战略和企业家
企业家与品牌战略

、
充 分认 识 品牌 价值
品牌 特 别 是 驰 名 商标 .一 方 面 .能 为企 业带 来 巨大 的 经 济
效 益 ;另一 方 面 .也 是企 业 经 济 实力 的 象征 。一位 经 济 学 家说 过 , 业 家 应 当 引 以 为戒 。
一
个 国 家或 地 区拥 有 商标 的数 量 .特 别 是 拥 有 驰 名 商 标 的数 量 . 标 志 着这 个 国 家 或地 区 商 品经 济 发 展 的 程 度 和 经 济 实 力 。 商 品的注 册 商 标属 知 识产 权 .一 经 问世 即 成 为一 种价 值 符 号 .
知 识 运 用 到 市 场 竞 争 中去 ,取 得 良好 的效 果 。
第 一 阶段 是 创 造 名 牌 .围 绕 这项 工作 ,要 重 视 市 场调 研 .选
量 是 构成 名牌 的核 心 ,离 开 了质 量 . 品牌 难 以成 为名 牌 .没 有质
力 ,但 更重 要 的 是 他们 必 须 能 够 整 合 这些 知识 ,并 将 这 些 整 合 的 准 突破 口 。企 业 的 产 品 首 先必 须 适 销 对路 ;要 狠 抓 产 品 质 量 .质 企 业 竞争 归根 到 底 是 产 品适 应 市 场 需 求 度 的竞 争 , 尤 其 现代 量 的 品牌 始 终 是 不 可 能长 久 的 ;要 借 助 于有 效 的产 品 宣 传 和售 后 市 场竞 争 .那 么 生 产什 么样 的产 品 才 能使 企 业 立 于 不败 之地 ,恐 服 务 ,产 品宣 传 是使 消 费者 由认 识 过 渡到 了解 的 必 经 阶段 ,售 后 怕 离 不 开企 业 家 的 思维 与决 策 。 所 以 ,企 业 家 的思 维 方 式越 来 越 服 务则 是 让 消 费者 信赖 产 品 的保 证 。 我 国现 在 的一 些 企 业对 产 品 同 企 业 的 经 营 成 果 直 接 挂 起 钩 来 .换 句 话 说 ,思 维 就 是 财 富 。 美 国 著名 企 业 家卡 内基 也 说 过 类似 的 名言 .思 维致 富 。 强调
企业家精神与战略管理

企业家精神与战略管理自古以来,商业就是人类最为重要的经济活动之一。
尤其是在现代社会,企业的作用越来越重要。
企业家作为企业的最重要的元素之一,其创新能力、责任感和社会影响力也不断得到了提升。
但是企业家只有靠一腔热血是远远不够的,也需要有效的战略管理来使企业持续成长。
这就需要企业家拥有好的战略管理思想和技能。
企业家精神对于发展壮大企业非常重要。
企业家精神具有创新性、开拓性、坚韧性等特点。
在企业的成长过程中,应该不断推崇企业家精神的价值,进一步培养和激发企业家的精神。
同时,在企业家创业的时候,也应该对其进行必要的教育指导,使其更好地发挥企业家精神,把事业做大做强。
企业家们必须具备厚积薄发的能力,这是企业家精神的表现。
创业者是在持续的学习和实践中,积累经验,锻炼自己,等待机遇的到来。
而企业家精神的开发不仅能够使企业家获得能力,更能够让企业实现持续的良性发展。
而战略管理则是企业家引领企业不断前进的重要工具。
战略是企业成功的关键,决定一个企业未来的发展路径和成败。
战略管理就是企业高层管理人员制定、实施和监督全面战略规划的综合管理体系。
其目标是为企业创造增长和持续发展的机会。
企业家可以通过战略管理来把握竞争,进行客观分析和明智决策。
通过市场调查、目标客户的分析、产品的推广等方式,企业家可以更好地把握企业的核心利益点。
同时,企业家也需要在战略管理中学会如何把握市场的变化,提前预测变化的趋势并做好应对准备。
战略管理也是企业社会责任的重要体现。
对于大多数企业家来说,企业责任感和社会责任感都非常重要。
在战略规划过程中需要考虑企业的社会价值以及经济利益。
这样可以更好地塑造企业的口碑,同时也可以提高企业在社会中的地位和认可度,从而让企业走向更全面的发展。
总之,企业家精神和战略管理都是构建企业成功的重要因素,它们相互关联相互影响。
良好的企业文化和管理思想,有助于企业家在市场中赢得优势,同时也能让公司不断成长壮大。
企业家精神和战略管理是企业成功的重要保障,是保证创业设计最终成功的重要基础。
从企业家和经营战略看企业的成长要素

4 敏 捷 的 危 机 管 理 .
《企业家精神与战略思维》

《企业家精神与战略思维》在我国的市场经济中,创业和企业家精神成为越来越多人所追求的生活方式。
而企业家精神作为一种创业意识和经营理念,也成为了企业的核心课题之一。
企业家精神可以是一个人成功创业、并获得高额利润的核心要素,而一个成功企业,则是建立在战略思维和创业精神的基础之上。
因此,在今天的市场环境中,企业家精神和战略思维是不可或缺的一对良好拍档。
一、企业家精神的基本内涵企业家精神是指创业者的内在素质、心理状态、思想观念和行为表现,如自我驱动力、决策能力、创新意识、风险意识、团队合作精神等。
在复杂多变的市场环境下,企业家精神是企业家们不断前行的引擎,它支撑着创业者在面对挑战时的勇气和决心,具有非常重要的意义。
首先,企业家精神具有自我驱动力。
创业者决定自己的方向和目标,并围绕着他们的使命和愿景来制定行动计划。
这种强烈的自我驱动力,不仅推动了创业者的个人成长,也推动了企业的发展。
其次,企业家精神具有决策能力。
创业者要不断地在不同的市场环境下进行决策,需要有决策的能力、眼光和经验。
因此,企业家精神强调创业者需要具备分析问题、提出解决方案和做出决策的能力。
再次,创业者需要具备创新意识。
市场的竞争激烈,企业需要对市场需求进行深入研究,寻找洞察力,提出创新产品和服务,从而满足市场需求,并取得更多的利润。
最后,企业家精神还需要具备风险意识。
创业者在创业过程中面临着风险和不确定性,如果没有强烈的风险意识,就难以应对市场竞争和挑战。
因此,创业者需要对风险进行合理的预判、评估和控制。
二、战略思维对企业的意义战略思维是企业经营中最核心的内容之一,也是企业成功的关键因素之一。
战略思维强调企业要有长远的眼光,要以市场营销为导向、以顾客为中心,制定出对企业发展最为有利的经营方针,将整个企业的资源和能力集中于实现目标上。
做好战略规划,企业就可以明确自己的愿景和目标,寻找高潜力市场和商机,制定合理的吸引顾客的营销策略,加强研发和行业合作,实现企业的高效发展。
国家和企业家的战略合作与经济发展趋势

国家和企业家的战略合作与经济发展趋势近年来,随着全球经济的发展,国家和企业家之间的战略合作显得越来越重要。
国家可以向企业家提供政策支持、资源保障等条件,而企业家则可以通过合作实现更好的发展,并为国家经济的繁荣做出贡献。
本文将探讨国家和企业家的战略合作与经济发展趋势。
一、政策支持成为合作重点在过去,企业家往往在经济发展中起到孤军奋战的作用。
但是现在,许多国家开始意识到,只有为企业家提供政策支持,才能更好地促进经济发展。
中华人民共和国是其中之一,中国政府近年来出台了一系列政策,包括减税降费、优化营商环境等,这些政策为企业家的创新和发展提供了条件。
而在全球范围内,美国也一直是支持企业家的示范国家之一。
美国的政策支持,不仅包括财政扶持、税收优惠,还包括科技创新和知识产权保护等方面。
这些政策支持成为了国家和企业家之间战略合作的重点。
二、企业家具备更强的创造力和实践能力不同于传统的政府机构,企业家在经济发展中往往具备更强的创造力和实践能力。
他们可以根据市场需求和发展趋势,进行创新和扩张,为国家经济的发展做出重要贡献。
尤其是在信息技术和互联网行业,企业家的作用更加明显。
近年来,全球互联网公司的崛起,很大程度上都是由企业家所主导的。
比如,中国的阿里巴巴和美国的谷歌,这些企业家不仅在创业初期找到了市场机遇,而且通过不断的创新和扩张,实现了企业在全球市场上的领先地位。
这些企业家在创新、创造价值方面的实践经验,对于国家和企业家之间的战略合作也有着重要的启示作用。
三、国家和企业家之间的合作处于良性循环的状态在实际经济发展过程中,国家和企业家之间的合作处于良性循环的状态。
国家的扶持政策为企业家提供了创造和创新的条件,而企业家的持续发展和壮大,也为国家发展提供了源源不断的动力。
在国家和企业家之间的合作中,也需要充分考虑到双方的利益,赢得双赢,避免不必要的摩擦和利益冲突。
同时,还要充分发挥市场的作用,为企业家提供充分的发展空间。
一般来讲企业家对战略的思考方式和典型

一般来讲企业家对战略的思考方式和典型
1.长远目标:企业家通常具有远见和长远目标,他们不只关注眼前的问题和
利益,而是着眼于未来发展。
他们会思考如何在竞争激烈的市场中保持竞争优势,以及如何实现企业的长期可持续发展。
2.创新性思维:企业家通常具有创新的思维方式,他们善于发现和抓住机会,
积极寻求新的商业模式、产品或服务。
他们会思考如何通过创新来满足市场需求,并在竞争中脱颖而出。
3.敏锐的市场洞察力:企业家对市场有着敏锐的洞察力,他们会观察市场趋
势和竞争对手的动态,并根据市场需求进行战略调整。
他们会思考如何抓住市场机会,并及时调整企业的战略方向。
4.风险管理:企业家通常能够识别和评估风险,并制定相应的应对策略。
他
们会思考如何降低风险,并制定灵活的战略计划来适应不确定的市场环境。
5.团队合作:企业家通常重视团队合作,他们会与团队成员一起思考和制定
战略。
他们会鼓励团队成员提供自己的意见和建议,并共同制定实施计划。
企业家的战略眼光

企业家的战略眼光
企业家的战略眼光是指其能够站在全局和长远的角度,对企业的发展进行深入思考和规划的能力。
这种战略眼光对于企业的成功至关重要。
拥有战略眼光的企业家能够准确地把握市场趋势和行业发展动态,提前做出正确的决策。
他们能够看到潜在的商机和风险,并采取相应的措施来利用机会和规避风险。
这种预见性和决断力使企业能够在竞争激烈的市场中保持领先地位。
此外,企业家的战略眼光还体现在其对企业核心竞争力的培育和发展上。
他们能够识别并培养企业的独特优势,通过不断创新和改进来提升企业的竞争力。
同时,他们能够制定长期的发展战略,引导企业朝着既定的目标稳步前进。
企业家的战略眼光还包括对人才和资源的合理配置。
他们懂得如何吸引和留住优秀的人才,以及如何有效地利用企业的资源,从而实现企业的可持续发展。
企业家的战略眼光是企业成功的关键因素之一。
它涵盖了对市场趋势的把握、核心竞争力的培育、长期发展战略的制定以及人才和资源的合理配置等方面。
企业家岗位职责

企业家岗位职责企业家是指那些创立、管理并发展企业的人,他们具有创新意识、冒险精神和领导能力。
作为一个企业的创始人和领导者,企业家承担着重要的职责和使命,需要具备多方面的能力来确保企业的顺利运营和持续发展。
以下是企业家岗位职责的详细描述:1. 制定企业发展战略企业家需要根据市场情况和企业内部资源,制定适合企业发展的长期战略和目标。
他们需要评估市场需求、竞争态势和政策环境,为企业未来的发展方向和重点制定清晰的计划,并确保整个团队共同努力实现这一目标。
2. 创新和创业精神企业家必须具备创新意识和创业精神,能够不断寻求新的商机和发展机会。
他们需要关注市场变化,积极研究新技术、新产品和新服务,不断改进和创新企业的经营模式和产品线,保持企业的竞争力和市场地位。
3. 管理企业运营企业家需要负责管理企业的日常运营活动,包括人员招聘、培训、绩效评估,财务管理、市场营销、供应链管理等方面。
他们需要协调各个部门和团队之间的合作,确保企业整体运作顺畅,实现预定的经营目标和利润。
4. 风险管理和应对危机企业家需要具备抗压能力和危机处理能力,能够在面临挑战和风险时保持镇定和应对灵活。
他们需要及时调整战略和措施,有效防范和化解各种经营风险,确保企业的可持续发展和突发情况的处理。
5. 建立企业文化和价值观企业家需要根据企业的使命和愿景,建立并倡导企业文化和价值观,引导员工树立正确的工作态度和价值观念。
他们需要塑造和传承企业的核心价值观,激励团队成员发挥潜力,共同实现企业的长远目标。
6. 建立和维护良好的企业形象企业家作为企业的代表,需要关注和维护企业在社会和市场上的形象和声誉。
他们需要积极参与公益慈善活动,与政府、合作伙伴和社会各界建立良好的合作关系,促进企业的可持续发展和社会责任意识。
7. 激励和培养人才企业家需要关注员工的发展和福祉,为员工提供良好的工作环境和晋升机会,激励他们积极投入工作,发挥自己的才能和潜力。
他们需要注重员工的培训和发展,引导团队成员共同成长,建立专业化的团队,支持企业的快速发展。
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
战略和企业家文件编码(008-TTIG-UTITD-GKBTT-PUUTI-WYTUI-8256)STRATEGY AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP: OUTLINES OF AN UNTOLD STORYSaras D. SarasvathyUniversity of WashingtonS. VenkataramanUniversity of VirginiaInvited book chapter in the Strategic Management Handbook editedby Hitt .(Revised December 10, 2000)In his book “Invention,” Professor Norbert Wiener (1993), commenting on the relative importance accorded to individuals and institutions in historical narratives of science and inventions, asks us to imagine Shakespeare’s “Romeo and Juliet” without either Romeo or the balcony.1 The story is just not the same. He likens much of the study of the economic history of science and accounts of inventions as “all balcony and no Romeo.” The balcony for Norbert Wiener captures the context in which the story unfolds – the culture, the institutions, the constraints and the catalysts that move the plot forward and thicken it. Romeos, for Wiener, play the leading parts in the story, because there is a strong fortuitous element to inventions and there is no inevitability that a possible discovery will be made at a given time and space. Take away either one, Romeo or the balcony, and the whole story falls apart. In a similar vein, we would liken studies of strategic management to “all balcony and no Romeo.” But if we accuse strategic management of being “all balcony and no Romeo,” strategic management scholars could legitimately accuse entrepreneurship of being “all Romeo and no balcony.”1 Weiner took his inspiration from the work of the English writer, Rudyard Kipling.In this chapter we wish to suggest a point of view from entrepreneurship that will allow strategic management scholars to accommodate more Romeos in their stories. Although these two fields have much to offer each other (trade in balconies and Romeos), they have developed largely independent of each other. We wish to suggest that entrepreneurship has a role to play in strategic management theory and that strategic management theory enriches our understanding of the entrepreneurial process, although this latter aspect will not be the focus of this chapter.One useful way of thinking about entrepreneurship is that it is concerned with understanding how, in the absence of markets for future goods and services, these goods and services manage to come into existence (Venkataraman, 1997). To the extent value is embodied in products and services, entrepreneurship is concerned with how the opportunity to create “value” in society is discovered and acted upon by some individuals. As Wiener has noted (Wiener, 1993: 7), at the beginning stages of a new idea, the effectiveness of the individual is enormous: “Before any new idea can arise in theory and practice, some person or persons must have introduced it in their own minds… Theabsence of original mind, even though it might not have excluded a certain element of progress in the distant future, may well delay it for fifty years or a century.”The field of strategic management can be usefully described as having to do with the “methods”used to create this “value” and the ensuing struggle to capture a significant share of that “value” by individuals and firms. Thus, if we understand entrepreneurship and strategic management as the fields that together seek to describe, explain, predict and prescribe how value is discovered, created, captured, and perhaps destroyed, then there is not only much that we can learn from each other, but together we represent two sides of the same coin: the coin of value creation and capture.One side of the coin, namely strategic management, has to do with the achievement of ends – obtaining market share, profit, and sustained competitive advantage. The other side of the coin, namely entrepreneurship, has to do with the achievement of beginnings –creating products, firms, and markets. But the clarity and complexity with which an author connects beginnings and ends is what makes a great story. We believe the really interesting story between strategicmanagement and entrepreneurship has not yet been told. The main reason for this is that in general, creation calls for very different modes of thinking and behavior than capture and sustenance over time. Yet the creation process not only determines certain powerful tendencies for survival and growth, but some elements of it also persist over long periods of time, subtly and substantially influencing the selection and achievement of later ends. Carefully bearing in mind that large expanses of strategic management may have no overlap with entrepreneurship2, this chapter nevertheless focuses exclusively on where entrepreneurship and strategic management overlap.In the preface to their 1994 book, Rumelt, Schendel, and Teece identify the subject matter of strategic management as "the purposeful2 It is worth pointing out here that when discussing creative processes in the economic domain, strategy is a sub-set of entrepreneurship. For example, for any given new technical invention there are, at least in theory, an infinite number of product possibilities that may flow out of that invention. But, in practice, only a finite sub-set of those possibilities will come into existence. Of those new products that come into existence, only a sub-set is introduced by existing firms. Indeed, a large number of new products are introduced into the economy by new firms. Strategy essentially focuses on existing firms and theactivities of existing firms. Entrepreneurship, on the other hand, has been focusing attention on the creative process, particularly of new firms. Where they overlap is at the nexus of the creative process of existing firms. Thus, each field has vast terrains that do not overlap.direction and natural evolution of enterprises." (Rumelt, et. al., 1994) They further identify four fundamental issues that comprise a research agenda in strategic management:1. Firm Behavior3How do firms behave Or, do firms really behave like rational actors, and, if not, what models of their behavior should be used by researchers and policy makers2. Firm DifferentiationWhy are firms different Or, what sustains the heterogeneity in resources and performance among close competitors despite competition and imitative attempts3. Firm ScopeWhat is the function of or value added by the headquarters unit ina diversified firm Or, what limits the scope of the firm4. Firm Performance3 The choice of the term firm and the choice of focusing on the pre-existing firm by Rumelt, Schendel, and Teece (1994) only affirm our assertion in the previous footnote.What determines success or failure in international competition Or, what are the origins of success and what are their particular manifestations in international settings or global competitionIn answering the four questions stated above, economics and strategic management theories generally tend to focus on rational decision making (whether unbounded or bounded and linear or non-linear) based on causal reasoning and the logic of prediction. Our explication of entrepreneurship, however, rests upon creative action based on effectual reasoning and the logic of control.We have elsewhere identified the subject matter of entrepreneurship as having to do with the exploitation of opportunities for creating hitherto non-existent economic artifacts (Venkataraman, 1997; Shane and Venkataraman, 2000; Sarasvathy and Simon, 2000; Sarasvathy, 2001). Depending upon the completeness and/or consistency of the larger environment, entrepreneurial opportunities may have to be recognized or discovered or created. In this chapter, we first examine these three types of action connected with entrepreneurial opportunities through a framework based on the preconditions for their existence. Thereafter, we explore the four fundamental issues of strategicmanagement listed above from an "entrepreneurial opportunity" perspective.ENTREPRENEURIAL OPPORTUNITIES4The Oxford English Dictionary defines opportunity as “a time, juncture, or condition of things favorable to an end or purpose, or admitting of something being done or effected.” As is clear from this definition, at the minimum, an opportunity involves an end or purpose, and things favorable to the achievement of it. An entrepreneurial opportunity consists of the opportunity to create future economic artifacts and as such, involves a demand side, a supply side and the means to bring them together. Therefore, in the case of an entrepreneurial opportunity, the “things favorable” consist of two categories: (a) beliefs about the future; and (b) actions based on those beliefs. In sum, an entrepreneurial opportunity consists of:1. Supply side: New or existing idea/s or invention/s;2. Demand side: One or more ends –may be subjective (endogenous)aspirations or objective (exogenous) goals or both;54 This section summarizes our more detailed exposition titled "Three views of entrepreneurial opportunity."3. Beliefs about things favorable to the achievement of those ends;and,4. Possible implementations of those ends through the creation of neweconomic artifacts.At this point, it is important to note that entrepreneurial opportunities exist at all levels of the economy –individual, corporate, and macroeconomic. For example, the invention of the internet not only led to the identification and creation of entrepreneurial opportunities for individuals and firms, but also opportunities for the US economy as a whole in terms of more effective globalization. Similarly, Adam Smith's exposition of the "invisible hand" guided both economic policy at the government level as well as the decisions of individual economic agents and firms in the creation of "free market" institutions.5 The entrepreneur not only has an idea for a product or firm, but also has some personal aspirations and/or goals in pursuing the opportunity. Goals could be as specific as making an IPO in five years to creating a legacy for their children. And aspirations could range from making money to enjoying an independent lifestyle to changing the world. Furthermore, these aspirations and goals could change and new ones could emerge over time.But entrepreneurial opportunities are extremely context specific. What might be an opportunity today in the Ukraine may not be an opportunity at all in the US today or even in the Ukraine tomorrow. This means that entrepreneurial opportunities do not necessarily lie around waiting to be discovered by the serendipitous entrepreneur who stumbles upon them or even to be “divined” by entrepreneurial geniuses, if any such geniuses exist. Instead, entrepreneurial opportunities are often residuals of human activities in non-economic spheres and emerge contingent upon conscious actions by entrepreneurs who continually strive to transform the outputs of those non-economic activities into new products and firms and in the process fulfil and transform human aspirations into new markets.In other words, before there are products and firms, there is human imagination; and before there are markets, there are human aspirations. Creative outputs of the human imagination in every realm of human action be it the arts or the sciences, sports or philosophy, become inputs for the economic domain. It is an empirical fact that profits for the individual and the firm, and welfare for the economy come as much from Jerry Seinfeld’s jokes and Michael Jordan’s baskets,as from great technological inventions and the tearing down of the Berlin wall. Similarly, human aspirations may range from career goals and individual prosperity to freedom and justice and the good life for all and peace on earth. These aspirations have to be transformed into demand functions and markets for specific economic artifacts such as particular goods, services and firms. Entrepreneurship consists in matching up the products of human imagination with human aspirations to create markets for goods and services that did not exist before the entrepreneurial act.In fact, most entrepreneurial opportunities, be they supply based or demand based, do not originate in the economic domain at all. For example, the internet was developed as a way to facilitate communication between defense scientists and remained out of the economic domain for several years. The mere existence of the internet did not guarantee the development of e-commerce. Rather, this artifact created to solve a political problem (namely, defense), had to be transformed through several intentional and unintentional activities to become a universe of entrepreneurial opportunities in the economic domain. To cite another example, entrepreneurs such as Robert Lucas transform literary andartistic endeavors into the Star Wars marketing empire by matching up creations of the human imagination with human aspirations such as the desire to participate in the triumph of good over evil. That is why if we are to understand entrepreneurial opportunities, we have to delve into the preconditions for their existence -- ., the preconditions for the existence of demand and supply combinations that constitute entrepreneurial opportunities. This leads us to a simple typology of entrepreneurial actions in relation to opportunities as follows:1. Opportunity RecognitionIf both sources of supply and demand exist rather obviously, the opportunity for bringing them together has to be "recognized" and then the match-up between supply and demand has to be implemented either through an existing firm or a new firm. Examples include arbitrage and franchises. For example, through its first successful coffee shop, Starbucks proved the existence of a demand for specialty coffees as also a viable and effective way to satisfy that demand. Thereafter, each Starbucks franchisee only has to recognize potential geographic locations for extending that demand and supply combination. They do nothave to invent sources of supply, or induce demand for a completely new product.2. Opportunity DiscoveryIf only one side exists in an obvious manner and the other side either does not exist or is so latent as to be virtually non-existent for most people -- ., demand exists, but supply does not, and vice versa -- then, the non-existent side has to be "discovered" before the match-up can be implemented. In other words, when demand exists; supply has to be discovered. An example of this is Ron Popeil and his inventions for more convenient and health conscious kitchen devices. On the other side of the coin, supply might exist; then demand has to be discovered. The history of technology entrepreneurship is strewn with solutions in search of problems. Xerox had the technology for the Macintosh computer, but it took Jobs and Wozniak to discover and exploit its potential demand.3. Opportunity CreationIf neither supply nor demand exist in an obvious manner, one or both have to be "created", and several economic inventions in marketing, financing, management etc. have to be made, for the opportunity to comeinto existence. Examples include Wedgwood Pottery, Edison's General Electric, U-Haul, AES Corporation, Netscape, Beanie Babies, and the MIR space resort.Historically, opportunities have been supposed to exist -- and the entrepreneur either is alert to them (Kirzner, 1979) or somehow goes about "discovering" them (Hayek, 1945 and Schumpeter, 1976). But the idea we will explore in this chapter is that entrepreneurial opportunities often have to be "created" by using the entrepreneurial imagination to embody human aspirations in concrete products and markets.THE CREATIVE ENTREPRENEURIAL ASPECTS OFFUNDAMENTAL ISSUES IN STRATEGIC MANAGEMENT1. Firm Behavior -- Emphasizing the creativity of human actionHow do firms behave Or, do firms really behave like rational actors, and, if not, what models of their behavior should be used by researchers and policy makersRational ActionEconomics has long rested on foundations of rational action; and it has long been criticized for it. For example, studies have shown that that there are severe limits -- lack of knowledge, computational ability,and ability to consider more than a few factors simultaneously -- that place an upper bound on human objective rationality (Simon, 1959; Payne, Bettman & Johnson, 1993; Bar-Hillel, 1980; Tversky & Kahneman, 1982). Although this does not imply that decision makers are irrational, it shows that they must usually use heuristics and approximate inductive logics -- that nevertheless often lead to very effective decisions (Gigerenzer, Hell & Blank, 1988). They seldom have the luxury of behaving like utility maximizers.But most criticisms of the "rational" foundations of economics attack and try to relax assumptions of rationality rather than provide an overarching alternative framework. In 1991, however, Buchanan and Vanberg called for more drastic measures, particularly for our understanding of entrepreneurship (Buchanan & Vanberg, 1991). In that paper, they argue for the usefulness of a perceptual construct of the market as a creative process, rather than as a discovery process, or the more familiar allocative process. Their arguments are based on a fundamental assumption of the future that is not merely unknown, but essentially unknowable. Only speculations and conjectures are possible about the future because the future is created by the choices that humanbeings make: “Entrepreneurial activity, in particular, is not to be modeled as discovery of that which is “out there.” Such activity, by contrast, creates a reality that will be different subsequent on differing choices. Hence, the reality of the future must be shaped by choices yet to be made, and this reality has no existence independent of these choices. With regard to a “yet to be created” reality, it is surely confusing to consider its emergence in terms of the discovery of “overlooked opportunities.” (178)Creative actionPursuant to the detailed arguments advanced by Buchanan and Vanberg, we propose the following answer to the first fundamental issue in strategic management: Firms behave creatively.Firms not only use rational and analytical decision making, they also use creative action as a way to figure out both goals and strategies in an intrinsically dynamic process. If we are to build theories of strategic management and entrepreneurship based on creative rather than rational action6, we need to first examine what we know so far about creative action.6We use the terms “rational action” and “creative action” in their precise philosophical/sociological meanings – such as those used by Parsons and Joas respectively (Parsons, 19xx; Joas, 1996). We want toIn a powerful theoretical exposition, Joas (1996) has argued in considerable detail for the fundamentally creative nature of all human action. “All theories of action which proceed from a type of rational action –irrespective of whether they are based on a narrower or broader, a utilitarian or a normative concept of rationality – make at least three assumptions. They presuppose firstly that the actor is capable of purposive action, secondly that he has control over his own body, and thirdly that he is autonomous vis-à-vis his fellow human beings and environment. … The proponents of such conceptions are well aware that the preconditions assumed by the model of rational action are frequently not to be found in empirically observable action. However, these writers are forced to claim that the limited degree to which these preconditions obtain is not a deficiency of their particular theory but a fault of the actors themselves. … I am not in any way denying the empirical usefulness of rational models of action when it comes to analyzing certain social phenomena. What I do question, however, is the claim that because of its usefulness this model of rational action, withstress that we do not mean creative action to be “irrational”, nor do we suggest that rationality cannot lead to creative outcomes in the colloquial sense.all its tacit assumptions, can be applied to an ever increasing number of fields of study without a thorough reflection of precisely those intrinsic presuppositions.” (147) Joas then goes on to analyze the intentional character, the specific corporeality and the primary sociality of all human capacity for action, with a view to developing a theory of creative action that could form a basis for the social sciences.Creative action and endogenous goalsBoth works cited above (Buchanan & Vanberg, 1991; Joas, 1996) explicitly question the pre-existence of goals. Both exhort the necessity for developing a theory of human intentionality in which human purposes emerge within the processes studied and are not given a priori. For example, economics imposes utility maximization as the sole purpose or telos on the individual; profit maximization on the firm; and, welfare maximization on the economy. But others, such as psychologists and historians have argued that individuals and firms and even economies may have a variety of purposes that are not given a priori and that are born, change, and die over time. While Buchanan and Vanberg decry the economist’s imposition of an exogenous telos on the phenomena theystudy, Joas brings to bear a wide variety of authorities from the pragmatist philosophers to expressivist anthropologists to develop a theory of creative action in which telos is neither ignored, nor imposed externally, nor assumed as a precondition for action. Within management literature, March too has called for theories that do not assume pre-existent goals (March, 1982): “To say that we make decisions now in terms of goals that will only be knowable later is nonsensical –as long as we accept the basic framework of the theory of choice and its presumptions of pre-existent goals. I do not know in detail what is required, but I think it will be substantial. As we challenge the dogma of pre-existent goals, we will be forced to reexamine some of our most precious prejudices. … We should indeed be able to develop better techniques. Whatever those techniques may be, however, they will almost certainly undermine the superstructure of biases erected on purpose, consistency, and rationality. They will involve some way of thinking about action now as occurring in terms of a set of unknown future values.”The first step in building a strategic management based on creative action, therefore, would call for theories that explain theselection of goals as endogenous to the strategic management process. In strategic management, researchers such as Mintzberg have called for a research program to examine strategies that were intended as well as those that were realized despite intentions (Mintzberg, 1978).One such theory, the theory of effectual (as opposed to causal) reasoning has recently been developed in entrepreneurship and as will be seen in the following sections, will bring additional new answers to the other three fundamental questions in strategic management. While creativity in causal reasoning consists in generating alternative means for the achievement of pre-specified goals, creativity in effectual reasoning involves the generation of possible goals, given limited means and constraints within dynamic and interactive environments. The theory of effectuation suggests that the solution to goal ambiguity need not lie in random and equivocal efforts or in dumb luck.2. Firm Differentiation -- Emphasizing effectuation rather than causationWhy are firms different Or, what sustains the heterogeneity in resources and performance among close competitors despite competition and imitative attemptsDifferentiating between generalized aspirations and specific goals The issue of differentiation is even an issue only if we assume homogeneity of goals, especially goals that are determined prior to choice. In reality, however, human beings do not begin with specific goals –only with vague and generalized aspirations, that are themselves contingent upon a host of situational and temporal factors. This intrinsically pluralizing role of contingent aspirations affects both demand-side and supply-side choices. For example, on the demand side, most hungry customers do not start with the “need” for a specific food such as hamburgers. Instead they start with a generalized hunger for something to eat. The entrepreneur induces the customer to transform that generalized aspiration into a concrete demand for a specific product such as the hamburgers manufactured by a particular company.There are two types of choice here. The first one involves the transformation of a vague aspiration such as hunger into the specific desire for a hamburger. The second one involves the choice between possible hamburger joints, given the desire for a hamburger.As proponents of the resource-based theory of the firm have pointed out, inmainstream economics and management, we tend to model the latter type of choice ., choice between means to achieve a particular goal) rather than the earlier one – ., the choice between possible ends, given particular means and very generalized aspirations (Ulrich & Barney, 1984).Similarly, on the supply side, most entrepreneurs do not set out to build a particular company for a particular product within a particular market (Ex: to create a profitable company for manufacturing and selling razor blades). Instead, when setting out, the entrepreneur only has some very general aim, such as the desire to make lots of money, or to create a lasting institution, or more commonly, just an interesting idea that seems worth pursuing. For example, Gillette started with the idea of making some product that would need to be repurchased repeatedly. Moving from that relatively vague starting point to actually designing and manufacturing the disposable razor involved a very different set of choices than after he had determined the particular product that he wanted to make and sell. The type of reasoning involved when specific goals have to be created from contingent aspirations is necessarily different from the type of reasoning involved in attaining that specific goal once it is finalized.Given a specific goal, selecting between alternative means involves causal reasoning. Transforming contingent aspirations into possible specific goals and choosing between them involves effectuation.Effectuation finds its theoretical antecedents in researchers such as March who investigated exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organizational learning involves decisions that allocate scarce resources (including attention) between the exploration of new possibilities and the exploitation of old certainties. These decisions are complicated by the fact that their costs and benefits may be dispersed over time and space, and that they are subject to the effects of ecological interaction. Yet, balancing the allocation between exploration and exploitation is crucial to the survival and sustenance of the organization. March argues that understanding the relationship between these two horns of a continuing dilemma in organizational evolution leads us away from a linear approach to concepts such as “success” and “sustainable competitive advantage”. For example, introducing a new technology such as computerized decision support systems, while improving the organization’s chance of avoiding b eingthe worst competitor, may reduce it’s chance to be the overall winner in the game (March 1991: 84).But effectuation goes beyond the dichotomies of exploration and exploitation, or the distinction between linear and non-linear thinking. Effectuation is useful in domains where there is no pre-existent universe of possibilities to explore –instead, such a universe gets created,often unintentionally, by acts of human imagination. These acts of the imagination may occur in the normal course of human activity in a wide variety of domains, most of which may not be driven by any immediate economic goal. For example, the theory of effectuation would argue that no exploration of any relevant economic domains could have led to the “discovery” of the intern et and its e-commerce possibilities. Instead, an artifact created to solve a particular problem in an unrelated domain (in the internet example, the communication problem for defense scientists) was eventually transformed into a universe of possible economic opportunities by internet entrepreneurs. This transformation did not happen overnight. The mere existence of the internet did not inevitably imply the creation of e-commerce. Instead, that creation had to await several fortuitous。