外商直接投资,技术寻求和逆向技术溢出效应【外文翻译】
外商直接投资,技术寻求和逆向技术溢出效应【外文翻译】

外文翻译原文FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT, TECHNOLOGY SOURCING AND REVERSE SPILLOVERSMaterial Source:The Manchester School Vol 71 No. 6 December 2003 Author: NIGEL DRIFFIELD Business School, University of Birmingham And JAMES H. LOVE† Aston Business School, Aston University Recent theoretical work points to the possibility of foreign direct investment motivated not by ‘ownership’ advantages which may be exploited by a multinational enterprise but by the desire to access the superior technology of a host nation through direct investment. To be successful, technology sourcing foreign direct investment hinges crucially on the existence of domestic-to-foreign technological externalities within the host country. We test empirically for the existence of such ‘reverse spillover’ effects for a panel of UK manufacturing industries. The results demonstrate that technology generated by the domestic sector spills over to foreign multinational enterprises, but that this effect is restricted to relatively research and development intensive sectors. There is also evidence that these spillover effects are affected by the spatial concentration of industry, and that learning-by-doing effects are restricted to sectors in which technology sourcing is unlikely to be a motivating influence.1 IntroductionTraditional models of foreign direct investment (FDI) have been heavily influenced by a framework which suggests that where a company has some ‘ownership’(i.e. competitive) advantage over its rivals and wher e, for reasons of property rights protection, licensing is unsafe, a company will set up production facilities in a foreign country through FDI (Dunning, 1988). Since much of the discussion of ownership advantages is couched in terms of technology and/or m anagement expertise, there is a strong a priori assumption that this ‘technology exploiting’ FDI will be an important method by which technology is transferred internationally. Indeed, there is a growing literature concerned with the extent to which FDI contributes to technological advance in host countries. Much of thisanalysis is based on estimations of externalities from inward FDI, with the evidence generally pointing towards positive effects of FDI on domestic productivity (Blomström and Kokko, 1998).However, the literature is increasingly turning to the possibility that FDI may be influenced by multinational firms’ desire not to exploit an existing ownership advantage abroad but to acquire technology from the host country, i.e. that ‘technology sourcing’ may be the motive for FDI. Kogut and Chang (1991) and Neven and Siotis (1996) point out that this possibility has exercised the minds of policy-makers in the USA and the EU, with concerns that host economies’ technological base may be undermined by technology sourcing by Japanese and US corporations respectively. These studies examine the effects of host versus home country research and development (R&D) expenditure differentials on FDI flows between Japan and the USA and the USA and the EU respectively. Both studies find a positive relationship between these measures, and interpret this as evidence of technology sourcing. The literature on the internationalization of R&D also contains an increasing amount of evidence that technology sourcing may be a motive for FDI (Cantwell, 1995; Cantwell and Janne, 1999; Pearce, 1999).This literature stresses a range of reasons for FDI in R&D, much of which is concerned with the relative technological strengths of the capital exporting (i.e. ‘home’) firm or country v ersus that of the host. For example, Kuemmerle (1999) distinguishes between ‘home-base exploiting’ FDI and‘home-base augmenting’ FDI. The former is undertaken in order to exploit firm-specific advantages abroad, while the latter is FDI undertaken to access unique resources and capture externalities created locally. And in an analysis of inward and outward FDI in 13 industrialized countries, van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie and Lichtenberg (2001) find positive spillover effects from outward FDI arising from accessing the R&D capital stock of host countries, leading them to conclude that FDI flows are predominantly technology sourcing in nature.Recent theoretical work represents an important step forward in this area, with Fosfuri and Motta (1999) and Siotis (1999) both presenting formal models of the FDI decision which embody the possibility of technology sourcing. They show that a firm may choose to enter a market by FDI in order to access positive spillover effects arising from close locational proximity to a technological leader in the host country. Because of the externalities associated with technology, these spillovers decrease the production costs of the investing firm both in its subsidiary operations and in its home production base. Siotis (1999) also shows that the presence ofspillovers may induce firms to invest abroad even where exporting costs are zero.The theoretical and empirical work reviewed above hinges crucially on the assumption that foreign firms investing in a host economy are able to capture spillover effects from the domestic (host) industry. The purpose of this paper is to test for the existence of this ‘reverse spillover’ effect for a panel of UK industries. If there is some evidence of productivity spillovers running from the domestic to the foreign sector of UK industry, this would suggest that the necessary condition for technology sourcing FDI does exist in practice. In addition to testing empirically for reverse spillover effects we also test for two elements which are implicit in the theoretical analysis: first, that the spatial concentration of production has an effect on productivity spillovers; and second, that learning-by-doing effects are linked to the investing motivations of foreign firms.2 THE MOTIV ATION FOR FDI, SPILLOVERS AND FIRM GROWTHFosfuri and Motta (1999) present a simple model in which two local (i.e. single country) firms are endowed with different technologies and are given the option of exporting to the other country, engaging in FDI or not entering. They show formally that an investing firm which is a technological laggard (i.e. has unit costs of production above those of its competitor) will find it profitable to invest abroad despite having an efficiency disadvantage, as long as the probability of acquiring the leader’s technology through productivity spillovers is sufficiently high. In other words, ‘technology sourcing’ rather than ‘technology exploiting’ FDI may occur. Siotis (1999) develops a similar model, but allows for the possibility of two-way spillovers between foreign and domestic firms. He too finds theoretical support for technology sourcing as a motivation for FDI.It seems plausible that the probability of benefiting from productivity spillovers will at least in part be dependent on the actions of the firms concerned, and that the scope for spillovers, particularly in the context of technology sourcing investment, will vary with the research efforts of domestic firms. Thus technology sourcing is most likely to occur where the scope for productivity externalities to be assimilated by foreign firms is greatest; this in turn is a positive function of the R&D intensity of domestic industry. We therefore anticipate reverse spillover effects being most apparent in those sectors in which domestic industry has invested heavily in R&D; these are the sectors in which the probability of acquiring technology through spillovers is greatest and in which technology sourcing FDI is most likely to occur. However, traditional explanations for FDI based on the exploitation offirm-specific‘ownership’ advantages shou ld not be ignored. Siotis (1999)shows that where a foreign firm has an ownership (i.e. efficiency) advantage relative to domestic firms, FDI will only occur if spillovers are likely to be small (the ‘dissipation effect’). We therefore anticipate technology exploiting FDI to be most likely where there is little scope for reverse spillovers, i.e. where domestic industry does not invest heavily in R&D. Reverse spillover effects should therefore be most evident in relatively research intensive sectors, but absent or less evident in sectors which are relatively non-research intensive.Two further and related hypotheses can also be tested. The first relates to the growth paths exhibited by firms that have different motivations for FDI. To the extent that it is possible to make the distinction between technology sourcing and technology exploiting FDI, then it is also likely that the patterns of development arising from these forms of investment will be different. This is likely to be important in the study of the development of total factor productivity in the foreign owned sector, following the theory of the multinational enterprise dating back to Dunning (1958) and more explicitly outlined in the seminal papers by Vernon (1966), Buckley and Casson (1976) or Dunning (1979). The traditional explanation of the existence of multinational enterprises is that firms transfer firm-specific assets across national boundaries but internalized within the firm (technology exploiting FDI). Firms operating in the foreign country then have to undertake the process of adapting this technology to a new environment, to take account of local working practices, available human capital and customers’ tastes for example. This is neither costless nor instantaneous, and so total factor productivity of foreign investment motivated in this ‘traditional’ manner is likely to demonstrate experience effects and significant learning-by-doing effects. By contrast, firms motivated by technology sourcing are less likely to undergo this adaptation of internal technology: their concern is not with adapting existing technology but in assimilating knowledge generated externally, in this case by local firms.Of course, in some cases the extent of adaptation by technology exploiting firms may be minimal in certain markets, while technology sourcing subsidiaries may undergo some degree of adaptation, so that the relative extent of learning by doing is ultimately an empirical issue. On balance, however, we expect significant learning by-doing effects among technology exploiting foreign firms, but perhaps not in the technology sourcing firms, where spillovers from domestic investments are likely to contribute more to total factor productivity in the foreign sector.The second subsidiary hypothesis relates to the extent to which technological externalities are constrained spatially. The theoretical analysis of Siotis (1999) depends on the existence of geographically localized spillovers to provide an incentive for technology sourcing FDI; Fosfuri and Motta (1999) also acknowledge this geographical dimension to spillovers. Empirically, there is significant evidence that technology spillovers are indeed limited geographically within countries, as well as between them (Head et al., 1995; Driffield, 1999). This suggests that reverse spillovers may be linked to the spatial distribution of industry; we therefore test whether the spatial concentration of production has an effect on the scale of productivity spillovers running from domestic to foreign industry.译文外商直接投资,技术寻求和逆向技术溢出效应资料来源:曼彻斯特大学学报71卷第6期作者:奈杰尔•德里菲尔德英国伯明翰大学商学院;詹姆斯H.爱阿斯顿商学院,阿斯顿大学近期的理论研究表明,外商直接投资的动机可能不是“所有权”优势,而是跨国公司希望通过直接投资积极利用东道国的先进技术。
外文翻译--FDI的溢出和后向关联效应:来自英国的经验性证据

本科毕业论文外文翻译外文题目:Spillover and Backward Linkage Effects of FDI:Empirical Evidence of the UK出处: Spatial Economics Research Centre作者:Richard Harris译文:FDI的溢出和后向关联效应:来自英国的经验性证据摘要近来,在研究FDI的影响时(包括作者本人)多是基于微观层面(即公司、机构或者工厂)数据的,因为这将使我们在回答一些问题的时候有更大的把握,比如外商直接投资的工厂是更有生产力还是更有创新力,外商直接投资是否会对本土企业产生溢出效应,以及外资工厂是否可以促进产业集群的建立等。
传统的研究方法(在文献中仍普遍存在)考虑产业和/或地区是否有最好的FDI投资经验,是否有更高的生产力、成长力、溢出效应和集群影响,但这种分析方法没有从原因和效应方面解决问题,因此要对一个产业或地区的FDI增长和它总体增长之间的关系进行多一点的观察。
如果外商直接投资能够进入更有表现力的产业和/或“地区”(受益于自己的潜在溢出效应),那么这并不等于外商直接投资一定会成为更大经济利益的来源。
因此本文的目的在于为英国(近期的和历史的)反映经验性证据,具体涉及到:第一、外商直接投资企业是不是更好(即拥有更高的生产力,或更有创新力),以及预测FDI是否会更好;第二、FDI是否会产生溢出效应;(3)是不是要在外商直接投资的工厂周围建立产业集群。
本文对以证据为基础的局限性也进行了讨论,并与研究结果一起反映在文献中,这引出了一些在今后的实证工作中需要加以解决的关键性研究问题,特别是在英国的空间水平上。
关键词:跨国公司;FDI;溢出一、简介本文对跨国公司如何影响英国生产力作了文献概述。
文章的重点是进入英国的外商直接投资,但报告也提到了对外直接投资对英国生产力的影响。
文章涵盖的问题包括用来测量生产力和生产力影响的数据,以及如何进行测量(包括使用的技术)。
外国直接投资与技术溢出

外国直接投资与技术溢出外国直接投资(Foreign Direct Investment)是指一个国家的投资者通过购买或控制另一个国家企业的产权,从而在被投资国内从事生产和经营活动。
外国直接投资既能为被投资国带来资金和技术,也能促进跨国企业的国际化发展。
随着全球经济一体化的进程加快,外国直接投资对于世界经济的影响日益显著。
外国直接投资的理论基础可以追溯到跨国公司理论。
跨国公司是个体经济实体通过在其他国家设立分子公司或参股企业实现跨国经营的一种组织形式。
跨国公司的出现,为外国直接投资提供了理论和实践的基础。
早期的跨国公司主要是为了获取资源和市场,并通过本国企业的控制来确保跨国经营的顺利进行。
但随着国际贸易和信息技术的发展,跨国公司也越来越注重技术创新和知识产权的保护,外国直接投资也逐渐成为获取技术溢出的重要手段。
技术溢出是指外国直接投资引入的技术和管理经验对于被投资国的经济发展产生积极影响。
首先,外国直接投资可以促进技术的引进和消化吸收。
获得外国直接投资的国家通常会享受到外方先进技术的借鉴和转移,从而缩短技术差距,提高生产能力和产业竞争力。
其次,外国直接投资还可以帮助被投资国提升技术创新能力。
跨国公司往往在全球范围内开展研发活动,将先进的研发成果引入到被投资国,并与本地资源和市场相结合,促进本土创新能力的提升。
最后,外国直接投资还能够带动产业配套和供应链的发展。
跨国公司在投资国设立的分公司和合作企业需要与当地企业合作,形成完整的产业链,从而提升整个产业的技术水平。
然而,外国直接投资带来的技术溢出并非一帆风顺。
首先,技术溢出的效果因国别、行业、投资方式等因素而异。
一些发展中国家在吸引外国直接投资时更多地关注经济效益,而忽视技术溢出的潜力。
其次,技术溢出对本土企业的冲击也需要警惕。
在技术创新能力相对薄弱的国家,外国直接投资可能会导致本土企业的技术和资源依赖加剧,影响其自主创新的能力。
为了促进外国直接投资的技术溢出效果,国家和地区应采取相应的政策和措施。
外商直接投资技术外溢效应研究的开题报告

外商直接投资技术外溢效应研究的开题报告一、研究背景随着全球化进程的不断推进,外商直接投资(Foreign Direct Investment,FDI)在国际经济中的地位和作用逐渐显现。
从撬动国内经济发展的角度看,各国政府高度重视吸引外来投资,加强投资环境建设、优化政策体系等,希望确保外来投资的顺利进行。
然而,外来投资不仅带来了资金、人才、市场和管理等多方面的资源,也可能带来技术方面的支持和帮助。
外资企业深入开展技术合作、转移技术、建设技术研发中心,成为新技术、新产品、新工艺研发的“推手”,对于国内企业的技术进步和创新起到了积极的促进作用,促进了经济的发展。
二、研究目的本研究旨在深入分析外商直接投资技术外溢效应的产生机理和影响因素,并通过实证研究评估外资企业技术外溢效应对于国内企业技术进步的促进作用。
三、研究内容1.外商直接投资技术外溢效应的定义和评价标准2.外商直接投资技术外溢效应的产生机理和影响因素3.实证分析外资企业技术外溢对我国企业技术创新和进步的促进作用4.政策建议四、研究方法首先,对不同经济体对外资技术外溢效应的评价标准进行整合,对外资技术外溢效应的定义和性质进行系统阐述。
其次,选取我国经济体系中外资企业与国内企业技术关联度较高的若干个行业作为研究对象,采用可比样本研究方法,建立回归模型,考察外资企业技术产权保护、企业规模、人力资本、行业竞争等因素对我国企业技术进步的促进作用。
五、研究意义本研究能够探究外商直接投资技术外溢效应的产生机理和影响因素,进一步了解外资企业在技术领域的优势和劣势,并能够对外资企业进一步提高技术转移和技术合作的能力提出有针对性的建议,更好地推动技术进步和经济发展。
外商直接投资外文翻译

外文翻译之一To share or not to share: Does local participation matter for spillovers from foreign direct investment? Author(s):Beata Smarzynska Javorcik and Mariana Spatareanu Nationality:U.S.Source:“To share or not to share: Does local participation matter f or spillovers from foreign direct investment?” Journal of Development Economics, Article in press1. IntroductionAlthough domestic equity ownership requirements used to be extensively utilized by governments in developing countries,2 their incidence has sharply declined in recent years (UNCTAD, 2003). Increasingly competitive environment for foreign direct investment (FDI) and the need to comply with international commitments have put pressure on governments to relax restrictions on foreign entrants.One of the original motivations for the existence of ownership sharing conditions was the belief that local participation in foreign investment projects reveals their proprietary technology and thus benefits domestic firms by facilitating technology diffusion (see Beamish, 1988 and Blomström and Sjöholm, 1999). As writing a contract specifying all aspects of the rights to use intangible assets is difficult, if not impossible, joint domestic and foreign ownership of an investment project is more likely to lead to knowledge dissipation. A local partner may use the knowledge acquired from the foreign investor in its other operations not involving the foreign shareholders or being in charge of hiring policies, as is often the case, the local partner may have less incentive to limit employee turnover.3 This problem is reduced when the multinational is the sole owner of its affiliate.4As a consequence, multinationals may be more likely to transfer sophisticated technologies and management techniques to their wholly owned subsidiaries than to partially owned affiliates.5This in turn has implications for knowledge spillovers to local producers in a host country. Less sophisticated technologies being transferred to jointly owned FDI projects may be easier to absorb by local competitors, which combined with a better access to knowledge through the actions of the local shareholder may lead to greater intra-industry (or horizontal) knowledge spillovers being associated with the shared ownership structure than with wholly owned foreign affiliates. Moreover, lower sophistication of inputs needed by jointly owned FDI projects and the familiarity of the local partner with local suppliers of intermediates may result in greater reliance on locally produced inputs and thus greater vertical spillovers accruing to local producers in upstream sectors. While a lot of research effort has been put into looking for the evidence of FDI spillovers (see the next section), little attention has been devoted to how the ownership structure affects this phenomenon.6This paper is a step forward in understanding the implications of the ownership structure of FDI projects for the host country. Using firm-level panel data from Romania for the 1998–2003 period, we examine whether wholly owned foreign affiliates and investments with joint domestic and foreign ownership are associated with a different magnitude of spillovers within the industry of operation and to upstream sectors supplying intermediate inputs. The results suggest that the ownership structure in FDI projects does matter for productivity spillovers.Consistent with our expectations, the analysis indicates that projects with joint domestic and foreign ownership are associated with positive productivity spillovers to upstream sectors but no such effect is detected for wholly owned foreign subsidiaries. The difference between the two coefficients is statistically significant. The magnitude of the former effect is economically meaningful. A one-standard-deviation increase in the presence of investment projects with shared domestic and foreign ownership is associated with a 4.4% increase in the total factor productivity of domestic firms in the supplying industries. This pattern can be found at the national as well as at the regional level. It holds for both best performers in each sector as well as for firm exhibiting lesser performance. The presence of joint ventures in downstream sectors benefits domestic firms but has no effect on foreign affiliates.In contrast to the vertical effects, the presence of FDI appears to have a negative effect on the performance of local firms operating in the same sector. As argued by Aitken and Harrison (1999), this may be due to the fact that local producers lose part of their market share to foreign entrants and thus are forced to spread their fixed cost over a smaller volume of production. The empirical literature suggests that the negative competition effect outweighs the positive effect of knowledge spillovers in developing countries (Aitken and Harrison, 1999, Djankov and Hoekman, 2000 and Konings, 2001). If greater knowledge dissipation tends to be associated with jointly owned FDI projects, we would expect that FDI with shared ownership has a less negative effect on local producers than do wholly owned foreign projects. Our findings are consistent with this expectation, as in all specifications we find the anticipated pattern. The difference between the magnitudes of the two coefficients is statistically significant for sectors with domestic-market orientation, in the subsample of foreign firms and in the regressions focusing on regional spillovers.While our findings are consistent with the existence of externalities associated with FDI, a word of caution is in order. We use the term ”spillovers” very broadly as our methodology does not allow us to distinguish between pure knowledge externalities, the benefits of scale economies that may be enjoyed by suppliers to multinationals or the effects of increased competition resulting from foreign entry into the product market. More work is certainly needed to fully understand the effects of FDI inflows on host countries.Our findings should not be interpreted as suggesting that restrictions on the extent of foreign ownership are desirable, as such restrictions may lead to lower overall FDI inflows and have other implications not addressed in our analysis. There exist other policies that could potentially be used to facilitate local sourcing by multinationals, such as improvements to the business climate or supplier development programs that assist local producers in learning how to satisfy requirements of foreign buyers. In any case, more research is needed to enhance our understanding of host country conditions facilitating knowledge spillovers from foreign direct investment and the role government policies may play in this area.能分享还是无分享:地方参与真的能从外商直接投资中获得溢出吗?作者:比阿塔·司马新斯卡·加沃斯克和玛瑞安娜·斯帕塔瑞奴国籍:美国出处:发展经济学期刊正在出版中1、引言尽管国内资产所有要求被广大发展中国家政府广泛地利用,近几年来它们的影响力急剧地下降,对外商来说越来越激烈的竞争环境以及需要遵守国际条约的压力迫使镇古放松外国进入者的限制。
外文翻译--中国外商直接投资与技术外溢

本科毕业论文外文翻译外文题目:FDI and Technology Spillover in China出处: Center for Economic Institutions作者:Sea Jin Chang, Jaiho Chung and Dean Xu译文:中国外商直接投资与技术外溢摘要利用中国企业数据库,我们研究了外国进入者和当地企业之间,以及“现代化”的当地企业之间的技术溢出效应。
我们的研究结果表明,行业内跨国公司的增加对当地企业上游部门的生产率具有积极的影响。
当中国政府对外国所有权的限制被取消,来自于外资企业的积极的产业内溢出效应会变得明显。
另外,我们还发现当地企业之间强烈的溢出效应。
关键词:外商直接投资,溢出效应,中国促进外商直接投资一直是决策者的主要关注点,特别是在发展中国家。
外国直接投资预计将迫使当地企业提高技术效率,当地企业也可以从FDI技术溢出中获得好处。
例如,中国政府鼓励外商直接投资,以支撑落后的产业。
关于FDI 东道国效应的大型文献已经证明了这些政策问题。
过去关于溢出效应的文献主要考察了各行业当地企业生产率和外商独资子公司份额之间的关系。
大部分早期的行业层面的研究是利用截面数据进行的(如Caves,1974;Blömstrom,1986),这些研究证实了正向的FDI溢出效应的存在。
然而,对溢出效应的实证研究结果好坏参半。
一些研究已经证明了正向溢出效应的存在(Hejazi和Safarian,1999;Javorcik,2004;Keller,2002;Liu,Siler,Wang和Wei,2000)。
另外有些研究提出了相反的结论(Aitken和Harrison,1999;Konings,2001),或者发现溢出效应只作用于其他跨国公司(Feinberg 和Majumdar,2001)。
此外,一些争辩说,外国公司构成足够的竞争威胁,他们可能会打击当地企业利润空间,最终“排挤”他们(Blomstrom,Kokko和Zejan,2000;Caves,1996;De Backer和Sleuwaegen,2003)。
-外商直接投资和技术溢出泰国制造业的一个跨行业分析外文翻译 学士学位论文
毕业论文(设计)外文翻译一、外文原文Foreign direct investment and Technology Spillover: A Cross-industry Analysis of Thai ManufacturingImportance of the issueForeign direct investment (FDI) has been widely recognized as a growth-enhancing factor in investment receiving (host) countries. FDI not only brings in capital but also introduces advanced technology that can enhance the technological capability of the host country firms, thereby generating long-term and sustainable economic growth. More importantly, the technological benefit is not limited to locally affiliated firms but can also spread to non-affiliated ones. The latter benefit is usually referred to as technology spillover.The expectation of gaining from technology spillover persuades many developing countries to offer various incentives in order to attract FDI. However the results of empirical research to test the validity of technology spillover are far from conclusive. Positive technology spillover from FDI has only been found in some countries.1 Overall, the findings seem to suggest technology spillover is not automatic, but depends on both country specific factors and policy environment.Foreign Presence in Thai ManufacturingThirdly, foreign plants are likely to be located in a highly protected industry. The average ERP2 of industries whose output shares of foreign plants are greater than 50% is 15.3%. The exception in these industries would be electrical machinery which is presumably dominated by labor-intensive assembled electronics and electrical appliances. On the other hand, regarding the industries where the share of foreign plants is less than 50%, average ERP tends to be lower at around 10.8%. In addition, the output share of foreign plants is likely to be associated with the degree of market concentration.Involvement of foreign plants in the manufacturing sector was predominately inimport substituting industries such as textiles, automobiles, and chemicals up to about the late 1970s (Akira, 1989). From then on, it was directed to more export-oriented activities. To begin with, export-oriented foreign firms entered light manufacturing industries such as clothing, footwear, and toys. More recently, labor-intensive assembly activities in electronics and electrical goods industries have been the main attraction for foreign investors (Kohpaiboon, 2005).Such involvement has closely mirrored the shift in the trade policy regime. Thailand began its first national economic development plan in 1961 with an import substitution (IS) regime to promote industrialization. Tariffs were the major instrument used to influence the country’s development path. The role of tariffs to promote the domestic industry effectively began in 1974 with the imposition of an escalating tariff structure, where the tariff rate ascended from raw materials to finished products. These changes increasingly favored the production of finished products, particularly consumer products. In 1975, the range of the effective rate of protection (ERP) in the Thai manufacturing sector was between –36 to 350% (Akrasanee & Ajanant, 1986). In 1982, the variation widened from –25.2 to 1,693.4% (Chunanantathum et al.1984). Several industries, such as textiles, tyres, furniture, automobiles, and leather products, had an extremely high ERP. There was also a high degree of variation in ERP across industries. This tariff structure remained virtually unchanged until the late 1980s, even though in 1974 the government announced a change in development strategy to an export promotion (EP) regime.Significant tariff reductions commenced in 1988, starting with electrical and electronic goods as well as with the inputs into these products. Comprehensive packages of tariff reform were implemented in 1995 and 1997. It involved tariff reduction and rationalization. Maximum tariffs were reduced from 100% in the early 1990s to 30%. By the end of the 1990s, the tariff bands were reduced from 39 to 6 tariff rates (0, 1, 5, 10, 20 and 30%). The two low rates (0 and 1%) were for raw materials and the two top rates (20 and 30%) for finished products with the two middle rates for intermediate goods. In addition, tariff restructuring has received renewed emphasis as an essential part of the overall economic reforms aimed at strengthening efficiency and competitiveness over the past two years. The Thaigovernment introduced another effort to lower tariff rates, commencing in June 2003 (implemented in October 2003), followed by a fouryear period of tariff reduction from 2004 to 2008. There are around 900 items involved in the second round of tariff reductions, covering a wide range of manufacturing products. The tariff reduction in this round is mainly on intermediate products, thereby maintaining the escalating tariff structure. The magnitude of tariff reduction is moderate, within the range of 0 to 8.9% (Athukorala et al. 2004).As a result, average tariffs declined markedly from 30.2% in 1990 to 21.3% in 1995 and further to 11% in 2005. The dispersion of ERP also narrowed over the periods across industries. In 2003, the ERP range reduced to -27.1 to 142% (Athukorala et al. 2004).4 The changes in the tariff structure would have significantly improved the incentive to attract FDI to industries where Thailand has a comparative advantage in international production.Analytical FrameworkTechnology spillover from FDI is said to take place when the presence of a foreign firm generates productivity or efficiency benefits for the host country’s local non-affiliated firms (Blomström & Kokko,1998). As mentioned, technology spillover from FDI is not automatic but rather conditioned on the nature of the trade policy regime across industries. A theoretical framework for examining the effect of the trade policy regime on the gains from FDI in a given host country was first presented by Bhagwati (1973) as an extension to his theory of immiserizing growth. It was further developed by Bhagwati (1985, 1994); Brecher & Diaz-Alejandro (1977); and Brecher & Findlay (1983). A key hypothesis arising from this literature is that technology spillover tends to be smaller, or possibly even negative, under a restrictive, import substitution (IS) regime compared with a liberalizing, export promotion (EP) regime.To illustrate how technology spillover takes place as well as how the trade policy regime across industries can alter the magnitude of these spillovers as suggested by Bhagwati (1973), we use the theoretical model developed by Wang & Blomström (1992). In the model, there are two firms, namely an affiliate of a multinationalenterprise (MNE) and a local non-affiliated firm (henceforth referred to as the ‘foreign’ and ‘local’ firms, respectively), producing differentiated but substitutable products for the host country market. Technology spillover is an outcome of interaction of these two firms. On the one hand, the entry of a foreign firm is always associated with some amount of proprietary technology from the parent company so as to offset the potential disadvantage against the local firm possessing superior knowledge of the availability of factor inputs, business practices and/or consumer preferences in the host country. In addition, advanced technology would help the foreign firm to gain market share in the host country. However transferring technology from MNE’s headquarter to its affiliates are costly. The m ore the advance level of technology transferred, the larger the dollar costs associated with the transfer.Because of the presence of cost and benefit, the foreign firm has to decide the effort of undertaking technology transferred from its headquarter to maximize its net benefit. Such effort would depend on the local firm’s response to the presence of the foreign firm. In a situation where the local firm actively puts in the effort to learn the advanced technology associated with the foreign firm, the technology superiority of the latter will not last long. As the result, it will need to keep undertaking technology transfer activities in the following period in order to maintain the advantage or even to just survive in the host country environment. In contrast, a situation where the local firm is less responsive in attempting to learn the associated technology provides relatively less incentive for the foreign firm to continue to actively undertake technology transfers from its parent company.On the other hand, the local firm can observe, learn, and adapt superior technology associated with the foreign firm to enhance its own technological capability. This is because the technology accompanied with the foreign firm has certain public good qualities, which cannot be fully internalized, thus the localization of the foreign firm could potentially generate positive externality in terms of technological benefit to the local firm. Since the market success of each firm depends on the level of technology it employs, this encourages the local firm to learn the associated superior technology. Nevertheless, the effort of learning and adapting the associated technology is associated with the dollar amount of cost so that the localfirm has to decide its effort to learn associated advanced technology. Similar to the foreign firm, the learning effort of the local firm also depends on the foreign firm behavior.To incorporate the ‘Bhagwati hypothesis’, the model discussed above is modified by hypothesizing that the trade policy regime influences the cost effectiveness in the learning activities of the local firm. That is, every effort to enhance the technological capability of the local firm is more costly in any industry where the trade regime is more restrictive. This is because much of the FDI flowing to an industry with high trade restrictions often enters relatively capital- and skill-intensive products where output is mainly supplied for a highly protected domestic market. Although the production technology associated with FDI is typically older and less advanced than used in the MNE’s home country, it is often relatively capital-and skill-intensive compared to those employed by the local firm. In this environment, it is more difficult for the local firm to learn the advanced technology. Instead the highly protected domestic market might encourage the local firm to produce products not directly competitive with those being produced by the foreign affiliate and to enjoy economic rents induced by the regime. Kokko (1994) refers to this as a situation where the foreign affiliate in such an industry may operate in ‘enclaves’ in isolation from the local firm.In contrast, in the context of a liberal trade regime, technology spillover from a foreign presence is likely to generate a more productivity enhancing effect. This is because the main incentives for FDI in a given host country are the relatively low labor costs and/or availability of raw materials. FDI inflows under an EP trade regime can be expected to employ technologies mo re in line with the host country’s comparative advantage. A higher level of policy neutrality creates a higher likelihood for MNEs to become involved with the host country’s production to serve their strategy for maintaining a competitive position in international markets. With this motivation, the associated advanced technology will be cutting edge and make use of existing resource endowments in the host country (Moran, 2001). Under these circumstances, it is easier for the demonstration effect of foreign involvement in the host country to operate. Global competition makes all economic agents actively seektechnological innovation to improve efficiency.ConclusionThis paper examines technology spillover from FDI based on a cross-industry analysis of Thai manufacturing. The prime objective has been to test the ‘Bhagwati hypothesis’ that technology spillover is unlikely to take place in highly trade-restricted industries compared to more exportoriented ones. In order to allow for the simultaneity between sectoral productivity and the foreign presence, this study uses a system of two equations (productivity determinants and FDI determinants) to test the key hypothesis. The regression results fail to reject the ‘Bhagwati hypothesis’. There is also evidence that trade barriers as well as the size of the domestic market play an important role in determining inter-industry differences in FDI participation. These findings also support the Bhagwati hypothesis. In sum, the results suggest that liberalizing the foreign investment regime while retaining a restrictive trade policy is likely to induce the type of FDI inflows that is unlikely to introduce technology spillover.二、翻译文章外商直接投资和技术溢出:泰国制造业的一个跨行业分析问题的重要性外商直接投资已被广泛确认为是对接受投资的国家的一种促进增长的要素。
国际投资与技术溢出效应
FDI溢出效应与自主技术创新效率
结论:异质性溢出效应
(1)FDI 进入对内资企业创新效率提高具有显著的正向促进作用 (2)FDI 溢出对内资企业自主创新效率的正向溢出效应相对较强 (3)有助于内资企业在技术创新中更好地吸纳FDI 的正向溢出效应。
政策建议
(1)创造良好的制度和金融环境 (2)加大对先进技术的消化-吸收-再创新投入 (3)加大该行业对外开放力度
C大ont,en说t d明esi模gn,型10拟y合ear优s e度xp较eri好en。ce 系数均为 负值,表明FDI 进入对内资企业创新效 率提高具有显著的正向促进作用。
FDI知识外溢和东道国政策:伊朗模式
主题 结论 实证方法
FDI知识外溢和东道国政策:伊朗模式
主题:分析东道主国家对FDI知识外溢上有关 政策带来的影响。
FDI溢出效应与自主技术创新效率
实证方法
wele to use these PowerPoint templates, New (一)模型设定:生产函数为 Content design, 10 years experience
分别表示i产业第t年的创新产出水平、创 新过程中R&D资本和研发人力投入,A 表示影响技术创新过程的其他因素
国际投资与技术溢出效应
It is applicable to work report, lecture and teaching
技术溢出效应概念
• 所谓技术溢出是指在贸易或其他经济行为 中,先进技术拥有者有意识或无意识地转 让或传播他们的技术,包括国际技术溢出、 国内技术溢出、行业间技术溢出、行业内 技术溢出四种形式。
FDI溢出效应与自主技术创新效率
实证方法
wele to use theБайду номын сангаасe PowerPoint templates, New Content design, 10 years experience
外文翻译--外商直接投资的溢出效应:国际经验的借鉴与启示
4420汉字,2430单词文献二:The Spillover Effect of Foreign Direct Investment: International Experience and Enlightenment1. IntroductionSince the 1990s, as the process of globalization and developing countries to accelerate the opening up of foreign direct investment in the spillover effect more and more by the general concern of all countries in the world. China and the Asian financial crisis has become a global attracting foreign direct investment than any other country, how best to encourage foreign direct investment in our country have a spillover effect, while foreign direct investment by reducing the negative impact, but also has been one of our government and the reality faced by the enterprises in question. international level in this area's most famous one of the researchers, as he and his colleagues in 1996, Professor Ari Kokko spillover effect on the description of the foreign direct investment that is spillover effect, as the international business enter or participate in the host country received by the local enterprises improve labor productivity. In fact, the international community on the spillover effects of foreign direct investmentIn the 1960s, the study has been started, it is precisely because the nature of the problem, and involved in an open economic environment in the country's development strategy for decades to research in the field more enthusiastic, and really made a lot of progress. Foreign direct investment spillover effect on the core issue of spillover effect is the mechanism, that is, when foreign direct investment after entry into the host country, through the micro-mechanism and how the process of the host country's labor productivity of local enterprises to promote the role of produce. On this issue will undoubtedly contribute to a thorough understanding of the host country's government and enterprises to take appropriate measures in order to achieve a more effective use of foreign investment, have contributed to the purpose of spillover effects.2. Understanding of evolution: foreign direct investment in the host country's influence and roleLooking back in history, people's attitude toward foreign direct investment has experienced from the initial breach of prudent to open and then take the initiative to attract process. In the late 1950s, foreign direct investment in a limited scale and scholars only treat it as capital flows between countries in international trade theory to be discussed to the late 1960s, with the scale of direct foreign investment and the expansion of scholars began to focus on on the market structure of the host country its impact and influence. Study results show that the mainstream, foreign direct investment by the sponsors of the national characteristics of an oligopoly market caused by the researchers are worried that foreign direct investment will be the domestic market imperfection of the spread to other countries. At the same time, prices on the international transfer of enterprises, as well as the study on foreign direct investment in the uneven development of the studies have strengthened the right of foreign direct investment resentment and thus the 1960s all countries, particularly developing countries on foreign direct investment holders reject or strictly limit policy.1970s, the international lending strong support to the capital of the Asian emerging countries the export-oriented economy, as well as Latin American countries import substitution-based economy flourish; However, the 1980s to government borrowing at the core of the Asian emerging mode of financing the development of the country by setbacks; and representatives to Mexico for some Latin American countries and into the debt crisis of developing countries in order to make foreign direct investment in the form of the introduction of international capital had to be re-thinking. At the same time, scholars of foreign direct investment in the in-depth study also showed some positive results. Many studies show that foreign direct investment in the host country has many spillover effects, particularly in the role of the international transfer of technology by the special attention. Thus, the host country for foreign direct investment in a major attitude change, whether passive or active to attract international capital to create opportunities for the international transfer of technology, most countries tend to start some open and the purpose of the introduction of foreign direct investmentpolicy.Since the 1990's, and people of foreign direct investment has had a positive perception further. Compared to other international transfer of technology, people have found that the more the latest technology and most profitable of the technology, the more likely international companies through international direct investment in the way in the host country use. The reason is that, from the point of view of international companies using such technologies that will form the legal right to remain in the control of the international enterprise. Want access to advanced technology from the point of view of the host country, for these reasons, the host country's enterprises needed advanced technology is not always able to buy on the market. Under such circumstances, the host country for foreign direct investment in local enterprises the special significance lies in the fact that when the international enterprises in the local investment and the use of advanced technologies for production activities, local enterprises can be the nearest through observation, imitation, reverse engineering and has been employed persons employed by international companies such channels as the corresponding technological and management of useful information, which can also cause the spillover of its technical information. Moreover, in addition to foreign direct investment may have spillover effects, the Harvard professor Caves also found that if foreign direct investment into the host country's monopoly market, the market will break the monopoly of the Central Plains some balance, local enterprises will be in foreign-funded enterprises competitive pressures increase efficiency. This is foreign direct investment reflects a spillover effect. In fact, the 90 countries of the 1980s, foreign policy is relatively more open, between the neighboring countries to attract foreign capital even more evident intention. It can be said that opening up and attracting foreign investment has become the strategic development of many developing countries an important part. On the above understanding of foreign direct investment This is clearly an important basis for the implementation of the policy.3. Explore mechanisms: direct foreign investment have spillover effectsDespite the presence of foreign direct investment compared with the generally positive awareness, and most developing countries have indeed adopted preferential policies to attract foreign capital, but according to different national manufacturing data by the experience of the results of the study but is not optimistic. The Caves by the Harvard professor, New York University professor and Globerman of Stockholm University Professor Magnus Blomstrom were led by Australia, Canada and Mexico manufacturing industry studies show that foreigndirect investment is in the host country had a spillover effect, but the World Bank study staff Haddad & Harrison & Aitken and the International Monetary Fund. Harri-SOll respectively Morocco and Venezuela study shows that the manufacturing sector did not have a spillover effect, and researchers from Italy Mariotti the study found, in the professional-oriented industries (Specialist sectors) and the scale industries (Scale intensive sectors) had a spillover effect, and in science-based industries (Science-based sectors) and traditional industries (Tranditional sectors) did not have spillover effects. Based on the results of different studies, international scholars reached a consensus: that foreign direct investment spillover effect is not automatically generated. In other words, countries and opening up policy itself does not guarantee entry into the country of foreign direct investment in the country will have a spillover effect, therefore, explore in depth the spillover effects on the conditions and mechanisms, become a reality in the countries in the spillover effect can effectively guide the key.Under the existing research results on the international spillover effects of foreign direct investment into the mechanism of the "spillover effect within the industry", "inter-industry spillover effect"①. Industry spillover effect. Industry spillover effect is also known as "demonstration and competition effect (Demonstration and Competition effects)," spillover effect of this mechanism embodiment, when foreign direct investment has entered a host of specific industries, on the one hand, foreign-funded enterprises adopt modern business model and advanced production and management technology to foreign-funded enterprises has created opportunities for high profits, which in the same industries in the local enterprises have a demonstration effect and that local enterprises and foreign-funded enterprises to watch the final acts of imitation to enable local enterprises to improve the efficiency of the results of their labor, access to the spillover effect. On the other hand, the entry of foreign direct investment on the local market and compete in the same industry in the operation of local enterprises a competitive pressures in order to maintain the existing market and fight for survival and development opportunities, local enterprises will do their utmost to take all possible measures to enhance operational efficiency. In this competitive environment contributed to improving the efficiency of the spillover effects are also manifestations. In view of this mechanism described Riedel and Lake respectively on the European semiconductor industry conducted two case studies. Case study results indicate that the United States is the entry of multinational corporations in Europe in the industry have brought new technology, the demonstration effect of the European role in the rise of the industry significantly; Langdon in the soap industry in Kenya found in a study of the case, Kenya entered the international soap manufacturing machinery manufacturing enterprises will be introduced soap market, local enterprises original handmade soap manufacturers lost sales, local soap manufacturers also have to introduce the corresponding soap manufacturing technology, thereby increasing productivity.In the above case study on the basis of 1992 Wang &Blomstrom the establishment of a simple theoretical model that the industry will be spillover effects of a push to a new level. Model will be the introduction of foreign advanced technology and the decision-making process of local enterprises to invest in learning the decision-making mutual contact of the two categories of enterprises in competing in the decision-making mechanism. They believe that the local enterprises, foreign-funded enterprises in the competitive pressure to invest in the learning process, and greater investment in the learning process, the technical capacity of local enterprisesis stronger, more access to higher profits, thus performance for the local because the access of foreign capital enterprises won the spillover effect; At the same time, foreign-funded enterprises in which the reduction of the technological gap, which will lead to more foreign-funded enterprises to host subsidiaries to the faster transfer of technology to enhance the corresponding competitiveness and to maintain the profits of the original space; This embodies funded enterprises as a result of the strengthening of competitiveness led to a spillover effect of foreign-funded enterprises, and is gratifying to note that the improvement of foreign-funded enterprises, in turn, access for local enterprises and further spillover effect Extension a new exhibition space. Thus, we understand, now, Wang &Blomstrom the industry spillover effect on the mechanism for a possible "spiral" development mechanism. Kokko in a 1994 against Mexico on the experience of the manufacturing sector to a certain extent, confirmed Wang &Blomstrom the conclusion of the study.②inter-industry spillovers. Inter-industry spillovers is also known as the "downstream correlation effects." This spillover effect through the branches of multinational companies with local suppliers and customers arising from the links between. Raul 1980 India has been selected two large truck manufacturers AL (foreign investment accounted for the major share) and TELCO (joint ventures), inspected the two enterprises, as well as their 36 suppliers in the establishment, information technology, finance, purchase of raw materials and the management and distribution channels, and other aspects of. According to the case study, All summed up that may lead to "upstream" spillover effects of the overflow of complementarily, he considered that the adoption of the following methods of transnational corporations may raise local suppliers of production efficiency: First, has the potential to help vendors build production facilities Secondly, to improve the supplier's product quality and innovation capacity to provide technical assistance or information; and third, to provide or help suppliers to purchase raw materials and intermediate products; fourth, for the management of vendors and organizations providing training and assistance; Fifth, to help suppliers to find more customers. Following Raul, Linda & Pang selected Singapore's three export-oriented electronics companies and conduct a case study. Linda & Pang selected three electronics companies are the world's leading electronics companies (the United States, Europe and Japan, the multinational corporations) in Singapore, a subsidiary or a branch, and three companies in Singapore have been operating for 8-13 years, their more than 90 percent of products exported overseas. Through the management of three companies visit, Lim & Pang found that the three companies are willing to local suppliers to establish connections, and from the financial, technical, management, and other aspects of the suppliers to provide help. On the basis of this is that Lim & Pang, multinational companies selling their products in the global market, market forces so that they sought in the global scope of the long-term efficiency, and local businesses (suppliers) that the favorable conditions to a certain extent, to reduce the risk of foreign-funded enterprises and uncertainty. Therefore, they proposed that the host government to pass a stringent policy to increase the limit for the purchase of local products is not necessary, the Government needs to strengthen local enterprises and multinational corporations who export-oriented association, crossed enterprises can be passed on to the links local enterprises have spillover effects.And the industry spillover effect similar to the study of the foreign-funded enterprises and local enterprises in the host association study also not optimistic about the situation there. A study found against Mexico in the North American Free Trade Area after the establishment of alarge number of American enterprises in the industry chain will need to use cheap labor to transfer part of the Mexican border. This industry is the transfer of enterprises from the United States access to the benefits of the lower costs, but did not play in Mexico related industries to help enhance the efficiency of the role. Seen in this light, to be effective access to the spillover effects industry, but also need more in-depth and more targeted research.③The result of the movement of spillover effects. As caused by the movement of foreign direct investment in the spillover effect is sometimes known as labor spillover effect, it mainly for multinational corporations to its local employees will generally give multifaceted, multi-level training, once these multinational corporations to other staff leave companies or set up their own office, they learn from multinational companies in the technology will benefit local enterprises. This spillover effect on the mechanism described is Irving Gershenberg through case studies of Kenya.翻译二:外商直接投资的溢出效应:国际经验的借鉴与启示1.引言90年代以来,随着全球化进程的加速以及发展中国家的对外开放,外商直接投资的溢出效应越来越多地受到了世界各国的普遍关注。
外商直接投资与技术溢出的关系
外商直接投资与技术溢出的关系外商直接投资(Foreign Direct Investment,FDI)是指跨国公司或个人在一个国家投资设立企业或购买该国企业的股权,从而在该国拥有一定的控制权和经营权。
随着全球化的不断发展,外商直接投资在国际经济中扮演着越来越重要的角色。
与此同时,技术溢出(Technology Spillover)作为外商直接投资的附带效应,也引起了人们的广泛关注。
外商直接投资与技术溢出之间存在着一种密不可分的联系。
外国企业通过直接投资进入其他国家的市场,不仅仅是为了获得更大的市场和更高的利润,还可以借助其先进的技术和管理经验,带动并改善该国的技术水平和管理能力。
这种技术溢出效应对于接受投资的国家来说,无疑是一种宝贵的机遇。
首先,外商直接投资为技术溢出提供了平台和机制。
跨国公司通常会将其最先进的技术和管理模式引入到所投资的国家,并通过培训和合作等方式将这些先进技术传递给当地的员工和合作伙伴。
由于外商直接投资涉及的资本和资源更加雄厚,使得技术溢出更加容易和顺利进行。
其次,外商直接投资可以促进当地企业的技术创新和升级。
通过与外国企业的合作和竞争,本地企业不仅可以学习和借鉴外国企业的技术和管理经验,还会面临更高的市场要求和竞争压力,从而迫使其进行技术革新和升级。
这种技术进步和创新对于一个国家的经济发展来说至关重要。
然而,外商直接投资带来的技术溢出效应并不是毫无代价的。
在享受技术溢出的同时,接受投资的国家也面临着一些挑战和问题。
首先,外商直接投资可能导致本地企业的竞争力下降,尤其是那些技术和规模较小的企业。
跨国公司通常具有更高的技术和资金实力,以及更大的规模经济效应,这使得本地企业在市场上处于相对劣势。
其次,外商直接投资可能导致技术依赖和创新能力不足。
一些发展中国家在吸引外商直接投资时通常会提供一系列的优惠政策和利益保障,这可能会导致本地企业对外国技术的过度依赖,而忽视自主研发和创新能力的培养。
- 1、下载文档前请自行甄别文档内容的完整性,平台不提供额外的编辑、内容补充、找答案等附加服务。
- 2、"仅部分预览"的文档,不可在线预览部分如存在完整性等问题,可反馈申请退款(可完整预览的文档不适用该条件!)。
- 3、如文档侵犯您的权益,请联系客服反馈,我们会尽快为您处理(人工客服工作时间:9:00-18:30)。
外文翻译原文FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT, TECHNOLOGY SOURCING AND REVERSE SPILLOVERSMaterial Source:The Manchester School Vol 71 No. 6 December 2003 Author: NIGEL DRIFFIELD Business School, University of Birmingham And JAMES H. LOVE† Aston Business School, Aston University Recent theoretical work points to the possibility of foreign direct investment motivated not by ‘ownership’ advantages which may be exploited by a multinational enterprise but by the desire to access the superior technology of a host nation through direct investment. To be successful, technology sourcing foreign direct investment hinges crucially on the existence of domestic-to-foreign technological externalities within the host country. We test empirically for the existence of such ‘reverse spillover’ effects for a panel of UK manufacturing industries. The results demonstrate that technology generated by the domestic sector spills over to foreign multinational enterprises, but that this effect is restricted to relatively research and development intensive sectors. There is also evidence that these spillover effects are affected by the spatial concentration of industry, and that learning-by-doing effects are restricted to sectors in which technology sourcing is unlikely to be a motivating influence.1 IntroductionTraditional models of foreign direct investment (FDI) have been heavily influenced by a framework which suggests that where a company has some ‘ownership’(i.e. competitive) advantage over its rivals and wher e, for reasons of property rights protection, licensing is unsafe, a company will set up production facilities in a foreign country through FDI (Dunning, 1988). Since much of the discussion of ownership advantages is couched in terms of technology and/or m anagement expertise, there is a strong a priori assumption that this ‘technology exploiting’ FDI will be an important method by which technology is transferred internationally. Indeed, there is a growing literature concerned with the extent to which FDI contributes to technological advance in host countries. Much of thisanalysis is based on estimations of externalities from inward FDI, with the evidence generally pointing towards positive effects of FDI on domestic productivity (Blomström and Kokko, 1998).However, the literature is increasingly turning to the possibility that FDI may be influenced by multinational firms’ desire not to exploit an existing ownership advantage abroad but to acquire technology from the host country, i.e. that ‘technology sourcing’ may be the motive for FDI. Kogut and Chang (1991) and Neven and Siotis (1996) point out that this possibility has exercised the minds of policy-makers in the USA and the EU, with concerns that host economies’ technological base may be undermined by technology sourcing by Japanese and US corporations respectively. These studies examine the effects of host versus home country research and development (R&D) expenditure differentials on FDI flows between Japan and the USA and the USA and the EU respectively. Both studies find a positive relationship between these measures, and interpret this as evidence of technology sourcing. The literature on the internationalization of R&D also contains an increasing amount of evidence that technology sourcing may be a motive for FDI (Cantwell, 1995; Cantwell and Janne, 1999; Pearce, 1999).This literature stresses a range of reasons for FDI in R&D, much of which is concerned with the relative technological strengths of the capital exporting (i.e. ‘home’) firm or country v ersus that of the host. For example, Kuemmerle (1999) distinguishes between ‘home-base exploiting’ FDI and‘home-base augmenting’ FDI. The former is undertaken in order to exploit firm-specific advantages abroad, while the latter is FDI undertaken to access unique resources and capture externalities created locally. And in an analysis of inward and outward FDI in 13 industrialized countries, van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie and Lichtenberg (2001) find positive spillover effects from outward FDI arising from accessing the R&D capital stock of host countries, leading them to conclude that FDI flows are predominantly technology sourcing in nature.Recent theoretical work represents an important step forward in this area, with Fosfuri and Motta (1999) and Siotis (1999) both presenting formal models of the FDI decision which embody the possibility of technology sourcing. They show that a firm may choose to enter a market by FDI in order to access positive spillover effects arising from close locational proximity to a technological leader in the host country. Because of the externalities associated with technology, these spillovers decrease the production costs of the investing firm both in its subsidiary operations and in its home production base. Siotis (1999) also shows that the presence ofspillovers may induce firms to invest abroad even where exporting costs are zero.The theoretical and empirical work reviewed above hinges crucially on the assumption that foreign firms investing in a host economy are able to capture spillover effects from the domestic (host) industry. The purpose of this paper is to test for the existence of this ‘reverse spillover’ effect for a panel of UK industries. If there is some evidence of productivity spillovers running from the domestic to the foreign sector of UK industry, this would suggest that the necessary condition for technology sourcing FDI does exist in practice. In addition to testing empirically for reverse spillover effects we also test for two elements which are implicit in the theoretical analysis: first, that the spatial concentration of production has an effect on productivity spillovers; and second, that learning-by-doing effects are linked to the investing motivations of foreign firms.2 THE MOTIV ATION FOR FDI, SPILLOVERS AND FIRM GROWTHFosfuri and Motta (1999) present a simple model in which two local (i.e. single country) firms are endowed with different technologies and are given the option of exporting to the other country, engaging in FDI or not entering. They show formally that an investing firm which is a technological laggard (i.e. has unit costs of production above those of its competitor) will find it profitable to invest abroad despite having an efficiency disadvantage, as long as the probability of acquiring the leader’s technology through productivity spillovers is sufficiently high. In other words, ‘technology sourcing’ rather than ‘technology exploiting’ FDI may occur. Siotis (1999) develops a similar model, but allows for the possibility of two-way spillovers between foreign and domestic firms. He too finds theoretical support for technology sourcing as a motivation for FDI.It seems plausible that the probability of benefiting from productivity spillovers will at least in part be dependent on the actions of the firms concerned, and that the scope for spillovers, particularly in the context of technology sourcing investment, will vary with the research efforts of domestic firms. Thus technology sourcing is most likely to occur where the scope for productivity externalities to be assimilated by foreign firms is greatest; this in turn is a positive function of the R&D intensity of domestic industry. We therefore anticipate reverse spillover effects being most apparent in those sectors in which domestic industry has invested heavily in R&D; these are the sectors in which the probability of acquiring technology through spillovers is greatest and in which technology sourcing FDI is most likely to occur. However, traditional explanations for FDI based on the exploitation offirm-specific‘ownership’ advantages shou ld not be ignored. Siotis (1999)shows that where a foreign firm has an ownership (i.e. efficiency) advantage relative to domestic firms, FDI will only occur if spillovers are likely to be small (the ‘dissipation effect’). We therefore anticipate technology exploiting FDI to be most likely where there is little scope for reverse spillovers, i.e. where domestic industry does not invest heavily in R&D. Reverse spillover effects should therefore be most evident in relatively research intensive sectors, but absent or less evident in sectors which are relatively non-research intensive.Two further and related hypotheses can also be tested. The first relates to the growth paths exhibited by firms that have different motivations for FDI. To the extent that it is possible to make the distinction between technology sourcing and technology exploiting FDI, then it is also likely that the patterns of development arising from these forms of investment will be different. This is likely to be important in the study of the development of total factor productivity in the foreign owned sector, following the theory of the multinational enterprise dating back to Dunning (1958) and more explicitly outlined in the seminal papers by Vernon (1966), Buckley and Casson (1976) or Dunning (1979). The traditional explanation of the existence of multinational enterprises is that firms transfer firm-specific assets across national boundaries but internalized within the firm (technology exploiting FDI). Firms operating in the foreign country then have to undertake the process of adapting this technology to a new environment, to take account of local working practices, available human capital and customers’ tastes for example. This is neither costless nor instantaneous, and so total factor productivity of foreign investment motivated in this ‘traditional’ manner is likely to demonstrate experience effects and significant learning-by-doing effects. By contrast, firms motivated by technology sourcing are less likely to undergo this adaptation of internal technology: their concern is not with adapting existing technology but in assimilating knowledge generated externally, in this case by local firms.Of course, in some cases the extent of adaptation by technology exploiting firms may be minimal in certain markets, while technology sourcing subsidiaries may undergo some degree of adaptation, so that the relative extent of learning by doing is ultimately an empirical issue. On balance, however, we expect significant learning by-doing effects among technology exploiting foreign firms, but perhaps not in the technology sourcing firms, where spillovers from domestic investments are likely to contribute more to total factor productivity in the foreign sector.The second subsidiary hypothesis relates to the extent to which technological externalities are constrained spatially. The theoretical analysis of Siotis (1999) depends on the existence of geographically localized spillovers to provide an incentive for technology sourcing FDI; Fosfuri and Motta (1999) also acknowledge this geographical dimension to spillovers. Empirically, there is significant evidence that technology spillovers are indeed limited geographically within countries, as well as between them (Head et al., 1995; Driffield, 1999). This suggests that reverse spillovers may be linked to the spatial distribution of industry; we therefore test whether the spatial concentration of production has an effect on the scale of productivity spillovers running from domestic to foreign industry.译文外商直接投资,技术寻求和逆向技术溢出效应资料来源:曼彻斯特大学学报71卷第6期作者:奈杰尔•德里菲尔德英国伯明翰大学商学院;詹姆斯H.爱阿斯顿商学院,阿斯顿大学近期的理论研究表明,外商直接投资的动机可能不是“所有权”优势,而是跨国公司希望通过直接投资积极利用东道国的先进技术。