进出口贸易外文翻译文献

合集下载

国际经济与贸易外文翻译外文文献英文文献.docx

国际经济与贸易外文翻译外文文献英文文献.docx

国际经济与贸易外文翻译外文文献英文文献.docx外文文献翻译The effects of subjective norms on behaviour in the theory of planned behaviour: A meta-analysisMark Manning*University of Massachusetts, Amherst, Massachusetts, USAA meta-analysis investigated the effects of perceived injunctive (IN) and descriptive (DN) norms on behaviour (BEH) within the theory of planned behaviour (TPB) in a sample of 196 studies. Two related correlation matrices (pairwise and listwise) were synthesized from the data and used to model the TPB relations with path analyses.Convergent evidence indicated that the relation between DN and BEH was stronger than the relation between IN and BEH. Evidence also suggested a significant direct relation between DN and BEH in the context of TPB. A suppressor effect of IN on DN in its relation with BEH was also noted? Moderator analyses indicated that the DN-BEH relation was stronger when there was more time between measures of cognition and behaviour, when behaviours were not socially approved, more socially motive and more pleasant: results were mixed in the case of the IN-BEH relation. Results imply that IN and DN are conceptually different constructs?As social beings, normative pressure inevitably affects our behaviour?Social nonns influence the way we dress, how we vote, what we buy, and a host of other behavioural decisions.Social psychologists have been exploring the influence of social norms on behaviour for decades? From AschM and Milgram s conformity- experiments (Asch, 19S6;Milgram, Bickman, & Berkowitz, 1969) through recent work by Cialdini andcolleagues(Cialdini, Reno. & Kallgren, 1990; Reno, Cialdini, & Kallgren, 1993), a substantial body of evidence has demonstrated that people conform to the judgments and behaviours of others.In experiments conducted by Cialdini and his colleagues (Cialdini et al., 1990; Reno et al., 1993), participants inferred behavioural norms for littering from environmental cues and acted in accord with these norms. The results highlight the fact that perceptions of norms, ratber than actual norms, can affect behaviour? Tlie relation between perceived norms and behaviour has receivedmuch empirical support (Borsari & Carey, 2003; Campo, Brossard. Fnizer. Marchell, Lewis, & Talbot, 2003; Gomberg, Schneider, & Dejong, 2(K)I; Grube, Morgan, & MeGree, 1986; Okun, Karoly, & Lutz,2002; Riniai & Real. 2005). However, one ofthc most influential models for predicting behaviour, the thcor>*of planned behaviour (TPB; Ajzcn, 1991), posits that rather than a direct relation between norm and behaviour, perceived nortns influence behaviour indirectly by way of behavioural intentions. Investigating the perceived norm-behaviour relation in tlic context of this theory offers insight not only into the strength of the relation, but also into the extent to which perceived norms may directly influence behaviour counter to theoretical expectations.The present study used mcta-analytic path analyses to examine, the relation between two types of perceived norms (injunctive (IN) and descriptive (DN) norms; described below) and behaviour in the context of the TPB (Ajzcn. 1991). The investigation explored the direct effects of IN and DN on behaviour as well as factors that may moderate the effect of subjective norms (SN) on behaviour?The theory of planned behaviourAccording to the TPB, the immediate antecedent of behaviour is the intention to pertbrm the behaviour (Figure 1). This behavioural intention is in turn a function of three major determinants: attitude towards the behaviour, perceived SN pertaining to the behaviour, and perceived degree of control over engaging in and ctJmpleting the behaviour (perceived behavioural control).The formation of attitudes (ATT), SN and perceived behavioural control (PBC) are respectively functions of behavioural beliefs, normative beliefs and control beliefs that a person holds with regards to the behaviour? Concerning ATT, the set of accessible beliefs that a person holds about the outcome of a behaviour will determine the evaluation of the behaviour, and thus influence the strength and direction of the ATT towards the behaviour.SN are a function of the normative beliefs that people relevant to the individual are perceived as having towards tbe behaviour coupled with the motivation of the individual to comply with the expected notins of these relevant persons? PBC is a function of the perceived factors that will influence the ability to engage in the behaviour coupled with the perception as to whether or not these factors will be present.In short, the TPB holds that favourable ATT, SN. And perceptions of control will lead to favourable intentions to engage in a given behaviour. Actual control over engaging in the behaviouris itself an important determinant? To the extent that individuals realistically appraise the amount of control that they have over the behaviour, the measure of PBC; can serve as a proxy for actual control. Perceived control is expected to have amoderating effect such that intentions will be reflected in actual behaviour to the extent that perceived control is high.The TPB has been applied successfully to a wide range of behaviours accounting for a sizable amount of variance (Armitage & Ckmner, 2001: Bamberg, Ajzen, & Schmidt,2003; Hardeman. Johnston. Johnston, Bonetti, Wareham, & Kinmonth. 2002; Povey.Wellens, & Conner, 2001; Rise. Thompson. & Verplanken, 2003). Regarding the SN construct, the theory holds that the effect of SN on behaviour is fully mediated by behavioural intentions? In other words, SN are not expected to have a direct effect (DE)on behaviour but instead influetice behaviours indirectly through their effect on intentions.Descriptive and injunctive normsTwo types of SN can be distinguished. IN are social pressures to engage in a behaviour based on the perception of what other people want you to do whereas DN are social pressures based on the observed or inferred behaviour of others? Tliis distinction has been empirically supported (Cialdini et al .,1990; Deutsch & Gerard.1955; Grube et al., 1986; Larimer & Neighbours, 2005; Larimer. Turner, Mallett. & Geisner, 2004; Reno et al.,1993; Rhodes & Courneya, 2003; White, Terry, & Hogg, 1994). Within the TPB, the SN construct was originally conceptualized as an injunctive norm (Ajzen, 1991). More recently, however, Ajzen and Fishbein (200S) have recommended including both types of normative measures in constructing planned behaviour stirveys? DN and IN will therefore be considered separately in the analyses to follow. Subjective norms-behaviour relationIn reviewing the SN construct in the planned behaviour context, Conner and Armitage(1998) have noted the lack of predictive power of the IN construct when predicting intention.Due to the paucity- of studies including DN in the planned behaviour context,conclusions regarding DN in this context are sparser. Recently, several investigators have included DN as predictors of intentions in the planned behaviour model (PBM;Fekadu &Kraft, 2002; MCiMUlan & Conner, 2(K)3; Okun et al.. 2002: Sheeran & Orbell, 1999b). Rivis and Sbeeran (2003) conducted a meta-analysis of DN in the planned behaviour context. Their analysis, based on 18 studies, demonstrated a significant relationship between DN and intention when controlling for otlier variables in the TPB.In that, these previous studies have investigated theeffects of SN on intentions, to date,no planned behaviour mcta-ana lysis has explored the potential for differences in the effects of SN on behaviour in the planned behaviour context.Deutsch and Gerard (1955) have suggested that DN and IN refer to different sources of motivation. Regarding DN, it has been shown that perceptions of behaviours of others lead one to behave in similar manners (Asch, 1956;Milgram et al., 1969). Descriptive normative information functions as a heuristic with regards to behavioural decisions offering cues as to what is appropriate behaviour iii a given situation (Cialdini et al., 1990; van Knippenberg, 2000). IN on the other iiand operate more through the role of motivation to comply with social sanctions (Ajzen, 1991;Lapinski & Rimal, 2005). To the extent that individuals are motivated to comply with perceived behavioural expectations of relevant referents, they avoid social sanctions?Though several studies have looked at the effect of one or botli types of norms on particular behaviours, there has yet to be a single meta-analytical review that compares the relationshipbetween the two types of norms and behaviours across a spectrum of behaviours. Consequently, on a general level it is unknown whether one type of norm has a stronger effect on behaviour than the other it may be hypothesized that DN have a stronger effect on behaviour than IN because DN are activated in the immediate behavioural situation. Furthermore, processing of DN for behavioural decisions may require less cognitive effort relative to the processing of IN, in that DN may rely more on heuristic than systematic informatioprocessing?Perhaps, this advantage contributes to efficient behavioural decision?making in line with descriptive normative information. In fact, researchers have shown that conditions that facilitate the use of heuristic information-processing lead participants to act more in line with DN (Hertel, Neuhof, Theucr, & Kerr, 2000). It is expected therefore, that DN will have a stronger effect on behaviour relative to IN.Direct effect ofSN on behaviourThe TPB posits that the relationship between SN and behaviour is fully mediated by behavioural intentions (Ajzen, 1991; Ajzen & Fishbein, 1973)? However, a number of planned behaviour studies that have included normative constructs as a behavioural predictor have found direct effects of SN on behaviour (Christian & Abrams, 2004 -Study 2; Christian & Arm 让age, 2002; Christian, Armitage, & Abrams, 2003; Okun et al.,2002; Trafimow & Finlay, 2001). In most research with the TPB, the effect of the normative component on intentions has received most attention (Armitage & Conner,2001; Rivis & Sheeran, 2003) while the potential for a DE of SN onbehaviour has received little empirical or meta-analytical scrutiny.One reason to explore, the potential for a DE may be the hypothetical nature under which most people report cognitionspertaining to behaviour in planned behaviour studies? Hypothetical contexts may not accurately reflect the relations between cognitions and behaviours that are evident in real behavioural contexts (Ajzen, Brown, & Carvajal, 2004). Furthermore, when an individual reports an intention to engage in a particular behaviour in one instance, that behavioural intention may be subject to change from the instance it is formed to the moment when an opportunity for behavioural engagement arises (Ajzen, 1991).For example, in the classic linn (1965) study, hotel managers expressed little intent to allow Chinese couples to stay in their hotels, however allowed them to do so when the instance arose? It is less likely that perceptions of norms related to the behaviour will change over time. Consequently, there is the potential for reported normative perceptions to have stronger relations with behaviour compared with relations between reported behavioural intentions and behaviour. This may be reflected in the presence of a DE of SN on the particular behaviour. The present meta-analjtical synthesis provides the opportunity* to gauge the potential for a direct relation between SN and behaviour in the context of the TPB.Variation in the magnitude of the SN^ehaviour relationship The possibility of a DE of SN on behaviour within the TPB implies that there are two ways in which SN can affect behaviour. There can be the theoretically posited indirect effect on behaviour mediated through intentions, and there may be a DE on behaviour. The total effect therefore is the sum of these two effects? In accord with the prediction that DN have a stronger relation with behaviours compared to the IN-behaviour relation, it is expected that the total effect of DN on behaviour is greater than the total effect of IN on behaviour. In addition to predicteddifferences between DN and IN in their effects on behaviour, there is the potential for differences in the magnitude of the effect within each type of norm. Compatibility* between measures of cognition and behaviour and the time between measurement of cognitions and behaviour are expected to lead to differences in the magnitudes of the effects of SN on behaviour. Additionally, the potential moderating effect of three further variables will be explored;the level of social approval of the behaviour, the extent to which social motives underlie behaviour, and the extent to which a behaviour is uselial versus pleasant may all contribute to variance in the relationship between norms and behaviour.CompatibilityElements of a particular behaviour can be defined in terms of the behavioural target, the action involved in the behaviour, the context in which the behaviour is performed, and the time at wliich it is performed. The relationship between cognitive predictors of a particular behaviour and engagement in the behaviour will be stronger if behavioural elements and cognitive assessment of the behaviour are compatible (Ajzen, 1996; Ajzen & Fishbein. 1977). That is to say., for instance, that if an investigator would tike to pretlict someone's propensity* to exercise 3 days a week for half an hour, measures should assess cognitions regarding exercising 3 days a week for half an hour rather than cognitions to be healthy, or some other general cognition regarding exercise?Tenned the ”principle of compatibility0, it holds that measurements of planned behaviour variables must be compatible with the target behaviour in terms of target, action, context, and time. Given the effect of compatibility and the magnitude of the correlations betweenplanned behaviour variables and behavioural measures, it is expected that studies where the cognitive and behavioural measures are fully compatible will feature stronger relations between SN and behaviour. It is also expected that among studies where measures are more compatible, the intention mediated relation between SN and behaviour will be stronger than any unmediated relation, in line with theoretical dictates, whereas among studies that are less compatible there will potentially be greater direct effects of SN on behaviour.Time interval between measures of SN and behaviourAccording to Ajzen ( 1991 ). cognitive precursors of behaviour that are measured closer to the target behaviour should be more predictive of behavioural engagement. Due to motivational considerations, measures of the intention to engage in a particular behaviour will vary as a function of proximity to behavioural engagement (Bandura & Schunk. 1981; Kamiol & Ross, 1996; Steel & Konig, 2006) in that tlie ftirther in the future is the potential behavioural engagement, the less predictive are intentions to engage in this behaviour. As Ibe relation between stated intentions and actual behaviour decreases over time, the potential exists for SN to be relatively more predictive of behaviour. This potential is evident in light of the argument outlined above wherein SN pertaining to a behaviour are less likely to change over time compared to behavioural intentions. As such, it is expected that as the time between measurement of cognitions and behaviour increases, SN will be reflected to a greater extent in actual behaviour.Furthermore, as the relation between intentions and behaviour diminishes, it is likely that the DE of SN on behaviour will be stronger as more time passes between measures of cognition and behaviour.。

国贸专业外文文献翻译

国贸专业外文文献翻译

外文文献原稿和译文原稿Introduction2010,Risks in Global MarketWhere there’s an opportunity,there’s a risk.Traders always face risks in any market,from the richest countries to the least developed economies. And as the global economic crisis changed markets,some risks for international trades might have been unveiled or worsened.The risks,which derive from the diversity and vicissitude of market structures,jurisdictions,commerce rules, cultures,languages,and even psychosociological factors,may exist in any sector and stage of the trade process,such as destination marketing,customs clearance,financial support,debts and solvencies,and adherence to WTO rules.A report by the Ministry of Commerce of China specified the risks of investing and doing business in many countries.Zhou Mi,an expert on the research panel,argued that the global market is undergoing a wave of restructuring and rebalancing because consumption in developed countries has waned and the emerging economies will accordingly wield greater influence in the world economy.The newest updates of this report will reveal more specifics, and some of them are listed here in advance.A senior manager from Ernst& Young analyzes the effect that corporate reshaping could have on customs clearance.China Export&Credit Insurance Corporation evaluates the risk factors in the financial systems and debt structures of some important markets.An expert from China’s Economic Diplomacy defines some risks created by WTO rules and offers advice on how to handle the risks.译文介绍2010年,在全球市场的风险那里是一个机会,还有一个风险。

国贸专业 外文翻译 外文文献 英文文献 不对外国企业抱任何敌意

国贸专业 外文翻译 外文文献 英文文献 不对外国企业抱任何敌意

原稿IntroductionITC: Not foreign enterprises hold any hostility- Vice-Chairman of the U.S. International Trade Commission(ITC)Deanna Tanner, Okun InterviewForeign Tade:For Chinese companies, the U.S. International Trade Commission (ITC) is still relatively unknown. Economic and trade fields, known for Chinese enterprises, the Ministry of Commerce. ITC What are the differences in their functions? Deanna Tanner Okun:States International Trade Commission (ITC) is a set up by Congress, quasi-judicial federal agency with extensive powers to deal with trade-related issues.In the U.S., has the power institutions dealing with trade-related matters in addition to the ITC the U.S. Commerce Department. Perform their duties in the course of the investigation of the anti-dumping and intellectual property rights infringement, the display can.In economy and trade, specifically, the duties of the U.S. Department of Commerce finds that constitute dumping and dumping margin, ITC is mainly survey dumping to the detriment of domestic firms in the United States. In addition .ITC is a quasi-judicial body, independent of the Government, specialized agencies, and trade for the U.S. government to provide advice and statistics. To take measures to maintain the general market relations in the United States for unfair trade practices.That is, the ITC's main functions include three parts. Management of U.S. trade remedy laws fair and objective manner; tariffs, international trade and competition issues to the President, the United States Trade Representative (USTR) and Congress to provide independent, high-quality information and support; maintaining the U.S. Harmonized Tariff Schedule. Based on the above-mentioned functions .ITC six members designated by the President and the Senate recognized the addition was designated to fill the unexpired vacancy, the appointment term of nine years. The term of office by the Constitution, theprovisions of the staggered calculated. Every 18 months, have different members have retired. Members of the office for more than five years may not again be specified. No more than three members from the same political party. Chairman and Vice-Chairman appointed by the president for a term of the statutory two years. The President shall not former President from the same political party. The President shall appoint two members from the same political party as Chair and Vice-Chairman.Foreign Tade:Then, the ITC is how to perform its functions for national service? Deanna Tanner Okun:ITC are five ways to carry out its functions to serve the country: - Import injury investigation, including determining the import of some kind of unfair trade (anti-dumping or countervailing duty investigations) and the increase in imports (global and bilateral security measures for the investigation) to cause damage or a threat of material injury to U.S. industry.- IP-related imports of investigation, including the guide to sex, to obey the president's objections against certain unfair practices in the import trade, such as patent or trademark infringement.- Investigation procedures, including an objective analysis of the major trade-related issues; to predict the economic impact of trade agreements; analysis of the specific competition in the industry, and to find within the industry and external economic factors that affect the industry competitive.- Trade information services to the ITC, Congress and the implementing agencies and the public delivery of reliable and timely information and analysis of data through this service. - Trade policy support .ITC staff to provide direct technical support to the USTR, Congressional committees, inter-departmental committee, and the U.S. delegation in multilateral trade organizations such as the World Trade Organization (WTO). Authorization based on field surveys .ITC to exercise the powers of the extensive investigation of trade-related issues.The right to exercise judgment, the ITC to make a decision in respect of certain unfair trade practices. Through research .ITC also become the source of a national trade data collectionand analysis, and information and analysis available to the implementing agencies and Congress to help them to specify and develop U.S. trade policy.Foreign Tade:Articles understand, import injury investigation, anti-dumping / countervailing duty investigations. The five-year (sunset) review of global security measures to investigate, and IP-related imports investigation the ITC often conducted several major investigations. Could you talk about the difference between them?Deanna Tanner Okun:Import Injury Investigation: ITC reserves the right to decide based on whether the U.S. trade law imported products cause damage to related industries for the United States, or a threat of injury. ITC's injury investigation into the 13 anti-dumping and countervailing duty investigations .And in accordance with Chapter VII of the 1930 Tariff Act five-year (sunset) review; global security measures under the 1974 Trade Act (Disclaimer), Chinese security measures market disruption investigation; According to the 1994 North American Free Trade Agreement(NAFTA), bilateral security measures to investigate the implementation of Act 302; and a survey conducted in accordance with section 22 of the agricultural Adjustment Act.Members according to the facts recorded in the relevant legal requirements and each survey to survey into El damage a decision on its view into El damage survey announced. And subject to judicial review.In each investigation, the ITC and investigation team (including an oversight investigator of an investigator, an accountant or auditor. An economist, a business analyst and a lawyer) produced a complete the survey of the domestic industry competitive market conditions report .Committee members and the research team using a variety of fact gathering techniques, including (but are not limited to) industry-specific questionnaires, telephone interviews, factory visits, technical and market experts advice, statements by the parties, the public hearing, and to review the industry and market literature.In each survey, the survey team to collect and analyze a wide range of data, then an objective and comprehensive report submitted to the ITC. The data in the report include (but are not limited to) industry production capacity, actual production, capacity utilization,domestic El goods, stocks, imports, the United States and foreign supplier by the share of U.S. market share, labor conditions, working hours, productivity, wages, paid total compensation, unit labor cost, pricing, distribution channels, and related industries in the United States financial data .Some foreign production of related products industry data collection and analysis.ITC members and officials of the U.S. Department of Commerce, the U.S. customs service, survey clients and their lawyers, the person in charge of the U.S. production company, importer, product buyers such as working together in the course of the investigation into El damage. In addition, members of Congress often through the hearing participating damage to their views and perspectives to the survey report. In 2003.Members of Congress on the importation matters related to the investigation of l damage appeared 51 times in the ITC. Second, the anti-dumping / countervailing duty investigations and five-year (sunset) review: 1930 under Chapter VII of the Tariff Act of the U.S. industry in the U.S. market at less than fair value into 13 sales (dumping) or benefit from foreign government subsidies (subsidies) to request the Government for relief .Dumping and subsidies are considered to be unfair trade practices.Under the law, the U.S. Department of Commerce decided to dump or subsidies exist, if it exists, the amount of dumping and subsidies. ITC decided to dumping or subsidies for imported products is the U.S. industry to cause substantial damage or substantial damage to the threat. If the two bodies on their respective problems have to give a positive final ruling, the Commerce Department will dump released the command of anti-dumping duty order or subsidies countervailing duties. In the five years after the promulgation of the Commerce Department should cancel the anti-dumping or countervailing duty imposed order .Or termination of the moratorium, unless the Commerce Department that the elimination of tariffs imposed order or termination of the moratorium could lead to the continuation or resumption of dumping or subsidies .ITC at the same time that the elimination of tariffs imposed order or termination of dumping or subsidies to suspend the agreement in the reasonably foreseeable period of time is likely to continue or start again.In 2003.41 under Chapter VII of the request is put forward .Most of which are dumping (41, 35). These requests include a wide range of products, Such as malleable iron pipe fittings, memory, memory module, refined brown aluminum oxide, ceramic radio cylindrical insulator, prestressed cement Wire Rope, fluorescent pale rust inhibitors, water magnetic cut-outs, Color television receivers, Wax / resin transfer zone, Ethylene retail bag, Trahydrofurfuryl alcohol ,Hot coat hanger, Electrolytic manganese dioxide, Transparent rectangular tube. ITC has also completed a 2002 'cases.Third, the global security measures survey: According to the 1974 Trade Act 201, imported products cause serious harm or serious threat of injury, the domestic industry can be brought to the ITC to reduce imports.201 did not like the anti-dumping / countervailing duty provisions of the Tariff Act, as the requirements to identify the existence of unfair trade behavior. If the ITC 201 investigation, a positive decision, it will recommend to the President to reduce imports to compensate for the damage, easy to adjust the domestic industry against import competition .The president ultimately decide whether the magnitude of the relief, and relief.Among them, 2003, the ITC proposed three measures against China. They include steel pipe hangers, brake drums and rotary axis, and an extension of the iron sprinklers. These are based on U.S. China Relations Act 2000 will be 421 to join the Trade Act of 1974.The simultaneous implementation of China's accession to the terms of the bilateral security measures for the Sino-US agreement in the WTO transition period, it is also known as safety measures investigation. According to the terms of the ITC found that imports to the United States, China products reach the number listed to increase or cause or threat of market disruption related and similar competitive products to meet the conditions set out, domestic producers get relief .Global security measures to investigate, if the ITC to make a positive decision, it will propose to the President relief proposal .The President made a final decision on whether to provide relief to the American industry, if provided, determine the types and duration of relief.Fourth, intellectual property-related imports investigation: According to the 1930 Tariff Act 337, the ITC conducted a survey of some of the inequitable conduct raised the import trade.The majority of complaints under the clause amounts patent or trademark infringement cases.Foreign Tade:In recent years .Chinese enterprises in the United States repeatedly subjected to anti-dumping and intellectual property investigations, whether to talk with Chinese enterprises, the investigation?Deanna Tanner Okun:The 337 program surveys typically include complex factual and legal decisions. In 2003.ITC has proposed three measures against China: Meanwhile, the number of 337 investigations is increasing and has started 111 investigations, 42 involve the Chinese mainland and Hong Kong, Only in 2005 to the present .Initiate an investigation of 11 in the five involved in the Chinese Mainland and Hong Kong; Types of 337 procedures to investigate products and intellectual property very extensive. About 41 from the 2003 survey of 337 procedures a third of it comes to high-tech products in the field, especially in the field of computers and communications, such as high-speed wireless LAN system, For storage .Management and data protection hardware and software systems, recordable and rewritable disc, a variety of memory core Sheets and related integrated circuit devices, and semiconductor mask works. Part of the investigation involving machinery, pharmaceutical, manufacturing microelectronic devices and equipment used for the transport and sorting parcels, the complex technology of the call device, such as garage door openers. In addition some of the year 337 investigation procedures involving bearings for industrial use, computer game systems, electronic education equipment, electronic security equipment as the facilities of toilet and kitchen wall, alkaline batteries, home vacuum packaging equipment, etc.. According to statistics, from 1998 to the present, 334 anti-dumping investigations, China accounted for 47 involving agricultural products, manufactured goods, and other fields.In 2003.A total of 41 cases of an ongoing investigation and associated procedures cases, from 21 in 2003.Only seven of the survey conducted in 2003 has nothing to do with thepatent infringement, one of which is due to the abuse of trade secrets and other non-patent unfair means, from trademarks and trade dress infringement and unfair to other non-patent means.Foreign Tade:Some people think that Section 337 violates the WTO rules on national treatment, how do you look at this issue?Deanna Tanner Okun:I can not answer this with political issues, but I personally think that 337 or more transparent,Its procedural framework is pretty fair, if there are errors, you can appeal to the courts to correct. In fact, in the 337 investigation has been launched, only 16% of the final decisionto constitute infringement, the ratio is not too high.Foreign Tade:It is reported that the U.S. domestic companies, drew ITC Section 337 investigations is no charge .Well, this may lead to sponsored enterprises due to the low cost and abuse complaint?Deanna Tanner Okun:Indeed, as you said, the ITC's investigation is no charge for no cost, but that does not mean to initiate enterprisesOr low cost. In the U.S., the fees of court litigation for $ 150, seemingly not high, attorney fees, however, is quite expensive .In fact, we found that the initiator of the cost of not less than the cost of the respondent to The same time, the abuse complaint by administrative law, therefore, generally will not abuse complaint behavior.Foreign Tade:ITC members have to vote if there are subjective factors?Work ITC how to avoid the subjective domestic trade protection tendency?Deanna Tanner Okun:In particular, I want to emphasize here is your question in the "external factors" .First, the prosecution of U.S. companies is their right, whether the respondent is also charged with enterprise rights .ITC did, just under the existing law to the specific investigation and ruling.Secondly, the ITC is an independent body on external factors does not exist, it asked all businesses to be assured, the ITC is a completely non-partisan, independent body.In theUnited States, the ITC is not affiliated with any administrative department of the United States.Foreign Tade:Specifically, China should be how to deal with anti-dumping and 337 investigations?Deanna Tanner Okun: This is why we came to China to highlight the one. I personally think that the Chinese enterprises, the first is to go out. Respond actively. Seize a 50% chance of success . The occasion of the investigation in the case of reconciliation is very large, for example, there have been three Chinese tractor companies as defendants .Which the two responding, and finally reached a settlement, only slightly changed the appearance of color on the line, so, the respondent is the first step is very important. Second is to take the correct and specific measures .I personally recommend that Chinese enterprises should apply for a patent to own the intellectual property rights, but also by way of thecross-license with each other to reach complementary and prosecution agreement, to prevent itself subject to appropriate investigation.In addition, the receipt of the initial questionnaire, the companies can find the appropriate lawyer to issue an infringement to prove, so that even losing in the final award as not to constitute malicious infringement of evidence, the loss will be much smaller.译文介绍ITC:不对外国企业抱任何敌意——美国国际贸易委员会(ITC)副主席Deanna Tanner Okun(迪安娜·蒂娜·奥昆)访谈Foreign Tade:对于中国企业来说,美国国际贸易委员会(ITC)还是比较陌生的。

宁夏农产品出口贸易问题英文文献

宁夏农产品出口贸易问题英文文献

宁夏农产品出口贸易问题英文文献Title: Export Trade Issues of Agricultural Products in Ningxia, ChinaIntroduction:Ningxia, located in the northwest of China, is an important agricultural region known for its production of various agricultural products such as goji berries, wolfberries, and apples. In recent years, Ningxia has been actively involved in exporting its agricultural products to international markets. However, the export trade of agricultural products in Ningxia faces several challenges, including quality control, market access, and trade barriers. This article aims to delve into these issues and propose potential solutions to promote and enhance the export trade of agricultural products in Ningxia. Quality Control:Ensuring the quality and safety of agricultural products is crucial for successful export trade. In Ningxia, there have been instances of product recalls or rejections due to quality issues, which have negatively impacted the reputation and market access of local agricultural products. To address this problem, it is essential to establish stringent quality control mechanisms throughout the entire production and supply chain.This can be achieved through implementing good agricultural practices, conducting regular inspections, and providing proper training and education to farmers and producers. Additionally, setting up quality testing laboratories and certification systems can help build trust and credibility for Ningxia's agricultural products in international markets.Market Access:Gaining access to international markets is another significant challenge for Ningxia's agricultural products. The region's relatively remote location and limited transportation infrastructure hamper efficient and cost-effective export trade. To overcome this barrier, it is necessary to improve transportation and logistics infrastructure, including road networks, railways, and air cargo facilities. Furthermore, establishing trade agreements and partnerships with foreign countries can help reduce trade barriers and facilitate market access for Ningxia's agricultural products. Collaborating with international trade organizations and attending trade fairs and exhibitions can also provide opportunities for networking and showcasing local products to potential buyers.Trade Barriers:Trade barriers such as tariffs, non-tariff measures, andsanitary and phytosanitary requirements can pose challenges to Ningxia's agricultural product exports. To address these barriers, it is crucial to engage in diplomatic negotiations with importing countries to lower or eliminate trade barriers. Furthermore, actively participating in international organizations and forums related to agriculture and trade can enable Ningxia to have a stronger voice in shaping global trade policies and regulations. Collaborating with other agricultural regions in China and sharing experiences and best practices can also help navigate trade barriers more effectively.Conclusion:Exporting agricultural products from Ningxia presents significant opportunities for economic growth and development. However, to fully harness these opportunities, it is essential to address the challenges related to quality control, market access, and trade barriers. By implementing comprehensive quality control measures, improving transportation infrastructure, and actively engaging in trade negotiations, Ningxia can enhance its export trade and establish its agricultural products as reputable brands in international markets.。

china's export中国进出口分析外文文献

china's export中国进出口分析外文文献

Rev World Econ(2013)149:565–585DOI10.1007/s10290-013-0149-2O R I G I N A L P A P E RChina’s fare share?The growth of Chinese exportsin world tradeSteven Husted•Shuichiro NishiokaPublished online:6February2013ÓKiel Institute2013Abstract The growth of Chinese exports in market share over the past two dec-ades is a singular event in the history of world ing data from1995–2010, we document this growth in a variety of ways.We show that the expanded trade is pervasive.Virtually every country in the world has seen China claim a larger share of its import market.Then,we use Constant Market Share analysis to determine which country or countries have lost market share as China’s trade has grown. Contrary to much discussion in the popular press,wefind strong evidence that other developing countries have not seen export shares fall as a result of China’s gains. Rather,our results suggest that China’s share growth has come largely at the expense of exporters based in developed countries,especially Japan and the United States.Keywords Chinese exportsÁConstant market share analysisÁExport shares JEL Classification F14ÁP331IntroductionOver the past two decades the Chinese economy has grown at a remarkable pace. Between1995and2007Chinese real GDP grew at an average annual rate of more S.Husted(&)Department of Economics,University of Pittsburgh,4508WW Posvar Hall,Pittsburgh,PA15216,USAe-mail:husted1@S.NishiokaDepartment of Economics,West Virginia University,1601University Avenue,Morgantown,WV26506-6025,USAe-mail:Shuichiro.Nishioka@566S.Husted,S.Nishioka than10%.Per capita real GDP rose by250%over this period.1One of the leading factors driving this economic growth has been the extraordinary performance of Chinese exports.According to the World Trade Organization(WTO),in2010China rankedfirst in exports to the world market with merchandise export sales of more than$1.5trillion and a world market share of10.4%.In1998,China had less than 2%of the world market.Twenty years earlier,China’s share was essentially zero. As China’s share of world exports has grown,it has come under increasing pressure to allow its currency to appreciate;often the criticism of its exchange rate practices includes charges that other developing and emerging market economies have borne the brunt in terms of lost export markets.2The purpose of this paper is to provide an analysis of Chinese export growth over the period when its share of world exports rose most rapidly,the years1995–2010. We provide detail on the commodity composition of Chinese exports and how this composition has changed.We also discuss some aspects of the geographic pattern and commodity composition of Chinese trade.In addition,a fundamental contribution of this paper is that we provide considerable evidence that the principal exporting countries that have lost market share to China are developed countries,especially Japan and the United States.We use Constant Market Share(CMS)analysis(i.e.,Fagerberg and Sollie1987) to determine which offive factors(i.e.,market share,commodity composition, commodity adaptation,market composition,and market adaptation)are responsible for the rise of Chinese share.During the period we consider,the market share effect is the critical factor to explain the share change in the world trade.This element of trade growth captures the extent to which an exporter gains or loses market share against other exporters independent of changes in the product and destination pattern of world imports.In particular,almost all share gains of China over the period1995–2010(i.e.,the market share effect accounts for11.6of12.9percentage points(pp.)of Chinese share gains)stem from the market share effects.3 We also apply CMS analysis to the sub-periods of1995–2000,2000–2005,and 2005–2010.In the period of1995–2000,the share gain of China was relatively moderate (2.9pp.)and Japan and Germany lost market share in roughly equal amounts(2.4and 2.2pp.,respectively).The United States also saw its world export market share rise during this period,due primarily to the commodity composition effect.That is,the United States gained market share because the structure of world import demand changed toward the types of goods that the United States exports.During the period2000–2005,Chinese market share increased by5.8pp.and the majority of Chinese share gains were accompanied by the significant market share loss of the United States(-4.0pp.).Finally, over the sub-period(2005–2010)that included the great trade collapse of2008–2009, 1These numbers use China Version2data from the PWT6.3data set.See‘‘What is New in PWT6.3?’’link on the Penn World Tables site,/php_site/pwt_index.php,for a discussion of the differences between this version of Chinese data and official Chinese data.2See,for instance,Arvin Subramanian,‘‘Who Pays for the Weak Renminbi?’’,11February2010,Vox Front Page,/index.php?q=node/4604.3With the exception of Sect.2,the discussion of share changes in the remainder of this section and the rest of the paper refers to trade in manufactured goods(SITC categories5–9)among a sample of92 countries and Hong Kong.China’s fare share567 China’s share increased by4.2pp.and the market share and commodity adaptation effects both explain the share changes.While developed countries’demands for manufacturing goods had slowed due to thefinancial crisis,developing countries’demands for foreign manufacturing goods were relatively strong.China had increased its world market share by exporting intensively to emerging developing countries.4 The rest of the paper proceeds as follows.In Sect.2we present an overview of Chinese trade expansion.In Sect.3we discuss CMS analysis,an empirical technique that provides a method for studying changes in export market shares.In Sect.4,we apply CMS to study trade patterns among a sample of94countries over the period1995–2010in commodity trade disaggregated at the5-digit SITC level. We also apply CMS to study the periods to1995–2000,2000–2005,and2005–2010. In Sect.5,we expand our analysis by focusing on export behavior across industries and in individual export markets.Section6offers our conclusions.2An overview of Chinese export performanceFigure1provides a time series plot of world export shares forfive of the world’s leading exporting countries,Germany,China,Japan,the United Kingdom,and the United States over the post World War II era.As thefigure shows,since the end of World War II,only Germany has seen as rapid and as large a rise in world export share as China.In the eleven year span from1948to1958,Germany’s share of world exports rose from1.3to10.3%,roughly matching in both magnitude and duration China’s performance.However there are several major differences between the two. First,Germany’s growth almost certainly represented a return for that country to a market position similar to the one that it had held prior to the war era.Second,at the time of Germany’s significant growth there were far fewer major exporters competing for market share.For instance,in the1950s the combined world export share of the countries now known as the Asian Newly Industrialized Countries (NICs)(Korea,Malaysia,Singapore,and Thailand)was virtually zero.In contrast, since at least the onset of the industrial revolution and prior to the1990s,China had never held a significant share of world trade.And,China’s export growth came only slightly after significant growth by the NICs and simultaneously with major growth by several other countries that along with China make up the BRICs(Brazil,Russia, and India),all of whom now also hold relatively large shares of the world market.Like all major exporting countries,China has a market presence in virtually every country in the world;this presence has grown in almost every market in recent ing data from the United Nation’s Commodity Trade Statistics Database we calculated aggregate exporter market shares in92countries and1territory (Hong Kong),from all parts of the world.5Several interesting patterns emerge from 4In a related study,Wood and Mayer(2011)look at how the entry of China into international markets over the past three decades has impacted production of primary and labor-intensive products in a wide set of developing countries.Theyfind that although output and exports of labor-intensive goods continued to rise following the emergence of China in the1990s,the growth in these ratios was slower in the1990s than in the1980s.5These countries were chosen due to the availability of the import data from UN Comtrade.568S.Husted,S.NishiokaTable1China’s national export market share by regionCountries2010national market shares(%)Share changes1995–2010aAverage SD Maximum Minimum Average SD Maximum MinimumAfrica2015.99.349.1 6.213.09.145.5 3.1Asia and Pacific1318.910.749.1 4.211.8 3.415.9 3.8 Europe319.4 6.536.0 3.18.0 6.033.4 2.4 Middle East712.0 1.113.310.210.20.711.09.0 North America316.4 5.221.911.613.1 2.615.09.5 South America1912.77.735.1 5.211.77.435.1 4.2Total9313.28.449.1 3.110.7 6.935.1 2.4a Share changes are measured in percentage pointsthis exercise.First,the global extent of China’s trade expanded significantly between1995and2010.By2010,China had at least3%of the market in all of these countries.Moreover,market share growth was pervasive;over the1995–2010 period China’s market share grew in all of these markets.In many cases,especially in South America,Africa,and smaller European countries,shares were essentially zero prior to1995.Table1provides some additional summary statistics.According to the table,geography is clearly important for China’s trade.At the end of2010,its highest regional market share was in Asia where among the sample countries it had an average share of18.9%.Its highest market share among all the Asian countries in the sample stood at49.1%.6Its next highest average regional market share was in North America;this included16.7%of all U.S.merchandise 6This was China’s share of Hong Kong’s market.Among the other Asian countries in this sample China had more than25%of Japan’s market in2010and more than10%of the export markets of Thailand, South Korea,Pakistan,and Singapore.China’s fare share569 imports in2010.On average,China’s smallest regional market penetration was in Europe,where its average national market share in2010was9.4%.Since2005, China’s export shares have increased particularly in remote and low-income countries.For example,the average of China’s export shares in African countries increased from8.3to15.9%.For the South American countries in our sample, China’s average market share almost doubled,rising from6.6to12.7%.As detailed more fully below,China’s export market share has grown in recent years,and it has changed the mix of goods it supplies to world markets.By value, virtually all of Chinese exports are manufactured goods.Early on,these exports were concentrated in Miscellaneous Manufactured Articles(SITC Category8), including apparel and toys.While that category still accounts for a significant share of Chinese exports,more recently Chinese trade growth has been concentrated in Machinery and Transport Equipment(SITC Category7).In order to better focus on this change in the commodity composition of trade,we restrict our attention to exports of differentiated manufactured products disaggre-gated at the5-digit SITC level.In much of what follows we continue to analyze data from a set of94countries.7Our sample includes countries from every continent and includes countries at various standards of living;slightly more than one-third the countries chosen in our sample are classified by the World Bank as high-income countries.In2010,the countries used in our analysis accounted for76.8%of total world imports.8Trade among these countries accounted for a majority of all world merchandise trade in each of the years in our sample.Thefirst panel of Table2provides detail on the composition of Chinese exports in1995and2010across broad categories of goods to our sample of markets as well as the countries identified as developing countries.9Also included in the table is China’s portion of total world exports at the1-digit level(SITC Rev.3)in1995and 2010.As the table shows,Chinese exports have been centered in manufactures for some time.In1995,90%of Chinese exports to our sample countries came from industries classified in SITC sections5–9.By2010,that share had risen to almost 95%of total exports.Traditionally,Chinese exports have been concentrated in Miscellaneous Manufactured Articles(SITC Category8).This sector includes many labor intensive manufactured products such as clothing,footwear,and toys,items 7In addition to China,we use the following countries:(Africa)Algeria,Burkina Faso,Burundi, Cameroon,Coˆte d’Ivoire,Egypt,Ethiopia,Gambia,Kenya,Madagascar,Malawi,Mauritius,Morocco, Mozambique,Niger,Togo,Tunisia,Uganda,Tanzania,and Zambia;(Asia and Pacific)Australia,Hong Kong,India,Indonesia,Japan,South Korea,Malaysia,Maldives,New Zealand,Pakistan,the Philippines, Singapore,and Thailand;(Europe)Austria,Croatia,Cyprus,the Czech Republic,Denmark,Estonia, Finland,France,Germany,Greece,Hungary,Iceland,Ireland,Italy,Kazakhstan,Kyrgyzstan,Latvia, Lithuania,Malta,Moldova,the Netherlands,Norway,Poland,Portugal,Romania,Slovakia,Slovenia, Spain,Sweden,Switzerland,and the United Kingdom;(Middle East)Bahrain,Israel,Jordan,Oman, Qatar,Saudi Arabia,and Turkey;(North America)Canada,Mexico,and the United States;(Central and South America)Argentina,Barbados,Belize,Bolivia,Brazil,Chile,Colombia,Costa Rica,Dominica, Ecuador,El Salvador,Guatemala,Jamaica,Nicaragua,Panama,Paraguay,Peru,Suriname,and Venezuela.8Our data set consists of bilateral trade of93countries.We calculate the total world imports from the sum of total imports of all available countries in UN Comtrade.9Developing countries are those not classified as being a high-income country by the World Bank in its 2009World Development Report.long identified as characteristic examples of Chinese exports.Twenty seven percent of Chinese exports to our sample countries in 2010came from this sector.However,this share had stood at 47%of total exports to these markets in 1995.Instead,in recent years,the share of Chinese exports of more sophisticated manufactures has risen substantially with exports in Machinery and Transport Equipment (SITC Category 7)more than doubling to 51%of its exports to the sample markets.The period 2005–2010includes the onset of the Great Recession in the United States and elsewhere and the consequent 2008–2009collapse in world trade.10AsTable 2Structure of world exports and imports SITC Rev 3Commoditiesposition of Chinese exports all countries II.China’s shares in world (China’s/World exports)1995201019952010(a)Structure of Chinese exports 0Food and live animals 4.5 2.0 3.4 5.01Beverages and tobacco 0.40.1 2.4 1.92Crude materials 2.40.8 2.8 2.33Mineral fuels2.4 1.0 2.3 1.34Animal and vegetable oils 0.10.0 1.10.65Chemicals and related products3.94.7 2.25.86Manufactured goods (materials)15.312.6 5.515.07Machinery and transport equipment 23.250.8 3.119.08Miscellaneous manufactured articles 47.327.418.933.39Other commodities 0.50.8 1.03.8SITC Rev 3CommoditiesIII.The levels of total imports (2005=1)Developing countries Developed countries 1995201019952010(b)Structure of world imports 0Food and live animals 0.789 1.6470.788 1.6421Beverages and tobacco 1.296 2.108 1.840 1.8532Crude materials 0.360 1.7280.533 1.5333Mineral fuels0.248 2.7290.542 3.7484Animal and vegetable oils 0.495 1.3450.935 1.6925Chemicals and related products 0.448 1.7030.629 1.3196Manufactured goods (materials)0.583 1.6840.841 1.2837Machinery and transport equipment 0.561 1.5580.8670.9348Miscellaneous manufactured articles 0.391 1.6220.843 1.0229Other commodities2.8411.4710.5361.394We use import data of 94countries for panels I and II10For detail on this period see Richard Baldwin,The Great Trade Collapse:Causes,Consequences,and Prospects ,VoxEU eBook,2009,/index.php?q=node/4297.570S.Husted,S.NishiokaChina’s fare share571 has been documented by the Nabli(2010)developing countries have rebounded much more strongly from the downturn,and these countries have accounted for much of the growth in trade over the past several years.This pattern shows up well in the second panel of Table2where we document the levels of imports for developing and developed countries for each product group.We set the import values of year2005as1.For example,while the import values of Category7 increased from1in2005to1.558in2010and those of Category8increased from1 to1.622for developing markets,the corresponding values are0.934and1.022for exports to developed country markets.China’s world market shares changes over this period followed the transforma-tion described above.Between1995and2010,its share of Industry7exports to the world increased by a factor of six,while its Industry8market share increased by slightly less than15pp.We are not thefirst to point out the recent growth in the sophistication of Chinese exports.Rodrik(2006,p.4)calculates that by2002China had an export bundle‘‘of a country with an income per capita level three times higher than China’s’’.In a related study,Schott(2008)focuses on Chinese exports to the United States.Hefinds that the composition of this export bundle ‘‘increasingly overlaps with that of the world’s most developed economies’’(Schott 2008,p.34).The data in Tables1and2document the growth of Chinese exports and the change in the sectoral composition of these goods over the period1995–2010. Clearly,the rapid growth of China in the world market has had market share implications for other exporting nations.A number of papers have focused on various aspects of the recent growth of Chinese exports on global competition.One focus of attention has been on whether the growth has occurred due to an expansion of the variety of goods exported(the extensive margin)or a growth in trade of existing varieties(the intensive margin).Broda and Weinstein(2006)find that over the last quarter of the twentieth century roughly30%of U.S.import growth was at the extensive margin,with China the largest contributor.However, using Chinese export data disaggregated at the HS-8level,Amiti and Freund(2010) report that most of Chinese export growth to the world between1997and2005was in existing varieties.Most recently,Manova and Zhang(2009)usingfirm level data on Chinese tradingfirmsfind that a relatively few largefirms are responsible for substantial share of exports;thesefirms export to many markets,and many are foreign owned.A principal focus of our paper is on which other exporting countries are losing foreign markets due to the rise of China.Other papers have also attempted to address this ing a gravity model,Hanson and Robertson(2010)study ten developing countries they identify as potential losers to Chinese competition. However,theyfind Chinese export expansion over the1995–2005period has had only a modest negative impact on the exports of these other countries.In an earlier study,Ahearne et al.(2003)use VAR analysis to see if Chinese exports reduce the exports of other Asian economies.Theyfind instead a positive correlation between exports from these two sources.Thesefindings along with the industry classifica-tions of Chinese exports suggest that major competing countries with China in world export markets may be developed rather than developing countries.In theremainder of this paper,we try to identify which countries have lost share and to provide a measure of the size of the losses.We also focus on the growth of Chinese exports at broad industry levels and in individual export markets.We turn now to describe the modeling strategy we employ to answer these questions.3Market shares methodologyConstant Market Share(CMS)analysis has long been used to study export performance.11This modeling approach treats as a norm of behavior that a country’s market share will remain constant over time.If instead it changes,that must be due to changes in competitiveness or changes in demand from the world as a whole or in individual markets.The analysis then proceeds to decompose export share changes in order to identify these factors.In the1950s and1960s,CMS was a popular tool of analysis.In a well-known paper,however,Richardson(1971)criticized its use, arguing that the signs and magnitudes of the measured effects depend upon in part on the methods used in their calculation.Taking these criticisms into account,Fagerberg and Sollie(1987)(hereafter FS)have proposed several refinements to traditional CMS analysis.These include improved theoretical consistency via the use of Laspeyres weights throughout and an explicit economic interpretation of all decomposed terms.They have also extended the traditional model to include two additional terms which measure the adaptability of the export sector of a country to changes in the commodity and national market composition of world exports.12We now turn to a brief derivation of their model.First,consider the change in exporters’shares in each importer’s market.We define the value of imports of product i from country k to l is defined as m i kl.The market share of country k(an exporter)in product i in market l(an importer)isa kl i ¼m kl i=Xkm klið1ÞProduct i’s share of country l’s total imports is defined asb l i ¼Xkm kli=XiXkm klið2ÞSince the market share of country k is written asM kl¼Xi a klib li;the change in country k’s share of market l between an initial year(time0)and year t isD M kl¼M kl tÀM kl0:11See Leamer and Stern(1970)Chapter7for a derivation of the original model and the references therein for examples of its use.12Irwin(1995)uses the FS approach to study changes in the export market share of Great Britain in the early twentieth century.572S.Husted,S.NishiokaThis equation can be rewritten as the sum of three terms:D M kl ¼D M kl a þD M kl b þD M klabð3ÞwhereD M kl a¼X iða kl it Àa kl i 0Þb li 0ð4ÞD M klb ¼Xi a kl i 0ðb l it Àb l i 0Þð5ÞD M kl ab¼Xiða kl it Àa kl i 0Þðb l it Àb li 0Þð6ÞEquation (4)is the effect of changes in the market share,weighting the change inexporter k ’s share of product i exports by the initial share of the product in market l .Equation (5)is the effect of changes in the product composition of importer l ,weighted by the initial share of the product from country k .The final term,Eq.(6),is a residual term which can be written asD M kl ab ¼r kl ab X iða kl it À"a kl t Àa kl i 0þ"a kl 0Þ2"#0:5Xiðb l it Àb l i 0Þ2"#0:5ð7Þwhere r klab is the correlation coefficient between the changes in market shares and the changes in product shares.FS then extend the decomposition exercise from one market to the world market.The country l ’s share of world imports is defined as:c l ¼X kX im kl i =X kX lXim kl ið8ÞIn this case,we can write the market share of county k in world market as M k ¼X lM kl c l :The change in M k between time 0and time t isD M k ¼D M k m þD M k c þD M kmc¼D M k a þD M k b þD M k ab þD M k c þD M kmcwhereD M k a ¼Xlc l 0Xiða kl it Àa kl i 0Þb li 0"#ð9ÞD M kb ¼X lc l 0Xia kl i 0ðb l it Àb li 0Þ"#ð10ÞD M kab ¼Xlc l 0Xiða kl it Àa kl i 0Þðb l it Àb li 0Þ"#ð11ÞChina’s fare share 573D M kc ¼XlM klðc l tÀc l0Þð12ÞD M kmc ¼XlðM kl tÀM kl0Þðc l tÀc l0Þð13ÞOur analysis focuses on Eqs.(9)–(13);following FS,each can be interpreted as a separate factor that influences export performance.Equation(9)is the market share effect.This term captures the change in an exporter’s share of each product in each country,holding constant the initial commodity composition and the country distribution of world imports.Thus,it captures the extent to which an exporter gains market share independent of changes in the product and destination pattern of world imports.Equation(10)is the commodity composition effect.The commodity composition effect measures the influence of the changing share of products in world trade on an exporter’s overall share.If,for instance,the structure of world imports changes towards more manufactured goods and away from agricultural products,the exporters of manufactured goods(agricultural goods)would see an increase(a decrease)in their market shares.Equation(11)is the commodity adaptation effect.The commodity adaptation effect identifies whether the change in the structure of a country’s exports is correlated with changes in the commodity composition of world imports.This number is zero if the country changes its export structure at the same rate as all countries exporting to the world market.Equation(12)is the market composition effect.This effect measures the influence of changes in the country demand pattern of world imports.Thus,it identifies the countries that increase their world market share by selling their products heavily in expanding markets.Finally,Eq.(13)is the market adaptation effect.This effect captures the correlation between a country’s export destinations and world export destinations.4Empirical results from the CMS approach4.1Share changes from1995to2010For each country in our study,the change in market share of the world market is decomposed into thefive effects discussed above.The results from1,832products for regional exports and a selected set of countries are given in Table3.13The right-most column in table provides the overall percentage change in the total sample export market share for each of the regions and sample countries over the period 13We concentrate on1,8325-digit exports of goods that Rauch(1999)and Hallak(2006)define as differentiated products at the3-digit level.To be consistent across93countries for years1995,2000, 2005,and2010,we use the5-digit level data,which is the highest disaggregation possible for our study. Most of these products are from1-digit SITC sectors of5–8.Since there are gaps in5-digit sub-products 673and676(some types of iron and steel products),we exclude products from these two sectors.We study the CMS decomposition for the country and region level separately.While we use93countries for each of l and k for the country-level analysis,we use the country aggregates of6regions for each of l and k for the regional analysis.574S.Husted,S.Nishioka1995–2010.14The other five columns represent different effects,corresponding to Eqs.(9)–(13),and add up to the total change.The first thing to note about the table is that for most countries in the study,overall export shares hardly changed over the sample period (see the last column).This stability of trade shares is a stylized fact of trade patterns at the bilateral level first pointed out and analyzed by Cassing and Husted (2004,2009)in two related studies.The principal exceptions to this pattern of export share stability over the sample period are China (?12.87pp.),Japan (-5.28pp.)and the United States (-4.29pp.),and four European countries (Germany,France,Italy,and the United Kingdom)combined (-5.25pp.).These results clearly imply that the growth in Chinese export market share has come largely at the expense of exporters in developed countries,in particular Japan and the United States,rather than exporters in developing countries.Since Canada also lost market share,each of the G7countries saw market shares drop over this period,several by more than one percentage point.In fact,the G7countries explain around 80percent of all the share losses.We turn now to discuss what factors have contributed to these changes in trade shares.Table 3Export market share change decomposition:selected countries (1995–2010)Fagerberg and Sollie decomposition (1,832SITC 5-digit products)Market shareCommodity composition Commodity adaptation Marketcomposition Market adaptation Total change in share Africa 0.111-0.0590.0330.0110.0110.108Kenya 0.000-0.002-0.0020.006-0.003-0.001Asia and Pacific 5.353-3.995 5.078-0.0680.350 6.719China 11.594-0.808 3.048-1.1310.16312.867India 0.6760.0380.114-0.061-0.0120.755Indonesia 0.266-0.0290.011-0.039-0.0650.145Japan -6.450-1.359 1.7670.3690.396-5.277Malaysia -0.640-0.3960.520-0.3810.232-0.665South Korea -0.993-1.051 1.7750.1300.6610.523Europe -6.499 2.293 1.258-0.129-0.260-3.337France -1.5390.3070.2010.050-0.037-1.018Germany -1.7040.1480.1520.644-0.178-0.938Italy-1.267-0.281-0.1630.228-0.131-1.616United Kingdom -2.0110.864-0.337-0.130-0.065-1.680North America -6.155 1.5250.3110.021-0.123-4.420Canada -1.1730.2010.139-0.1690.025-0.977Mexico 0.7320.0550.283-0.132-0.0910.847United States -5.9770.8080.9790.284-0.383-4.290South America 0.2310.063-0.1690.1650.0030.293Brazil -0.0210.0200.0280.0310.0250.083Middle East0.4760.146-0.0030.0000.0180.637For the regional-level analysis,we use the country aggregates of 6regions for k and l14Values for the countries not listed in Table 3tended to be very small.They are available on request.123。

世界贸易和国际贸易外文文献及中文翻译

世界贸易和国际贸易外文文献及中文翻译

World Trade and International TradeIn today’s complex economic world, neither individuals nor nations are self-sufficient. Nations have utilized different economic resources; people have developed different skills. This is the foundation of world trade and economic activity. As a result of this trade and activity, international finance and banking have evolved.For example, the United States is a major consumer of coffee, yet it does not have the climate to grow any or its own. Consequently, the United States must import coffee from countries (such as Brazil, Colombia and Guatemala) that grow coffee efficiently. On the other hand, the United States has large industrial plants capable of producing a variety of goods, such as chemicals and airplanes, which can be sold to nations that need them. If nations traded item for item, such as one automobile for 10,000 bags of coffee, foreign trade would be extremely cumbersome and restrictive. So instead of batter, which is trade of goods without an exchange of money, the United State receives money in payment for what it sells. It pays for Brazilian coffee with dollars, which Brazil can then use to buy wool from Australia, which in turn can buy textiles Great Britain, which can then buy tobacco from the United State.Foreign trade, the exchange of goods between nations, takes place for many reasons. The first, as mentioned above is that no nation has all of the commodities that it needs. Raw materials are scattered around the world. Large deposits of copper are mined in Peru and Zaire, diamonds are mined in South Africa and petroleum is recovered in the Middle East. Countries that do not have these resources within their own boundaries must buy from countries that export them.Foreign trade also occurs because a country often does not have enough of a particular item to meet its needs. Although the United States is a major producer of sugar, it consumes more than it can produce internally and thus must import sugar.Third, one nation can sell some items at a lower cost than other countries. Japan has been able to export large quantities of radios and television sets because it can produce them more efficiently than other countries. It is cheaper for the United States to buy these from Japan than to produce them domestically. According to economic theory, Japan should produce and export those items from which it derives a comparative advantage. It should also buy and import what it needs from those countries that have a comparative advantage in the desired items.Finally, foreign trade takes place because of innovation or style. Even though the United States produces more automobiles than any other country, it still imports large numbers of autos from Germany, Japan and Sweden, primarily because there is a market for them in the United States.For most nations, exports and imports are the most important international activity. When nations export more than they import, they are said to have a favorable balance of trade. When they import more than they export, an unfavorable balance of trade exists. Nations try to maintain a favorable balance of trade, which assures them of the means to buy necessary imports.International trade is the exchange ofgoods and services produced in one country for goods and services produced in another country. There are several reasons for it.The distribution lf natural resources around the world is somewhat haphazard: some nations possess natural deposits in excess of their own requirements while other nations have none. For example, Britain has large reserves of coal but lacks many minerals such as nickel, copper, aluminum etc, whereas the Arab states have vast oil deposits but little else. In the cultivation of natural products climates whereas others, such as citrus fruits, require a Mediterranean climate. Moreover, some nations are unable to produce sufficient of a particular product to satisfy a large home demand, for example, Britain and wheat. These are the reasons why international trade first began.With the development of manufacturing and technology, there arose another incentive for nations to exchange their products. It was found that it made economic sense for a nation to specialize in certain activities and produce those goods for which it had the most advantages, and to exchange those goods for the products of other nations which and advantages in different fields. This trade is based on the principle of comparative advantage.The theory of comparative advantage, also called the comparative cost theory, was developed by David Ricardo, and other economists in the nineteenth century. It points out that trade between countries can be profitable for all, even if one of the countries can produce every commodity more cheaply. As long as there are minor, relative differences in the efficiency of producing a commodity even the poof country can have a comparative advantage in producing it. The paradox is best illustrated by this traditional example: the best lawyer in town is also the best typist in town. Since this lawyer cannot afford to give up precious time from legal and typing matters. But the typist’s comparative disadvantage is least in typing. Therefore, the typist has a relative comparative advantage in typing.This principle is the basis of specialization into trades and occupations. At the same time, complete specialization may never occur even when it is economically advantageous. For strategic or domestic reasons, a country may continue to produce goods for which it does not have an advantage. The benefits lf specialization may also be affecting by transport costs: goods and raw materials have to be transported around the world and the cost of the transport narrows the limits between which it will prove profitable to trade. Another impediment to the free flow of goods between nations is the possible introduction of artificial barriers to trade, such as tariffs or quotas.In addition to visible trade, which involves the import and export lf goods and merchandise, there is also invisible trade, which involves the exchange of services between nations.Nations such as Greece and Norway have large marine fleets and provide transportation service. This is a kind of invisible trade. When an exporter arranges shipment, he rents space in the cargo compartment or a ship.The prudent e xporter purchases insurance for his cargo’s voyage. While at sea, a cargo is vulnerable to many dangers. Thus, insurance is another service in which some nations specialize. Great Britain, becauseof the development of Lloyd’s of London, is a leading expor ter of this service, earning fees for insuring other nations’ foreign trade.Some nations possess little in the way of exporter commodities or manufactured goods, but they have a mild and sunny climate. During the winter, the Bahamas attract large numbers of countries, who spend money for hotel accommodations, meals, taxis, and so on. Tourism, therefore, is another form of invisible trade.Invisible trade can be as important to some nations as the export of raw materials or commodities is to other. In both cases, the nations as the export of raw materials or commodities is to other. In both cases, the nations earn money to buy necessities.International trade today little resembles European commerce as it existed between the 16th century and the 19th century. Trade in earlier times was conducted largely between a mother country and its colonies. It was conducted according to strict mercantilist principles. The colonies were supposed to supply the mother country with raw materials, and they were expected to buy all finished goods from the mother country. Other forms of trade were forbidden to the colonies, but many of them evaded these restrictions.A result of the Industrial Revolution, which began in England in the 18th century, was the transformation of trade from a colonial exchange into a many sided international institution. Cottage industries gave way to mass production in factories. Railroads and steamships lowered the cost of transportation at the same time that new markets were being sought for the expanding output of goods.The Industrial Revolution also brought an end to mercantilist policies. The laissez-faire attitudes that emerged in their stead permitted businessmen to manufacture what they pleased and to trade freely with other nations. Trade was also stimulated by the growth of banking facilities, insurance companies, and improved commercial shipping and communications.The repeal of the Corn Laws by Great Britain in 1846 ended Britain’s longstanding policy of protectionism. During the 19th century, many European nations made commercial agreements with each other easing their tariff rates. Lower tariffs and the growth of population and industry caused trade to soar in the 19th century.In the 20th century two world wars and a major depression caused severe disturbances in international trade. Nations, sensing a threat to their domestic economies, sought to protect themselves from further disturbances by erecting various barriers to trade.The situation became even worse after Great Britain abandoned the gold standard. The nations that were closely related to Britain, including most of the members of the Commonwealth of gold standard. As the means of making international payments broke down and trade restrictions increased, some countries had to resort to barter to obtain foreign goods.International trade was in such severe straits during the depression that a World Economic Conference was held in 1933. This conference, however, was unable to halt a rash of currency devaluations, tariff increases, and quota arrangements.In 1934, U.S. Secretary of State Cordell Hull persuaded Congress to pass the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act. This law authorized the President to negotiate tariff cuts with other nations. The Reciprocal Trade Act provided for protection of U.S. industries in the event foreign imports increased to such a degree that U.S. businesses were injured. This protection included peril point and escape clauses under which tariff cuts could by refused of rescinded if a U.S. industry suffered economic hardship. Despite the protectionist clauses in the act, U.S. tariffs were substantially reduced.Shortly before the end of World War Ⅱ, members of the United Nations met at Bratton Woods, N.H. to discuss ways of reducing the financial barriers to international trade. The International Monetary Fund was established as a result of the conference. The fund was designed to encourage the growth of international trade by stabilizing currencies and their rate of foreign exchange.In the early postwar period, more than 20 nations met in Geneva, Switzerland, to negotiate tariff reductions. When any two nations reached an agreement to reduce tariffs on a product, the benefits were extended to all participating nations. This was an application of the so-called most favored nation clause.The Geneva tariff agreements were written into the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). GATT also established standards for the conduct of international trade. Fox example, the agreement prohibits nations from placing quotas of limits on imports, except under very special circumstances.After World War Ⅱ a number of free trade areas were formed to solve trade problems on a regional basis. Tariffs on goods moving within these areas were to be abolished. Some of the groups also erected a single tariff on the goods of outsiders coming into their common area. Such groups are called customs unions. The goal of all trade blocs was to merge small political units into large geographic entities in which goods could be freely manufactured and sold. A large market area greatly stimulates economic growth and prosperity. These trade blocs are: Benelux, The European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC), the European Economic Community (EEC or Common Market), the European Free Trade Association (EFTA), the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECOM), the Latin American Free Trade Association (LAFTA), the Central American Common Market (CACM), the Caribbean Free Trade Area (CARIFTA), the Caribbean Community and Common Market (CARICOM).世界贸易和国际贸易在当今复杂的经济世界个人和国家都不是自给自足。

国际贸易参考文献英文

国际贸易参考文献英文English:For references on international trade, there are several key texts that scholars and practitioners often use. "International Trade: Theory and Policy" by Paul Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld is a well-regarded textbook that provides an in-depth understanding of the theories and policies surrounding international trade. Another important reference is "World Trade Statistical Review" by the World Trade Organization, which provides comprehensive data and analysis on global trade patterns and trends. "The Law and Policy of the World Trade Organization" by Peter Van Den Bossche is an essential text for understanding the legal framework and workings of the WTO, while "The Competitive Advantage of Nations" by Michael E. Porter offers insights into the role of national competitiveness in international trade. These references cover a wide range of topics and provide valuable insights into the complexities of international trade.中文翻译:对于国际贸易的参考文献,有几本关键的书籍是学者和实践者经常使用的。

高新技术产品出口贸易外文文献翻译

文献出处:Gaulier G. The research of high-tech product export trade [J]. Economic Change and Restructuring, 2015, 10(2): 27-37.原文The research of high-tech product export tradeGaulier GAbstractThe development of world economic integration, makes the competition of the international trade market, outstanding performance for the competition of science and technology, especially high-tech products, the development of high-tech products has become the embodiment of the national competitiveness. The development of high-tech industries to the development of the whole world economy plays a vital role. New high-tech product export to promote upgrading of the industrial structure, is of great significance to the economic growth mode transformation, is a measure of a country's economic strength, science and technology the important index of strength and export power. Under the background of a significant change in the economy, further improve the quality and efficiency of growth of high-tech products, is to realize the economy and the important way of foreign trade imports and exports rose sharply. Therefore, the related research of high-tech products export trade is very necessary. We must identify the actualities of the development of new high-tech product export trade structure, explore the essence of the problem, investigate its reason, and adopt corresponding strategies.Keywords: High technology industries; Technology products export; Technology innovation1 IntroductionThe world economy in the 1990 s after the development speed is generally slow, appear serious insufficient effective demand, the world market and in developed countries to accelerate worldwide industrial structure adjustment and technology capital to promote the economic development of developed countries, the result is the new and high technology industries in developed countries, increasing the proportion of high-tech products export has become the developed countries and emergingindustrialized countries the main form of international trade and world market competition is mainly determined by the new and high technology products. In the face of the development of world economy and the arrival of knowledge economy, to show new and high technology industries and expand new high-tech product export trade as the international competitiveness, promote economic growth, implementing trade country to trading powers, the key to cultivate new growth point of foreign trade. High-tech products export trade has become the key to the rapid growth of foreign trade to achieve. High and new technology industry development is to achieve by extensive trade growth to quality and change the way of growth.2 An overview of the new and high technology productsThe definition standard of high-tech industries in different countries of more, a common definition of high and new technology industry is based on the R&D funds accounted for the proportion of sales or engineers, scientists, in the proportion of total worker. For example, the American scholar r. nelson in the five countries are more high-tech policy points out: "refers to the high and new technology industry, those funds to invest a lot of research and development, rapid technological progress as the symbol of industry.” About the definition of high and new technology industry and its products in different countries, different regions and different development period is different. But we usually use the organization for economic co-operation and development (OECD) definition of standards. The OECD's standard is according to the industrial sector in the research and development funds accounted for the proportion of the total output value to determine the technology intensity and the high technology industry is divided into five sectors: medical, precision and optical scientific instruments; Office, accounting, and computing devices; Medicine; Radio, television and communication equipment; Aerospace.The characteristics of high and new technology products(1) High knowledge intensity, high risk and high investmentIs high and new technology has been used widely in a variety of modern scientific and technological achievements, on the basis of a variety of knowledge innovation, the characteristics of high and new technology itself makes high-techproducts combined with a variety of new and high technology become inevitable. High-tech products are with high intensity of knowledge. In the processing and manufacturing of the products, packaging, sales each link such as application of new and high technology, increase the technology content of products, improves the performance and quality, to expand the function of the product, finally to improve the market competitiveness of products. High and new technology product is highly centralized capital and manpower, need early high investment. High and new technology research and development and creation, first of all need a lot of high technology management and development of talent, you must devote to the innovation talented person has a certain scale to achieve technology research and development. Second high concentration of creative talents must have a lot of money as a guarantee, so the large concentration of high technology research and development need the money. High investment will bring high risk, to the high return of high-tech products, high investment and high risk must be prominent features of high technology products. Have a certain scale to achieve technology research and development. Second high concentration of creative talents must have a lot of money as a guarantee, so the large concentration of high technology research and development need the money. High investment will bring high risk, to the high return of high-tech products, high investment and high risk must be prominent features of high technology products. (2) With increasing marginal revenue of uniquenessHigh and new technology product breaks through the traditional product law of diminishing marginal returns, shows the characteristics of marginal increasing returns. First, because the marginal cost of high and new technology to copy is decreasing, they can realize sharing and reuse. Second, the high and new technology as the most dynamic factors of production, has a unique savings and economies of scale, it can save the material in the production of manpower, material, time, money, improve labor productivity, shortening production high-tech products of social necessary labor time, reduce the production value per unit product; Increased with the application scope, sharing, more show the trend of increasing return to scale, in the international trade exchange can obtain more trade benefits. The third, along with the increase ofthe content of goods at improve the quality of the goods and performance formed the brand effect, high value-added profit can be obtained. Fourth, the leader of the new high-tech product, and is due to take the opportunity, will take the lead in the international market to establish a favorable technology standard, product standard, market access and market competition rules, thereby gaining monopoly and monopoly profits.(3) The present special life cycle of high-tech productsDue to the speeding up of the scientific and technological progress, scientific and technological achievements into productivity cycles are getting shorter; leading to high and new technology product update speed, shorten the life cycle. Moore says integration of semiconductor integrated circuit is doubling every about 18 months, the law has been proved. According to the theory of product life cycle theory, the technology gap, in the stage of product innovation, because innovation countries invested a lot of research and development spending, innovative products production in the first place in the United States and other developed countries, and then exported to other similar level of economic development in developed countries, and income level is higher; Therefore, high-tech products trade development is the structural adjustment and transfer of international industry complement each other. But innovative countries and multinational companies will not have monopoly advantages of high and new technology transfer to developing countries, it will be the core technology firmly in their own hands, developing countries are difficult to introduce the world's most advanced high technology.(4) The unique high-tech products market demandFirst of all, the international market demand for high-tech products rendering of irreversible one-way, new technology products will completely replace old technology products. Market demand is the motive force of high technology innovation, when a new and high technology products has been after the innovation, form and expand new market demand, which triggered a new round of high and new technology innovation, this new technology may replace the old technology, for example the digital mobile phone has fully replace simulator. Second, the international marketdemand for high-tech and derivative products, namely high-tech achievements can be derived into the related industries and products. A kind of new and high technology can be applied to many products, such as chip technology, digital technology; The emergence of a kind of new and high technology products will form a "chain reaction" and "diffusion effect", the cause and promote a group of related high-tech products, to form a new market demand, leading to the international high-tech products market demand, has the high growth potential..3 Related research progressesAbout high and new technology industry and its products export trade of existing research, most studies focused on the influence factors of high-tech products export, policy and way were analyzed. Study of high and new technology industry and trade products is necessary to draw lessons from the regional research results, combined with the actual do deeper analysis and research. Scholars for high-tech products export trade have their own different opinions; the following is related to the paper research content and views on some enlightenment in this paper.Ibarra (2005), first in Japan and the United States, two countries abroad high-tech exports as the basis, from the level of market openness, the development of science and technology and new high-tech product export trade strategy formulation and implementation, as well as technical ability to open made a comparative study on four aspects, such as; Second is high and new technology industry development as the research object, highlight different development advantages and characteristics of each region are analyzed, and its technical innovation, new achievements, talents technology equipped with relatively important position in the high-tech development.DM Bickford (2005), analyzes the actuality of high and new technology industry development, summarizes the development of high-tech industries with high industrial concentration and pillar industry is highlighted increasingly market-oriented, science and technology enterprises, and leading enterprise scale become the core strength of high and new technology industry development, etc, for the future development direction and development of new and high technology industries of Hunan road to give a clear argument.Reynolds (2003) of the new and high technology industries and products export trade at present situation analysis, for foreign trade in the international status and the present situation of high-tech products export is also analyzed, prominent is the export of products, computer and communication technology as a high-tech products and joint ventures rely on playing an increasingly important role in export trade, processing trade as a main way of trade continued its in new high-tech product export trade position that cannot be ignored.Williams (2007) for the sustainable development of high-tech products export were studied, combined with new high-tech product export in an increasing number of proportion in the total export, export enterprises and the quantity of varieties, mainly processing trade export trade way, using the method of SWOT, location advantages, industry foundation, enterprise competitive advantages of Shanghai hi-tech products export, is put forward in the new and high technology talent references, R&D investment, the establishment of the risk investment mechanism, improve innovation capability, and optimize the allocation of resources and so on should intensify their efforts to work and to promote the development of high and new technology industry better and faster.JB Berger (2005) studied the high and new technology industry development, think high-tech industrial output and exports have increased significantly, and increase in the number of science and technology plan projects at the same time, there exist some problems, such as policies and regulations do not coordinate with industry development needs, the system innovation lag, resources shortage, investment subject is single, intermediary services are relatively smaller also relatively backward, and so on, it has become the bottleneck of high and new technology industries and product export trade development.4 ConclusionsThe world economy the development level of high and new technology industry has become an important index to measure a country's economic strength. Therefore, promote the traditional industry to speed up the upgrading, improve the independent innovation ability, improve the proportion of high-tech industry in the economy hasbecome the top priority., therefore, in order to speed up the development of high-tech industries, must give the policy, capital, talent cultivation and attaches great importance to technology introduction and innovation, etc, to set up as soon as possible to promote the export of high-tech products to comprehensive policy supporting system.译文高新技术产品出口贸易研究Gaudier G摘要世界经济一体化程度的发展,使得国际贸易市场的竞争日趋激烈,突出表现为科技尤其是高新技术产品的竞争,高新技术产品的发展状况已成为国家竞争力的体现。

世界贸易和国际贸易外文文献及中文翻译

世界贸易和国际贸易外文文献及中文翻译World Trade and International TradeIn today’s complex economic world, neither individuals nor nations areself-sufficient. Nations have utilized different economic resources; people have developed different skills. This is the foundation of world trade and economic activity. As a result of this trade and activity, internationalfinance and banking have evolved.For example, the United States is a major consumer of coffee, yet it does not have the climate to grow any or its own. Consequently, the United States must import coffee from countries (such as Brazil, Colombia and Guatemala)that grow coffee efficiently. On the other hand, the United States has large industrial plants capable of producing a variety of goods, such as chemicals and airplanes, which can be sold to nations that need them. If nations traded item for item, such as one automobile for 10,000 bags of coffee, foreign trade would be extremely cumbersome and restrictive. So instead of batter, which is trade of goods without an exchange of money, the United State receives moneyin payment for what it sells. It pays for Brazilian coffee with dollars, which Brazil can then use to buy wool from Australia, which in turn can buy textiles Great Britain, which can then buy tobacco from the United State.Foreign trade, the exchange of goods between nations, takes place for many reasons. The first, as mentioned above is that no nation has all of the commodities that it needs. Raw materials are scattered around the world. Large deposits of copper are mined in Peru and Zaire, diamonds are mined in South Africa and petroleum is recovered in the Middle East. Countries that do not have these resources within their own boundaries must buy from countries that export them.Foreign trade also occurs because a country often does not have enough ofa particular item to meet its needs. Although the United States is a major producer of sugar, it consumes more than it can produce internally and thus must import sugar.Third, one nation can sell some items at a lower cost than other countries. Japan has been able to export large quantities of radios and television sets because it can produce them more efficiently than other countries. It is cheaper for the United States to buy these from Japan than to produce themdomestically. According to economic theory, Japan should produce and export those items from which it derives a comparative advantage. It should also buy and import what it needs from those countries that have a comparative advantage in the desired items.Finally, foreign trade takes place because of innovation or style. Even though the United States produces more automobiles than any other country, it still imports large numbers of autos from Germany, Japan and Sweden, primarily because there is a market for them in the United States.For most nations, exports and imports are the most important international activity. When nations export more than they import, they are said to have a favorable balance of trade. When they import more than they export, an unfavorable balance of trade exists. Nations try to maintain a favorable balance of trade, which assures them of the means to buy necessaryimports.International trade is the exchange ofgoods and services produced in one country for goods and services produced in another country. There are several reasons for it.The distribution lf natural resources around the world is somewhat haphazard: some nations possess natural deposits in excess of their own requirements while other nations have none. For example, Britain has large reserves of coal but lacks many minerals such as nickel, copper, aluminum etc, whereas the Arab states have vast oil deposits but little else. In the cultivation of natural products climates whereas others, such as citrus fruits, require a Mediterranean climate. Moreover, some nations are unable to produce sufficient of a particular product to satisfy a large home demand, for example, Britain and wheat. These are the reasons why international trade first began.With the development of manufacturing and technology, there arose another incentive for nations to exchange their products. It was found that it made economic sense for a nation to specialize in certain activities and produce those goods for which it had the most advantages, and to exchange those goods for the products of other nations which and advantages in different fields.This trade is based on the principle of comparative advantage.The theory of comparative advantage, also called the comparative cost theory, was developed by David Ricardo, and other economists in the nineteenth century. It points out that trade between countries can be profitable for all,even if one of the countries can produce every commodity more cheaply. As long as there are minor, relative differences in the efficiency of producing a commodity even the poof country can have a comparative advantage in producing it. The paradox is best illustrated by this traditional example: the best lawyer in town is also the best typist in town. Since this lawyer cannotafford to give up precious time from legal and typing matters. But thetypist’s comparative disadvantage is least in typing. Therefore, the typist has a relative comparative advantage in typing.This principle is the basis of specialization into trades and occupations. At the same time, complete specialization may never occur even when it is economically advantageous. For strategic or domestic reasons, a country may continue to produce goods for which it does not have an advantage. Thebenefits lf specialization may also be affecting by transport costs: goods and raw materials have to be transported around the world and the cost of the transport narrows the limits between which it will prove profitable to trade. Another impediment to the free flow of goods between nations is the possible introduction of artificial barriers to trade, such as tariffs or quotas.In addition to visible trade, which involves the import and export lf goods and merchandise, there is also invisible trade, which involves the exchange of services between nations.Nations such as Greece and Norway have large marine fleets and provide transportation service. This is a kind of invisible trade. When an exporter arranges shipment, he rents space in the cargo compartment or a ship.The prudent exporter purchases insurance for his cargo’s voyage. While at sea, a cargo is vulnerable to many dangers. Thus, insurance is another service in which some nations specialize. Great Britain, becauseof the development of Lloyd’s of L ondon, is a leading exporter of this service, earning fees for insuring other nations’ foreign trade.Some nations possess little in the way of exporter commodities or manufactured goods, but they have a mild and sunny climate. During the winter, the Bahamas attract large numbers of countries, who spend money for hotel accommodations, meals, taxis, and so on. Tourism, therefore, is another form of invisible trade.Invisible trade can be as important to some nations as the export of raw materials or commodities is to other. In both cases, the nations as the export of raw materials or commodities is to other. In both cases, the nations earn money to buy necessities.International trade today little resembles European commerce as it existed between the 16th century and the 19th century. Trade in earlier times was conducted largely between a mother country and its colonies. It was conducted according to strict mercantilist principles. The colonies were supposed to supply the mother country with raw materials, and they were expected to buyall finished goods from the mother country. Other forms of trade were forbidden to the colonies, but many of them evaded these restrictions.A result of the Industrial Revolution, which began in England in the 18th century, was the transformation of trade from a colonial exchange into a many sided international institution. Cottage industries gave way to mass production in factories. Railroads and steamships lowered the cost of transportation at the same time that new markets were being sought for the expanding output of goods.The Industrial Revolution also brought an end to mercantilist policies. The laissez-faire attitudes that emerged in their stead permitted businessmen to manufacture what they pleased and to trade freely with other nations. Trade was also stimulated by the growth of banking facilities, insurance companies, and improved commercial shipping and communications.The repeal of the Corn Laws by Great Britain in 1846 ended Britain’s longstanding policy of protectionism. During the 19th century, many European nations made commercial agreements with each other easing their tariff rates. Lower tariffs and the growth of population and industry caused trade to soarin the 19th century.In the 20th century two world wars and a major depression caused severe disturbances in international trade. Nations, sensing a threat to their domestic economies, sought to protect themselves from further disturbances by erecting various barriers to trade.The situation became even worse after Great Britain abandoned the gold standard. The nations that were closely related to Britain, including most of the members of the Commonwealth of gold standard. As the means of makinginternational payments broke down and trade restrictions increased, some countries had to resort to barter to obtain foreign goods.International trade was in such severe straits during the depression that a World Economic Conference was held in 1933. This conference, however, was unable to halt a rash of currency devaluations, tariff increases, and quota arrangements.In 1934, U.S. Secretary of State Cordell Hull persuaded Congress to pass the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act. This law authorized the President to negotiate tariff cuts with other nations. The Reciprocal Trade Act providedfor protection of U.S. industries in the event foreign imports increased to such a degree that U.S. businesses were injured. This protection includedperil point and escape clauses under which tariff cuts could by refused of rescinded if a U.S. industry suffered economic hardship. Despite the protectionist clauses in the act, U.S. tariffs were substantially reduced.Shortly before the end of World War Ⅱ, members of the United Nations met at Bratton Woods, N.H. to discuss ways of reducing the financial barriers to international trade. The International Monetary Fund was established as a result of the conference. The fund was designed to encourage the growth of international trade by stabilizing currencies and their rate of foreign exchange.In the early postwar period, more than 20 nations met in Geneva, Switzerland, to negotiate tariff reductions. When any two nations reached an agreement to reduce tariffs on a product, the benefits were extended to all participating nations. This was an application of the so-called most favored nation clause.The Geneva tariff agreements were written into the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). GATT also established standards for the conduct of international trade. Fox example, the agreement prohibits nations from placing quotas of limits on imports, except under very special circumstances.After World War Ⅱ a number of free trade areas were formed to solve trade problems on a regional basis. Tariffs on goods moving within these areas were to be abolished. Some of the groups also erected a single tariff on the goods of outsiders coming into their common area. Such groups are called customs unions. The goal of all trade blocs was to merge small political units intolarge geographic entities in which goods could be freely manufactured and sold.A large market area greatly stimulates economic growth and prosperity. These trade blocs are: Benelux, The European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC), the European Economic Community (EEC or Common Market), the European Free Trade Association (EFTA), the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECOM), the Latin American Free Trade Association (LAFTA), the Central American Common Market (CACM), the Caribbean Free Trade Area (CARIFTA), the Caribbean Community and Common Market (CARICOM).世界贸易和国际贸易在当今复杂的经济世界个人和国家都不是自给自足。

进出口贸易外文翻译文献

进出口贸易外文翻译文献(文档含英文原文和中文翻译)China’s Competitive Performance: A Threat To East Asian Manufactured Exports?There is growing concern in Southeast and East Asia about the competitive threat posed by China’s burgeoning exports, exacerbated by its accession to the WTO. The threat is not confined to labor-intensive products but spans the whole technological and skill range. At the same time, China is rapidly raising its imports from the region, and it is not clear whether its burgeoning exports will damage it s neighbors. We examine the dimensions of China’s competitive threat in the 1990s, benchmarking competitive performance by technology and market, and finds that market share losses are so far mainly in low technology products, with Japan being the most vulnerable market. We analyze market share changes and highlight product groups that are directly or indirectly exposed to a competitive threat. We examine intra-regional trade and find that China and its neighbors are raising high technology exports in tandem: the nature of theinternational production systems involved lead to complementarily rather than confrontation. China is thus acting as an engine of export growth for its neighbors in terms of direct trade. However, this will change as China moves up the value chain and takes on the activities that have driven East Asian export growth.IntroductionConcern about China’s competitive threat is widespread (in developed economies like US as well as developing ones like Mexico), but is strongest in East and So utheast Asia. China’s burgeoning exports–backed by cheap and productive labor, a large stock of technical manpower, huge and diversified industrial sector, attractiveness to foreign investors, pragmatic use of industrial policy, and, now, freer access to world markets under WTO – lead to apocalyptic visions of export losses.2 China is most threatening to neighbors that rely primarily on low wages for their export advantage. However, as it upgrades its export structure, the more advanced economies (Singapore, Hong Kong, Korea and Taiwan) also fear for their competitiveness. The current hollowing out of their low-end manufacturing may soon extend to complex production, design, development and related services. Domestic markets are also threatened by China, but so far most attention seems to have been on exports.Offsetting this threat are the promise of the giant Chinese market (WTO accession is only one of several initiatives to liberalize regional trade) and the potential for collaboration with it in exporting to the rest of the world. Trade within the East Asian region is flourishing. China is a growing importer from the region of natural resources that it does not possess. It is also raisin g imports of manufactured products. Its advanced neighbors are selling it sophisticated consumer and producer goods, and using it as a base for processing exports to third countries. The multinational companies (MNCs) that now account for around half of Chinese exports (and far more of its high technology exports, UNCTAD,2002) are incorporating China into production systems spanning the region (‘fragmentation’ and‘segmentation’ are used to describe this phenomenon3), so promoting considerable intra-firm trade with other regional bases. China’s own enterprises are likely t o specialize with respect to regional counterparts and so raise intra-industry trade in differentiated products. Perhapsworryingly for competitors in other regions, such integration can lead China to complement regional competitiveness as a whole, rather than substitute its exports for those of its neighbors.It is difficult to assess, however, whether complementarily between China and the regional economies will fully offset its competitive threat. The dynamics and complexity of the interactions make it impossible to quantify the outcome, even to predict broad directions. The basic issue is whether China’s higher wage neighbors can move into more advanced export activities or functions rapidly enough to permit continued export expansion. If they can, they can continue with export-led growth. If they cannot, they will suffer export deceleration and/or a shift in specialization towards primary products or slow-growing segments of manufactured exports. The outcome, in other words, will depend on the relative growth of technological and other capabilities in Chinese and regional enterprises, with the former having such advantages as lower wages, larger scale economies, greater industrial depth, pools of technical skill and a proactive government. However, as East Asian countries differ widely in these factors (Lall, 2001), they face different kinds and intensity of competitive threat. The nature of the threat depends, moreover, on the organization of the production and marketing system: independent local firms are likely to compete more directly than affiliates of the same MNC spread over different countries in an integrated system.This paper does not try to measure China’s competitive threat or its effects, but to map relative export performance in the 1990s by technology and destination and so assess where the threat appears most intense. We focus on major East Asian exporters5 and on exports to third markets, but we also analyses complementarities between China and East Asia, particularly in electronics, the re gion’s largest export and the one where MNC systems dominate. As the 1990s predate China’s WTO accession, we do not go into the implications of this accession; however, the analysis of competitive trends has implications for the evolution of future trade by the region as liberalization grows.Background on Chinese export performanceChinese manufactured exports grew by 16.9% per annum over 1990-2000, compared to 6.4% for the world, 12.0% for all developing countries and 10.3%for the rest of East Asia. Its share of world manufactured exports rose from 1.7% to 4.4% over the decade and continued rising rapidly. 6 Thus, by 2002 China accounted for 5.1% of world merchandise exports; it was then the fifth largest exporter (after USA, Germany, Japan and France, an d ahead of the UK). China’s share of developing world manufactured exports rose from 11% to 20% over the 1990s and of the East Asian region excluding China from 18.7% to 41.8%. Its export gains (see below) spanned the entire technological spectrum, and were most dynamic in the complex end of the range, in products that have recently driven the export growth of the rest of East Asia.This export surge is likely to be sustained for some time to come. China has ‘spare capacity’ in that its per capita exports are still relatively small,7 wages are much lower than in its main neighbors and it has large reserves of cheap and disciplined labor (though drawing it into exports will involve the cost of building links with the interior).8 More importantly, its advantages are not static (confined to cheap labor); they are upgrading rapidly. China is investing heavily in technology and advanced skills; for example, the share of the relevant age group enrolled in tertiary education rose from 9 percent in 1997 to 13 percent in 2000 (UNESCO website). It is exploiting the scale offered by its giant market to become competitive in capital-intensive activities beyond the reach of many neighbors. It is using its diverse industrial base to deepen local content. It is drawing in export-oriented FDI at an impressive rate, using its market attractions to induce investors to raise local R&D and linkages; till now it has been able to impose performance requirements of the type soon to be banned under WTO rules.WTO accession may constra in China’s ability to use industrial policy (Nolan, 2001) but it will also open up new export opportunities, particularly in textiles and garments.9 Accession may also enhance its domestic competitiveness: it will improve the investment climate for FDI, make imported inputs cheaper (for enterprises outside special export regimes) and induce faster restructuring of domestic enterprises (Ianchovichinaetal, 2003, and Lemoyne and Unal-Kesenci, 2002).Market share changes in major developed country marketsWe analyze market shares of China and its neighbors in three major markets: Japan, the US and West Europe, according to technology categories (Annex Table 1). In terms of value, the most important market for China in 2000 is the US ($49 billion), followed by Japan ($36 billion) and West Europe ($38 billion). However, the rest of the world is almost as large a destination for Chinese exports as these together ($106 billion in 2000) and within this the rest of East Asia is larger than any major OECD market by itself ($74.6 billion).The competitive position of each country can be analyzed in terms of the market share in 1990 and 2000 and the change over the decade. The annex table shows the following:Total manufactured exports: China does best in Japan, followed at some distance by the US. In common with most neighbors, its market share gain is weakest in West Europe. Korea loses market shares in both Japan and US, while Taiwan loses only in the US. Hong Kong’s loses market shares in all markets, particularly in the US and Japan. Like Taiwan, Singapore loses only in the US. The new Tigers gain share in all markets. With the exception of Indonesia, with a rather tepid performance, the others all gain most share in the Japanese market. Resource based products: China again leads the region in terms of market share increases, with a pattern similar to that for total exports. However, Korea has a large gain in Japan, in contrast to Taiwan and Singapore, which lose shares; the latter two also lose in the US. Thailand is a big gainer in Japan while Indonesia and the Philippines lose out in the US. Low technology products: China’s massive market share gains are again concentrated in Japan. The four mature Tigers generally suffer losses in market share, but Singapore sees an increase in Japanese market share. The best overall performance among the new Tigers is by Indonesia.Medium technology products: While the Chinese pattern of success recurs, the new Tigers make significant gains in Japan and Korea incurs a significant loss. Taiwan and Singapore suffer losses in the US market. High technology exports: Taiwan again diverges from Korea in its performance in Japan, the former showing the second largest gain in the group (after China) and the latter the largest loss. In the US market, the situation is reversed, with Singapore joiningTaiwan in losing market shares. Among the new Tigers, Malaysia and the Philippines are the big gainers in Japan, but the other two also benefit significantly. The Philippines is the second largest winner in the group in the US market. In sum, China’s main market share gains in the developed world are concentrated in Japan (though the US accounts for a larger dollar value of export growth). This is also true of its neighbors with the exceptions of Korea and Indonesia (Hong Kong was an all-round loser). To the extent that we can interpret market share changes to be causally related to China’s export surge, it would seem that the mature Tigers suffered the most from Chinese competition. The largest such loss is in low technology products, which is to be expected, but this not take into account the growth of LT exports by Korea and Taiwan to China. The relatively low gains by the lower-income new Tigers in LT may also reflect the impact of Chinese competition – without the offsetting increase in exports of intermediates to China.ConclusionsChina’s export surge has raised grave concerns in the region. While some of the apocalyptic predictions may have been overdone, it is certainly possible that rapid export growth by such a massive entrant will adversely affects export growth in its neighbors. As this analysis shows,however, the outcome is complex. For a start, the rise in China’s exports is matched by that in its imports – within the region its import growth outpaces its export growth. With appropriate restructuring of activities to match new competitive needs, its neighbors should be able to maintain high rates of export growth.There are two main drivers of regional exports to China. The first is to meet its burgeoning demand for imported products: primary products and resource-based manufactures that it cannot produce capital goods and intermediates for domestic -oriented production and more sophisticated consumer goods than its industry can currently provide. The second is to meet the needs of its export industries. This has two components: ‘processing’ activity in special economic zones that use imported inputs for export activities, and other exporters that also need imports. Processing activity is increasingly organized as part of integrated production systems, particularly its high technology segments, thoughsome domestic oriented industries are also being plugged into this system as they realize scale and learning economies and become globally competitive. Both drivers are likely to continue into the foreseeable future, though their composition will change as Chinese and regional capabilities develop.中国竞争力的表现:是对东亚制成品出口的威胁吗?越来越多的东南亚和东亚地区关注中国出口的迅速增长所带来的竞争威胁,中国加入WTO后,更加剧了这种情况。

  1. 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
  2. 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
  3. 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。

进出口贸易外文翻译文献(文档含英文原文和中文翻译)China’s Competitive Performance: A Threat To East Asian Manufactured Exports?There is growing concern in Southeast and East Asia about the competitive threat posed by China’s burgeoning exports, exacerbated by its accession to the WTO. The threat is not confined to labor-intensive products but spans the whole technological and skill range. At the same time, China is rapidly raising its imports from the region, and it is not clear whether its burgeoning exports will damage it s neighbors. We examine the dimensions of China’s competitive threat in the 1990s, benchmarking competitive performance by technology and market, and finds that market share losses are so far mainly in low technology products, with Japan being the most vulnerable market. We analyze market share changes and highlight product groups that are directly or indirectly exposed to a competitive threat. We examine intra-regional trade and find that China and its neighbors are raising high technology exports in tandem: the nature of theinternational production systems involved lead to complementarily rather than confrontation. China is thus acting as an engine of export growth for its neighbors in terms of direct trade. However, this will change as China moves up the value chain and takes on the activities that have driven East Asian export growth.IntroductionConcern about China’s competitive threat is widespread (in developed economies like US as well as developing ones like Mexico), but is strongest in East and So utheast Asia. China’s burgeoning exports–backed by cheap and productive labor, a large stock of technical manpower, huge and diversified industrial sector, attractiveness to foreign investors, pragmatic use of industrial policy, and, now, freer access to world markets under WTO – lead to apocalyptic visions of export losses.2 China is most threatening to neighbors that rely primarily on low wages for their export advantage. However, as it upgrades its export structure, the more advanced economies (Singapore, Hong Kong, Korea and Taiwan) also fear for their competitiveness. The current hollowing out of their low-end manufacturing may soon extend to complex production, design, development and related services. Domestic markets are also threatened by China, but so far most attention seems to have been on exports.Offsetting this threat are the promise of the giant Chinese market (WTO accession is only one of several initiatives to liberalize regional trade) and the potential for collaboration with it in exporting to the rest of the world. Trade within the East Asian region is flourishing. China is a growing importer from the region of natural resources that it does not possess. It is also raisin g imports of manufactured products. Its advanced neighbors are selling it sophisticated consumer and producer goods, and using it as a base for processing exports to third countries. The multinational companies (MNCs) that now account for around half of Chinese exports (and far more of its high technology exports, UNCTAD,2002) are incorporating China into production systems spanning the region (‘fragmentation’ and‘segmentation’ are used to describe this phenomenon3), so promoting considerable intra-firm trade with other regional bases. China’s own enterprises are likely t o specialize with respect to regional counterparts and so raise intra-industry trade in differentiated products. Perhapsworryingly for competitors in other regions, such integration can lead China to complement regional competitiveness as a whole, rather than substitute its exports for those of its neighbors.It is difficult to assess, however, whether complementarily between China and the regional economies will fully offset its competitive threat. The dynamics and complexity of the interactions make it impossible to quantify the outcome, even to predict broad directions. The basic issue is whether China’s higher wage neighbors can move into more advanced export activities or functions rapidly enough to permit continued export expansion. If they can, they can continue with export-led growth. If they cannot, they will suffer export deceleration and/or a shift in specialization towards primary products or slow-growing segments of manufactured exports. The outcome, in other words, will depend on the relative growth of technological and other capabilities in Chinese and regional enterprises, with the former having such advantages as lower wages, larger scale economies, greater industrial depth, pools of technical skill and a proactive government. However, as East Asian countries differ widely in these factors (Lall, 2001), they face different kinds and intensity of competitive threat. The nature of the threat depends, moreover, on the organization of the production and marketing system: independent local firms are likely to compete more directly than affiliates of the same MNC spread over different countries in an integrated system.This paper does not try to measure China’s competitive threat or its effects, but to map relative export performance in the 1990s by technology and destination and so assess where the threat appears most intense. We focus on major East Asian exporters5 and on exports to third markets, but we also analyses complementarities between China and East Asia, particularly in electronics, the re gion’s largest export and the one where MNC systems dominate. As the 1990s predate China’s WTO accession, we do not go into the implications of this accession; however, the analysis of competitive trends has implications for the evolution of future trade by the region as liberalization grows.Background on Chinese export performanceChinese manufactured exports grew by 16.9% per annum over 1990-2000, compared to 6.4% for the world, 12.0% for all developing countries and 10.3%for the rest of East Asia. Its share of world manufactured exports rose from 1.7% to 4.4% over the decade and continued rising rapidly. 6 Thus, by 2002 China accounted for 5.1% of world merchandise exports; it was then the fifth largest exporter (after USA, Germany, Japan and France, an d ahead of the UK). China’s share of developing world manufactured exports rose from 11% to 20% over the 1990s and of the East Asian region excluding China from 18.7% to 41.8%. Its export gains (see below) spanned the entire technological spectrum, and were most dynamic in the complex end of the range, in products that have recently driven the export growth of the rest of East Asia.This export surge is likely to be sustained for some time to come. China has ‘spare capacity’ in that its per capita exports are still relatively small,7 wages are much lower than in its main neighbors and it has large reserves of cheap and disciplined labor (though drawing it into exports will involve the cost of building links with the interior).8 More importantly, its advantages are not static (confined to cheap labor); they are upgrading rapidly. China is investing heavily in technology and advanced skills; for example, the share of the relevant age group enrolled in tertiary education rose from 9 percent in 1997 to 13 percent in 2000 (UNESCO website). It is exploiting the scale offered by its giant market to become competitive in capital-intensive activities beyond the reach of many neighbors. It is using its diverse industrial base to deepen local content. It is drawing in export-oriented FDI at an impressive rate, using its market attractions to induce investors to raise local R&D and linkages; till now it has been able to impose performance requirements of the type soon to be banned under WTO rules.WTO accession may constra in China’s ability to use industrial policy (Nolan, 2001) but it will also open up new export opportunities, particularly in textiles and garments.9 Accession may also enhance its domestic competitiveness: it will improve the investment climate for FDI, make imported inputs cheaper (for enterprises outside special export regimes) and induce faster restructuring of domestic enterprises (Ianchovichinaetal, 2003, and Lemoyne and Unal-Kesenci, 2002).Market share changes in major developed country marketsWe analyze market shares of China and its neighbors in three major markets: Japan, the US and West Europe, according to technology categories (Annex Table 1). In terms of value, the most important market for China in 2000 is the US ($49 billion), followed by Japan ($36 billion) and West Europe ($38 billion). However, the rest of the world is almost as large a destination for Chinese exports as these together ($106 billion in 2000) and within this the rest of East Asia is larger than any major OECD market by itself ($74.6 billion).The competitive position of each country can be analyzed in terms of the market share in 1990 and 2000 and the change over the decade. The annex table shows the following:Total manufactured exports: China does best in Japan, followed at some distance by the US. In common with most neighbors, its market share gain is weakest in West Europe. Korea loses market shares in both Japan and US, while Taiwan loses only in the US. Hong Kong’s loses market shares in all markets, particularly in the US and Japan. Like Taiwan, Singapore loses only in the US. The new Tigers gain share in all markets. With the exception of Indonesia, with a rather tepid performance, the others all gain most share in the Japanese market. Resource based products: China again leads the region in terms of market share increases, with a pattern similar to that for total exports. However, Korea has a large gain in Japan, in contrast to Taiwan and Singapore, which lose shares; the latter two also lose in the US. Thailand is a big gainer in Japan while Indonesia and the Philippines lose out in the US. Low technology products: China’s massive market share gains are again concentrated in Japan. The four mature Tigers generally suffer losses in market share, but Singapore sees an increase in Japanese market share. The best overall performance among the new Tigers is by Indonesia.Medium technology products: While the Chinese pattern of success recurs, the new Tigers make significant gains in Japan and Korea incurs a significant loss. Taiwan and Singapore suffer losses in the US market. High technology exports: Taiwan again diverges from Korea in its performance in Japan, the former showing the second largest gain in the group (after China) and the latter the largest loss. In the US market, the situation is reversed, with Singapore joiningTaiwan in losing market shares. Among the new Tigers, Malaysia and the Philippines are the big gainers in Japan, but the other two also benefit significantly. The Philippines is the second largest winner in the group in the US market. In sum, China’s main market share gains in the developed world are concentrated in Japan (though the US accounts for a larger dollar value of export growth). This is also true of its neighbors with the exceptions of Korea and Indonesia (Hong Kong was an all-round loser). To the extent that we can interpret market share changes to be causally related to China’s export surge, it would seem that the mature Tigers suffered the most from Chinese competition. The largest such loss is in low technology products, which is to be expected, but this not take into account the growth of LT exports by Korea and Taiwan to China. The relatively low gains by the lower-income new Tigers in LT may also reflect the impact of Chinese competition – without the offsetting increase in exports of intermediates to China.ConclusionsChina’s export surge has raised grave concerns in the region. While some of the apocalyptic predictions may have been overdone, it is certainly possible that rapid export growth by such a massive entrant will adversely affects export growth in its neighbors. As this analysis shows,however, the outcome is complex. For a start, the rise in China’s exports is matched by that in its imports – within the region its import growth outpaces its export growth. With appropriate restructuring of activities to match new competitive needs, its neighbors should be able to maintain high rates of export growth.There are two main drivers of regional exports to China. The first is to meet its burgeoning demand for imported products: primary products and resource-based manufactures that it cannot produce capital goods and intermediates for domestic -oriented production and more sophisticated consumer goods than its industry can currently provide. The second is to meet the needs of its export industries. This has two components: ‘processing’ activity in special economic zones that use imported inputs for export activities, and other exporters that also need imports. Processing activity is increasingly organized as part of integrated production systems, particularly its high technology segments, thoughsome domestic oriented industries are also being plugged into this system as they realize scale and learning economies and become globally competitive. Both drivers are likely to continue into the foreseeable future, though their composition will change as Chinese and regional capabilities develop.中国竞争力的表现:是对东亚制成品出口的威胁吗?越来越多的东南亚和东亚地区关注中国出口的迅速增长所带来的竞争威胁,中国加入WTO后,更加剧了这种情况。

相关文档
最新文档