险投资的回报率应当高于非风险投资的回报率,资产组合应当经过有效的分散措施以降低风险。
资本资产定价模型可以通过以下公式来计算:股权成本 = 无风险利率+ β x (市场回报率 - 无风险利率)其中,无风险利率是指非风险投资的回报率,β是公司股票相对于市场股票的波动性系数,市场回报率是市场股票的平均回报率。
资本资产定价模型的优点是它能够考虑市场风险和个别公司特征的影响,因此得出的成本数据更加精准。
资本成本在财务中的应用研究资本成本在财务管理中有广泛的应用,包括权益融资决策、资金预算、剩余收益分析和合理投资决策等。
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
外文翻译原文The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and Theory of InvestmentMaterial Source: http://ww.jstor.or Author: Franco Modigliani; Merton H. MillerA. Capital Structure and Investment PolicyOn the basis of our propositions with respect to cost of capital and financial structure (and for the moment neglecting tans), we can coercive the following simple rule for optimal investment policy by the firm:Proposition III. If a firm in class is acting in the best interest of the stockholders at the time of the decision, it will exploit an investment opportunity if and only if the rate of return on the investment, say , is as large as or larger than . That is, the cut-off point for investment in the firm will in all cases be and will be completely unaffected by the type of security used to finance the investment. Equivalently, we may say that regardless of the financing used, the marginal cost of capital to a firm is equal to the average cost of capital, which is in turn equal to the capitalization rate for an unlevered stream in the class to which the firm belongs.To establish this result we will consider the three major financing alternatives open to the firm-bonds, retained earnings, and common stock issues-and show that in each case an investment is worth undertaking if, and only if,.Consider first the case of an investment financed by the sale of bonds. We know from Proposition I that the market value of the firm before the investment was undertaken was:(20)And that the value of the common stock was:(21)If now the firm borrows I dollars to finance an investment yielding its market value will become:(22)And the value of its common stock will be:(23)Or using equation 21,(24)HenceTo illustrate, suppose the capitalization rate for uncertain streams in the class is 10 per cent and the rate of interest is 4 per cent. Then if a given company had an expected income of 1,000 and if it were financed entirely by common stock we know from Proposition I that the market value of its stock would be 10,000. Assume now that the managers of the firm discover an investment opportunity which will require an outlay of 100 and which is expected to yield 8 per cent. At first sight this might appear to be a profitable opportunity since the expected return is double the interest cost. If, however, the management borrows the necessary 100 at 4 per cent, the total expected income of the company rises to 1,008 and the market value of the firm to 10,080. But the firm now will have 100 of bonds in its capital structure so that, paradoxically, the market value of the stock must actually be reduced from 10,000 to 9,980 as a consequence of this apparently profitable investment. Or, to put it another way, the gains from being able to tap cheap, borrowed funds are more than offset for the stockholders by the market's discounting of the stock for the added leverage assumed.Consider next the case of retained earnings. Suppose that in the course of its operations the firm acquired I dollars of cash (without impairing the earning power of its assets). If the cash is distributed as a dividend to the stockholders their wealth , after the distribution will be:(25)Where represents the expected return from the assets exclusive of I in question. If however the funds are retained by the company and used to finance newassets whose expected rate of return is , then the stockholders' wealth would become:(26)Clearly as so that an investment financed by retained earnings raises the net worth of the owners if and only if .Consider finally, the case of common-stock financing. Let Po denote the current market price per share of stock and assume, for simplicity, that this price reflects currently expected earnings only, that is, it does not reflect any future increase in earnings as a result of the investment under consideration. Then if N is the original number of shares, the price per share is:(27)And the number of new shares, M, needed to finance an investment of I dollars is given by:(28)As a result of the investment the market value of the stock becomes:And the price per share:(29)Since by equation (28), I= M Po, we can add M Po and subtract from the quantity in bracket, obtaining:(30)and only if.Thus an investment financed by common stock is advantageous to the current stockholders if and only if its yield exceeds the capitalization rate .Once again a numerical example may help to illustrate the result and make it clear why the relevant cut-off rate is and not the current yield on common stock,i.e. Suppose that is 10 per cent, r is 4 per cent, that the original expected income of our company is 1,000 and that management has the opportunity of investing 100 having an expected yield of 12 per cent. If the original capital structure is 50 per cent debt and 50 per cent equity, and 1,000 shares of stock are initially outstanding, then, by Proposition I, the market value of the common stock must be 5,000 or 5 per share. Furthermore, since the interest bill is .045,000 =200, the yield on common stock is 800/5,000=16 per cent. It may then appear that financing the additional investment of 100 by issuing 20 shares to outsiders at 5 per share would dilute the equity of the original owners since the 100 promises to yield 12 per cent whereas the common stock is currently yielding 16 per cent. Actually, however, the income of the company would rise to 1,012; the value of the firm to 10,120; and the value of the common stock to 5,120. Since there are now 1,020 shares, each would be worth 5.02 and the wealth of the original stockholders would thus have been increased. What has happened is that the dilution in expected earnings per share (from .80 to .796) has been more than offset, in its effect upon the market price of the shares, by the decrease in leverage.Our conclusion is, once again, at variance with conventional views, so much so as to be easily misinterpreted. Read hastily, Proposition III seems to imply, that the capital structure of a firm is a matter of indifference; and that, consequently, one of the core problems of corporate finance-the problem of the optimal capital structure for a firm-is no problem at all. It may be helpful, therefore, to clear up such possible misunderstandings.B. Proposition III and Financial Planning by FirmsMisinterpretation of the scope of Proposition III can be avoided by remembering that this Proposition tells us only that the type of instrument used to finance an investment is irrelevant to the question of whether or not the investment is worth while. This does not mean that the owners (or the managers) have no grounds whatever for preferring one financing plan to another; or that there are no other policy or technical issues in finance at the level of the firm.That grounds for preferring one type of financial structure to another will still exist within the framework of our model can readily be seen for the case of common-stock financing. In general, except for something like a widely publicized oil-strike, we would expect the market to place very heavy weight on current and recent past earnings in forming expectations as to future returns. Hence, if the owners of a firm discovered a major investment opportunity which they feltwould yield much more than ,they might well prefer not to finance it via common stock at the then ruling price, because this price may fail to capitalize the new venture. A better course would be a pre-emptive issue of stock (and in this connection it should be remembered that stockholders are free to borrow and buy). Another possibility would be to finance the project initially with debt. Once the project had reflected itself in increased actual earnings, the debt could be retired either with a11 equity issue at much better prices or through retained earnings. Still another possibility along the same lines might be to combine the two steps by means of a convertible debenture or preferred stock, perhaps with a progressively declining conversion rate. Even such a double-stage financing plan may possibly be regarded as yielding too large a share to outsiders since the new stockholders are, in effect, being given an crest in any similar opportunities the firm may discover in the future. If there is a reasonable prospect that even larger opportunities may arise in the near future and if there is some danger that borrowing now would preclude more borrowing later, the owners might find their interests best protected by splitting off the current opportunity into a separate subsidiary with independent financing. Clearly the problems involved in making the crucial estimates and in planning the optimal financial strategy are by no means trivial, even though they should have no bearing on the basic decision to invest (as long as ) .Another reason why the alternatives in financial plans may not be matter of indifference arises from the fact that managers are concerned with more than simply furthering the interest of the owners. Such other objectives of the management-which need not be necessarily in conflict with those of the owners-are much more likely to be served by some types of financing arrangements than others. In many forms of borrowing agreements, for example, creditors are able to stipulate terms which the current management may regard as infringing on its prerogatives or restricting its freedom to maneuver. The creditors might even be able to insist on having a direct voice in the formation of policy. To the extent, therefore, that financial policies have these implications for the management of the firm, something like the utility approach described in the introductory section becomes relevant to financial (as opposed to investment) decision-making. It is, however, the utility functions of the managers per se and not of the owners that are now involved.In summary, many of the specific considerations which bulk so large in traditional discussions of corporate finance can readily be superimposed on our simple framework without forcing any drastic (and certainly no systematic)alteration of the conclusion which is our principal concern, namely that for investment decisions, the marginal cost of capital isC. The Effect of the Corporate Income Tax on Investment DecisionsIn Section I it was shown that when an disintegrated corporate income tax is introduced, the original version of our Proposition I,Must be rewritten as:(11)Throughout Section I we found it convenient to refer to as the cost of capital. The appropriate measure of the cost of capital relevant to investment decisions, however, is the ratio of the expected return before taxes to the market value, i.e. , . From (11) above we find:(31)Which shows that the cost of capital now depends on the debt ratio, decreasing, as D/V rises, at the constant rate . Thus, with a corporate income tax under which interest is a deductible expense, gains can accrue to stockholders from having debt in the capital structure, even when capital markets are perfect. The gains however are small, as can be seen from (31), and as will be shown more explicitly below.From (31) we can develop the tax-adjusted counterpart of Proposition III by interpreting the term D/V in that equation as the proportion of debt used in any additional financing of V dollars. For example, in the case where the financing is entirely by new common stock, D=0 and the required rate of return S on a venture so financed becomes:(32)For the other extreme of pure debt financing D= V and the required rate of return, D, becomes:(33)For investments financed out of retained earnings, the problem of defining the required rate of return is more difficult since it involves a comparison of the tax consequences to the individual stockholder of receiving a dividend versus having a capital gain. Depending on the time of realization, a capital gain produced by retained earnings may be taxed either at ordinary income tax rates,50 per cent of these rates, 25 per cent, or zero, if held till death. The rate on any dividends received in the event of a distribution will also be a variable depending on the amount of other income received by the stockholder, and with the added complications introduced by the current dividend-credit provisions. If we assume that the managers proceed on the basis of reasonable estimates as to the average values of the relevant tax rates for the owners, then the required return for retained earnings R can be shown to be:(34)Where the assumed rate of personal income tax on dividends and is the assumed rate of tax on capital gains.A numerical illustration may perhaps be helpful in clarifying the relationship between these required rates of return. If we take the following round numbers as representative order-of-magnitude values under present conditions: an after-tax capitalization rate of 10 per cent, a rate of interest on bonds of 4 per cent, a corporate tax rate of 50 per cent, a marginal personal income tax rate on dividends of 40 per cent (corresponding to an income of about $25,000 on a joint return), and a capital gains rate of 20 per cent (one-half the marginal rate on dividends), then the required rates of return would be: (1) 20 per cent for investments financed entirely by issuance of new common shares; (2) 16 per cent for investments financed entirely by new debt; and (3) 15 per cent for investments financed wholly from internal funds.These results would seem to have considerable significance for current discussions of the effect of the corporate income tax on financial policy and on investment. Although we cannot explore the implications of the results in any detail here, we should at least like to call attention to the remarkably small difference between the "cost" of equity funds and debt funds. With the numerical valuesassumed, equity money turned out to be only 25 per cent more expensive than debt money, rather than something on the order of 5 times as expensive as is commonly supposed to be the case. The reason for the wide difference is that the traditional view starts from the position that debt funds are several times cheaper than equity funds even in the absence of taxes, with taxes serving simply to magnify the cost ratio in proportion to the corporate rate. By contrast, in our model in which the repercussions of debt financing on the value of shares are taken into account, the only difference in cost is that due to the tax effect, and its magnitude is simply the tax on the "grossed up" interest payment. Not only is this magnitude likely to be small but our analysis yields the further paradoxical implication that the stockholders' gain from, and hence incentive to use, debt financing is actually smaller the lower the rate of interest. In the extreme case where the firm could borrow for practically nothing, the advantage of debt financing would also be practically nothing.译文资本成本,公司财务和投资理论资料来源: / 作者:莫迪格利尼和米勒A 资本结构和投资政策在我们假设的基础上关于资本成本和财务结构,我们可以得出以下简单的关于企业最优投资政策的规律:命题Ⅲ:如果一个属于k 层级的企业在做决策的时候总是在股票持有者认为的最佳利率的行动,那么他将开发一个投资机会仅且仅当投资的期望回收利率*ρ大于或者等于k ρ时。